II. MONETARY POLICY FRAMEWORK IN INDIA
3.36 In India, the transition of economic policies in general,
and financial sector policies in particular, from a control oriented regime
to a liberalised but regulated regime has been reflected in changes in the nature
of monetary management (Mohan, 2004a). While the basic objectives of monetary
policy, namely price stability and ensuring credit flow to support growth, have
remained unchanged, the underlying operating environment for monetary policy
has undergone a significant transformation. An increasing concern is the maintenance
of financial stability. The basic emphasis of monetary policy since the initiation
of reforms has been to reduce segmentation through better linkages between various
segments of the financial markets including money, Government securities and
forex markets. The key development that has enabled a more independent monetary
policy environment was the discontinuation of automatic monetisation of the
Government's fiscal deficit through an agreement between the
Government and the Reserve Bank in 1997. The enactment of the Fiscal Responsibility
and Budget Management (FRBM) Act, 2003 has strengthened this further. Development
of the monetary policy framework has also involved a great deal of institutional
initiatives to enable efficient functioning of the money market: development
of appropriate trading, payments and settlement systems along with technological
infrastructure.
3.37 Against this brief overview, this Section focuses on the
key changes in the monetary policy framework that became necessary in the liberalised
economic regime. As in Section I, the discussion is organised under three broad
heads: objectives, intermediate targets and operating procedures.
Objectives
3.38 The preamble of the Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934 enjoins
the central bank '…to regulate the issue of Bank Notes and keeping of reserves
with a view to securing monetary stability in India and generally to operate
the currency and credit system of the country to its advantage…'. Within this
broad mandate, the Reserve Bank's monetary policy pursues the twin objectives
of price stability and ensuring the availability of credit to the productive
sectors in the Indian economy. The emphasis between the twin objectives of price
stability and growth has,
however, varied over time depending on the evolving price-output
situation. Initially, this was guided by the concept of developmental central
banking crystallised in the First Five Year Plan, which required the Reserve
Bank to create an institutional framework for industrial as well as rural credit
to support economic growth (GoI,1951)2. This reflected a widespread
consensus that public investment could spur rapid growth. The concomitant deficit
financing associated with public investment began to spill over into inflation
and concerns began to be expressed over the inflationary consequences of the
fiscal deficit during the 1960s (Iengar, 1959; Rama Rau, 1960; Narasimham, 1968).
These concerns gathered momentum during the 1970s as inflation trended up to
around nine per cent during the 1970s (Chart III.2). Against this backdrop of
persistent high inflation, the Chakravar ty Committee recommended that price
stability emerge as the 'dominant' objective of monetary policy with a concomitant
commitment to fiscal discipline (RBI, 1985)3. Besides the conventional
wisdom that fluctuations in prices affected business decisions, inflation was
also seen as a social injustice, especially as the poor seldom had hedges against
inflation (Rangarajan, 1988).
3.39 The case for price stability as the dominant -if not sole
- objective of monetary policy gathered momentum in the early years of financial
liberalisation. Although it had to stabilise the economy in the face of the
balance of payments crisis of 1991, the Reserve Bank emphasised that its ultimate
mission was to steer monetary policy with its sights set firmly on inflation
control (RBI, 1992). Price stability was seen to be critical to sustain the
process of reforms (RBI, 1993). This acquired a new urgency as strong capital
flows, after the liberalisation of the external sector, began to push inflation
into the double digits. The very fact that inflation could be reined in during
the second half of the 1990s by tightening monetary conditions -in turn, enabled
by improved monetary-fiscal interface, as discussed later - appeared to demonstrate
the potency of monetary policy in ensuring price stability (RBI, 1997). In the
latter half of the 1990s, as the economy slowed down, monetary policy pursued
an accommodative stance with an explicit policy preference for a softer interest
rate regime while continuing a constant vigil on the inflation front. The macroeconomic
scenario began to change by the first half of 2004-05. In the face of sharp
increases in international commodity prices and the persistence of a large liquidity
overhang, the Reserve Bank reaffirmed that maintaining confidence in price stability
was a continuing policy objective (RBI, 2004b). The inflation situation would
be watched closely in order to respond in a timely and measured manner.
3.40 Thus, price stability has been an abiding objective of
monetary policy since the early 1950s although the success with price stability
has varied over time in response to the evolving monetary-fiscal interface.
It is only since the second half of 1990s that both inflation and inflation
expectations have moderated substantially (see Chapter V). There is very little
disagreement about the fact that price stability should continue to be a key
objective of monetary policy. The Advisory Group on Monetary and Financial
2 The First Five-Year Plan (1951) stated that: '...central
banking in a planned economy can hardly be confined to the regulation of the
overall supply of credit or to a somewhat negative regulation of the flow
of bank credit. It would have to take on a direct and active role, firstly
in creating or helping to create the machinery needed for financing developmental
activities all over the country and secondly, ensuring that the finance available
flows in the directions intended...'.
3 The Chakavarty Committee set out the following other
tasks for the monetary system so that its functioning would be in consonance
with the national development strategy as envisaged in the successive Five
Year Plans: (a) mobilising the savings of the community and enlarging the
financial savings pool; (b) promoting efficiency in the allocation of the
savings of the community to relatively productive purposes in accordance with
national economic goals; (c) enabling the resource needs of the major ‘entrepreneur’
in the country, viz., the government, to be met in adequate measure;
and, (d) promoting an efficient payments system.
Policies (Chairman: Shri M. Narasimham) recommended that the Reserve Bank should
be mandated a sole price stability objective (RBI, 2000a). There are, however,
several constraints in pursuing a sole price stability objective (RBI, 2000).
- The recurrence of supply shocks limits the role of monetary policy in the
inflation outcome.Structural factors and supply shocks from within and abroad
make inflation in India depend on monetary as well as non-monetary factors
- The persistence of fiscal dominance implies that the debt management function
gets inextricably linked with the monetary management function while steering
liquidity conditions.
- The absence of fully integrated financial markets suggests that the interest
rate transmission channel of policy is rather weak and yet to evolve fully.
In particular, the lags in the pass-through from the policy rate to bank lending
rates constrain the adoption of inflation targeting.
- The high frequency data requirements including those of a fully dependable
inflation rate for targeting purposes are yet to be met.
3.41 With the opening up of the Indian economy and its growing
integration, monetary policy had to contend not only with price stability but
also to ensure orderly conditions in the financial markets (Box III.5). The
growing integration of financial markets, while necessary for economic efficiency,
posed challenges for monetary management in terms of heightened risks of contagion.
Episodes of financial volatility, often sparked off by sudden switches in capital
flows in response to various shocks - such as the East Asian financial crisis,
sanctions after the nuclear explosions, downgrading of credit ratings, the meltdown
of the information technology bubble and the September 11 US terrorist attacks
- required a swift monetary policy response. The Reserve Bank, therefore, began
to emphasise the need to ensure orderly conditions in financial markets as a
prime concern of monetary management. Financial stability is now being recognised
as a key consideration in the conduct of monetary policy, in terms of ensuring
uninterrupted financial transactions; maintenance of a level of confidence in
the financial system amongst all the participants and stakeholders; and absence
of excess volatility that unduly and adversely affects real economic activity
(Reddy, 2004a).
Box III. 5
Monetary Policy Matrix in India
The conduct of contemporary monetary policy in the Indian economy
is based on a carefully crafted strategy. The strategy aims to balance the linkages
between monetary policy, credit policy and the regulatory regime in a dynamic
environment of structural transformation (Reddy, 2004).
Monetary policy now simultaneously pursues the objectives of
price stability, provision of appropriate credit for growth and increasingly,
financial stability. While there are complementarities between the objectives,
especially in the long run, it cannot be denied that there are certain tradeoffs,
particularly in the short run. The Reserve Bank has always had to address the
monetary policy dilemma of providing adequate credit to the Government and the
commercial sector, without fuelling inflationary pressures (Reddy, 1999a). With
the deregulation of interest rates, an added dimension is to balance the interest
cost of public debt with the price of commercial credit. Besides, with the opening
up of the economy, there are times when it is necessary to tighten monetary
conditions to ward off speculative pressures on the exchange rate, although
the growth objective presages a softer interest rate regime. Finally, the imperatives
of price stability have to be increasingly balanced with the impact of monetary
policy actions on balance sheets of the banking system.
In order to achieve these objectives, the Reserve Bank has,
at its disposal, three instruments - monetary policy, credit policy and regulatory
policies. At the same time, it is, however, not possible to compartmentalise
the policy actions, especially as the instruments are also used interchangeably
to serve different objectives. Changes in the policy interest rates, for example,
not only transmit a monetary policy signal but also change the price of credit
and impact asset prices. This, in turn, requires some other complementary measures
to manage the short-run trade-offs, especially in the context of the transitional
problems and transactional costs of an economy in transition.
The process of monetary policy formulation is essentially based
on the information content of a large host of macroeconomic indicators - quantum
and rate - spanning the entire domestic macroeconomy as well as international
macroeconomic developments. An internal Financial Markets Committee (FMC), instituted
in 1997, monitors market developments and recommends tactical operations for
meeting the evolving situation in the financial markets on a daily basis. For
this purpose, the FMC makes an assessment of market liquidity based on the evaluation
of inflows and outflows from the Reserve Bank balance sheet as a result of its
operations with the banking sector, financial institutions and the Government
(RBI, 2002). This is reinforced by inflation and growth forecasts produced by
an Inter-Departmental Group. The Board for Financial Supervision (BFS), constituted
as a Committee of the Central Board in November 1994 and headed by the Governor,
is entrusted with the supervision of commercial and select co-operative banks,
select financial institutions and non-banking financial companies. The Reserve
Bank also draws policy inputs from the Technical Advisory Committee on Money
and Government Securities Markets and the Standing Committee on Financial Regulation,
which also includes external experts, as well as a number of working groups,
again with external experts, appointed to look into specific issues.
Monetary-Fiscal Interface in India
3.42 A key message from the above discussion is that the surge
in inflation during the 1970s and 1980s was a consequence of expansionary monetary
policy. This, in turn, was the outcome of expansionary fiscal policies. Concomitantly,
the 1990s received a renewed focus on improving monetary-fiscal interface in
order to provide the monetary policy necessary flexibility in monetary management.
This Section briefly touches upon the monetary-fiscal interface over the past
decades and the recent efforts to strengthen the same through fiscal rules.
3.43 With the progressive widening of fiscal deficits from
the 1960s onwards, the burden of financing was borne by the Reserve Bank and
the banking system. The support of the banking system to the Government's borrowing
programme took the form of a progressive increase in statutory liquidity ratio
(SLR). Although interest rates - initially kept artificially low to contain
the interest cost of public debt - on Government securities were steadily raised
to enhance their attractiveness to the market, it got increasingly difficult
to get voluntary subscriptions even at higher rates of return. The SLR, therefore,
was raised to 38.5 per cent by the early 1990s4. The increase in
the SLR was, however, unable to fully meet the fiscal requirements and the burden
of financing the Government had also to be borne by the Reserve Bank. As Reserve
Bank financing is inflationary beyond a limit, the increase in the Reserve Bank
support to the Central Government was accompanied by an increase in cash reserve
requirements (CRR). The CRR was increased from three per cent in the early 1970s
to reach 15 per cent (in fact, 25 per cent if incremental reserve requirements
are also taken into account) by the early 1990s. However, even this order of
increase in the CRR to impound liquidity was insufficient and broad money growth
continued to remain high during the 1970s and 1980s and spill over to inflation.
3.44 As discussed in Section I, there are limits to the effectiveness
of monetary policy in containing inflation in the face of an expansionary fiscal
policy. Accordingly, monetary-fiscal coordination is often emphasised in order
to achieve price stability. In India too, following the balance of payments
crisis of the early 1990s, structural reforms addressed the issue of imparting
monetary policy greater flexibility. This was done through, inter alia,
raising market borrowings at market-related yields and the phasing out of the
automatic monetisation through ad hocs. These measures were able to reduce
the reliance on the Reserve Bank significantly from mid-1990s onwards5
. It is now clear that the Reserve Bank is able to control the timing and form
of its accommodation to the Government. The more critical issue is whether the
Reserve Bank would be able to contain the volume of its support to the Government,
once liquidity conditions change - either because domestic credit demand picks
up or capital flows dry up. Not only is the Centre's fiscal deficit still substantial,
but the share of net bank credit to the Government in financing the fiscal deficit
remains high (Chart III.3). Monetary management, however adroit, and monetary-fiscal
co-ordination, however seamless,

4 The increase in SLR coupled with the increase in the cash reserve requirements
(CRR) had the effect of crowding out the private sector from the credit markets
(see Chapter 6).
5 Other factors such as strong capital flows, weak credit
demand and risk aversion by banks also lowered the recourse to monetisation.
This, in turn, implies that commercial banks hold a large proportion of long-term
Government paper although their deposit liabilities are usually short, creating
an inherent maturity mismatch in commercial bank balance sheets. As their
demand for longer-term assets is already met by investments in government
paper, the ability of commercial banks to fund infrastructure financing is
also thus limited (Mohan, 2004a) (see Chapter IV).
cannot thus be a substitute for fiscal discipline (Jadhav,
2003) (Box III.6). It is for these reasons that, as discussed in Section I,
several countries have put in place fiscal responsibility legislation which,
inter alia, place limits on fiscal deficits to guard against fiscal profligacy.
3.45 As in other economies, the fiscal-monetary coordination
in India has been strengthened through the enactment of the FRBM Act, 2003.
The FRBM Act, while placing limits on deficits, prohibits borrowings from the
Reserve Bank from the fiscal year 2006-07 except by way of WMA or under exceptional
circumstances. The
Box III.6
Monetary and Fiscal Co-ordination: The Indian Experience
The evolving relationship between the Reserve Bank and the
Government over time can be analytically divided into four distinct phases (Reddy,
2001a). These span the periods of i) 1935-48, ii) 1948-69, iii) 1969-91 and
iv) 1991 onwards. Interestingly, the proposal to set up a central bank, originally
made by the Royal Commission on Indian Currency and Finance (Chairman: Sir Edward
Hilton Young) in 1926, was itself long held up partly on account of the debates
over the precise mechanism, which would ensure the independence of the central
bank from the budgetary demands of the fisc (Deshmukh, 1948; RBI, 1970; Rangarajan,
1993)6.
During the first phase, the Reserve Bank, although set up as
a privately owned and managed entity, was virtually subservient to the dictates
of the British Indian Government, especially in view of the war effort. This
was demonstrated by a Government threat to supersede the Reserve Bank board
if it did not recommend monetary and exchange rate policies compatible with
fiscal policy (RBI, 1970).
The second phase began with the nationalisation of the Reserve
Bank in 1948. The pressure on public finances, emerging from the programme of
large-scale industrialisation taken up in the Second Five Year Plan, led the
Government to turn increasingly to the Reserve Bank for financing its deficit.
It is during this phase that the process of automatic financing of the fiscal
deficit through ad hoc Treasury Bills as and when the Government balances
fell below a stipulated minimum took root (RBI, 1983). This led to persistent
deficit financing with inflationary consequences.
Fiscal dominance increased further during the 1970s and 1980s.
The entire financial system came to be geared to funding the budgetary requirements
of the fisc. The continuous process of monetisation of the fiscal deficit, in
particular, ended up effectively subjugating monetary policy to the imperatives
of fiscal policy. It was in this context that the Chakravarty Committee (RBI,
1985) recommended a cap on the net Reserve Bank credit to the Government.
The fourth phase, co-incident with the programme of financial
sector reforms, has been redrawing the institutional relationship between the
Reserve Bank and the Central Government to ease the fiscal constraint on monetary
policy (Rangarajan, 1993). An important initial step in this was the process
of pricing Government debt at market-determined rates (Tarapore, 2002). This
was supported by the development of a Government securities market. The emergence
of a Government securities market enabled, and in turn was facilitated, by the
reduction in SLR to the statutory minimum of 25.0 per cent of net demand and
time liabilities. The investments in Government paper are now guided, to a large
extent, by portfolio considerations, rather than administrative fiat
(Reddy, 1999). Ad hoc Treasury Bills were phased out in April 1997 with
a view to enabling the Reserve Bank to gain better control over money supply.
During this period, the Reserve Bank adopted a strategy of combining private
placements and devolvements in Government securities in order to moderate the
impact of fluctuations in monetary conditions on the interest cost of public
debt.
The Finance Minister, in the Union Budget Speech, 2000-01 announced
that in the fast changing world of modern finance it had become necessary to
accord greater operational flexibility to the Reserve Bank for the conduct of
monetary policy and regulation of the financial system. A key step forward in
this respect has been the enactment of the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget
Management (FRBM) Act, 2003 which, inter alia, prohibits borrowings from
the Reserve Bank from the fiscal year 2006-07 except by way of WMA or under
exceptional circumstances. This is backed by limits on the fiscal deficit. The
FRBM Act also seeks to eliminate the revenue deficit by March 2008.
6 The need for central bank independence was, in fact,
prophetically stressed by the Government while piloting the Reserve Bank of
India Act, 1934: '….It has generally been agreed in all the constitutional
discussions, and the experience of all other countries bears this out, that
when the direction of public finance is in the hands of a ministry responsible
to a popularly elected Legislature, a ministry which would for that reason
be liable to frequent change with the changing political situation, it is
desirable that the control of currency and credit in the country should be
in the hands of an independent authority which can act with continuity. Further,
the experience of all countries is again united in leading to the conclusion
that the best and indeed the only practical device for securing this independence
and continuity is to set up a Central Bank, independent of political influence….(In)
modern life, and modern economic organisations, there are two important functions:
they are the functions of those who have to raise and use money and there
are the functions of those who are responsible for producing the actual tokens
of money, the money in circulation. The basis of the whole proposal for setting
up an independent Central Bank is to keep these functions separate. The largest
user of money in the country is the Government, and the whole principle of
the proposal is that the Government, when it wants money to spend, should
have to raise that money by fair and honest means in just the same way as
every private individual has to raise money which he requires to spend for
his own maintenance. If the Government is in control of the authority which
is responsible for exercising the other function, then all sorts of abuses
can intervene'.
Reserve Bank would, however, still be able to buy or sell Government
securities in the secondary market consistent with the conduct of monetary policy.
In exercise of the powers of the Act, the Central Government has framed the
FRBM Rules, 2004. In the Fiscal Strategy Statement, the Government proposes
to assist the Reserve Bank in restraining the growth in money supply without
damaging the medium/long-term prospects of savings in the economy and without
hurting the interests of the poor, senior citizens and other fixed-income earners.
3.46 To conclude, price stability has been an abiding objective
of monetary policy in India although its achievement was circumscribed by the
fiscal dominance of monetary policy till the mid-1990s. In the subsequent years,
the reforms in the monetary-fiscal interface have been successful in providing
the Reserve Bank greater flexibility in monetary management. A key development
in this regard was the accord between the Government and the Reserve Bank in
1994 that eliminated the automatic monetisation of the Central Government's
fiscal deficit by gradually phasing out ad hocs by 1997. The most noteworthy
endeavour in this direction is the enactment of the FRBM Act. Adherence to FRBM
targets is critical for the objective of maintaining price stability, and more
importantly, to stabilise inflation expectations in the economy.
Intermediate Targets
3.47 As indicated earlier in Section I, central banks seek
to achieve their final objectives through the control of intermediate targets.
In India, these targets have evolved over time with changes in the overall operating
environment of monetary policy and financial liberalisation of the Indian economy.
This subsection presents a brief overview of the evolution of the intermediate
targets - from broad money to a multiple indicator approach - in the conduct
of the Reserve Bank's monetary policy.
3.48 The Reserve Bank did not have a formal intermediate target
till the 1980s. Bank credit - aggregate as well as sectoral - came to serve
as a proximate target of monetary policy after the adoption of credit planning
from 1967-68 (Jalan, 2002). Credit targeting, in fact, wove well into the concept
of development central banking. Since inflation was largely thought to be structural,
selective credit controls were used, from 1956, to regulate bank advances to
sensitive commodities to influence production outlays, on the one hand and to
limit possibilities of speculation, on the other. A Credit Authorisation Scheme
(CAS), introduced in November 1965, required commercial (and later, co- operative
banks, since 1974) banks to seek the Reserve Bank's prior approval before sanctioning
large working capital limits. This additional measure of credit regulation was
expected to perform the multiple objectives of keeping inflationary pressures
under check and ensuring that credit was directed to genuine purposes. The elaborate
process of credit regulation, however well intentioned, was not only the cause
of delays in credit disbursal but also impeded efficient resource allocation
by segmenting credit markets [Marathe Committee (RBI, 1983); Chakravarty Committee
(RBI, 1985)]. It was in this context that the requirement of prior authorisation
in respect of credit limits exceeding a threshold level under the Credit Authorisation
Scheme was replaced by a system of post-sanction scrutiny in 1988. Selective
credit controls were also abolished in the 1990s.
3.49 During the early 1960s, even as the analytics of money
supply continued to be governed by the expansion in credit, the Reserve Bank
began to pay greater attention to the movements in monetary aggregates. This
accent on monetary aggregates was supported by several empirical studies which
provided evidence of a stable money demand function in the Indian economy (Vasudevan
1977; Jadhav 1994). By the early 1980s, there appeared to be a consensus that
while fluctuations in agricultural prices and oil price shocks did affect prices,
continuous inflation of the kind witnessed since the early 1960s could not occur
unless it was sustained by the continuous excessive monetary expansion generated
by the large-scale monetisation of the fiscal deficit.
3.50 Against this backdrop, the Chakravarty Committee recommended
a monetary targeting framework to target an acceptable order of inflation in
line with output growth (RBI, 1985). Changes in broad money were thought to
provide reasonable predictions of average changes in prices over a medium-term
horizon of 4-5 years, though not necessarily on a year-to-year basis. It was,
in fact, argued that in the absence of a stable money demand function, the role
of monetary policy in inflation management would itself be negligible. Thus,
broad money emerged as an intermediate target of monetary policy and the Reserve
Bank began to formally set monetary targets in order to rein in inflation. As
the process of money creation is simultaneously a process of credit creation,
it was also necessary to estimate the increase in credit required by the projected
increase in output. The concept of monetary targeting adopted by the Reserve
Bank was a flexible one allowing for various feedback effects.
3.51 The process of financial liberalisation, which gathered momentum in the
1990s, necessitated a re-look at the efficiency of broad money as an intermediate
target of monetary policy. The Reserve Bank's Monetary and Credit Policy Statement
of April 1998 noted that most studies in India show that money demand functions
have so far been fairly stable. At the same time, it observed that financial
innovations emerging in the economy provided some evidence that the dominant
effect on the demand for money in the near future need not necessarily be real
income, as in the past. Interest rates too seemed to exercise some influence
on the decisions to hold money. In a similar vein, the Working Group on Money
Supply: Analytics and Methodology of Compilation (Chairman: Dr. Y.V. Reddy)
observed that monetary policy exclusively based on the demand function for money
could lack precision (RBI, 1998a) (Box III.7).
3.52 The Reserve Bank, therefore, formally adopted a multiple
indicator approach in April 1998. Besides broad money which remains an information
variable, a host of macroeconomic indicators including interest rates or rates
of return in different markets
Box III.7
Stability of Money Demand
In India, broad money emerged as an intermediate target of
monetary policy from the mid-1980s following the recommendations of the Chakravarty
Committee (RBI, 1985). The monetary targeting framework was based on the premise
of a stable relationship between money, output and prices. At the same time,
in view of ongoing financial innovations, a view emerged that monetary policy
exclusively based on the demand function for money could lack precision. This
necessitated a switch to a multiple indicator approach in which broad money
remains an important information variable in the conduct of monetary policy.
Notwithstanding this shift, the Reserve Bank's monetary policy statements continue
to provide an indicative trajectory of broad money growth. Amongst the recent
studies, Joshi and Saggar (1995), Arif (1996), Mohanty and Mitra (1999) and
Das and Mandal (2000) found evidence in favour of money demand stability while
Bhoi (1995) and Pradhan and Subhramanian (2003) found that financial deregulation
and liberalisation in the 1990s did affect the empirical stability of broad
money demand.
Against this backdrop, an attempt is made to examine stability
of money demand in India. Following the literature, real broad money is postulated
to depend upon real GDP. In order to assess the role of interest rates, the
interest rate on deposits of 1-3 years maturity is included. As these variables
turn out to be non-stationary, cointegration analysis is undertaken in the Johansen-Jesuelius
framework, using annual data from 1975-76 to 2003-04. Based on trace as well
as maximum eigenvalue tests, the null hypothesis of a single cointegrating vector
cannot be rejected. The coefficients of the cointegrating vector have the expected
signs7 . Real money demand increases with real GDP and the estimated
coefficient - although it cannot be interpreted as the elasticity - is close
to the various estimates of income elasticity of money demand in India. As regards
the interest rate, its coefficient is positive. This reflects the fact that
time deposits are the predominant component of broad money and an increase in
the interest rate on these deposits, therefore,
leads to a shift of financial assets towards bank deposits.
This analysis, therefore, confirms that real money and output are cointegrated,
i.e., there exists a long-run relationship between these variables.
Following this, the short-run dynamics are examined using an
error correction model. Results indicate that real GDP and interest rates are
weakly exogenous to the system. As regards real money, the error correction
results show that the coefficient on the error correction term is negative and
statistically significant (t-value is 4.0)8 . Stability properties
of the short-run model are examined by employing CUSUM and CUSUM SQUARE tests.
Both these tests indicate that the path of the parameters has been within the
two standard error bands (Chart III.4). While this supports the stability of
the parameters, the path of the parameters is not exactly horizontal. However,
as noted by the Working Group on Money Supply (RBI, 1998), the predictive stability
is equally important. Towards this purpose, the model is re-estimated up to
1999-2000 and multivariate dynamic forecasts for change in broad money are evaluated.
As Chart III.4 indicates, the model under-predicts the demand for money. A number
of factors may explain this behaviour. First, inflation has come down significantly
since the second half of the 1990s and this could have increased the real demand
for money. Second, monetary aggregates are inclusive of nonresident deposits
and movements in these deposits have varied a lot from year-to-year, mainly
in response to policy efforts to modulate these deposits. Third, the mergers
in the banking industry have provided a jump to monetary aggregates. From these
factors, it is evident that in the short-run, there can be deviations from the
long-run equilibrium relationship. These results thus support the conclusions
of RBI (1998) that monetary policy based solely on broad money could lack precision.
At the same time, given the long-run relationship, there is a role for monetary
aggregates to play. Accordingly, a multiple indicator approach in which broad
money remains an important information seems to be appropriate.
7 LMR = -9.6 + 1.32 LGDPR + 0.02 DR
MR, GDPR and DR are real broad money, real GDP and nominal interest rate on
deposits of 1-3 years. The prefix L denotes that variables are in logs. The
VAR was estimated with three lags.
8 DLMR = 0.04 DLMR(-1) + 0.53 DLGDPR(-1) - 0.01 DDR(-1) + 0.08 DLMR(-2)
+ 0.05 DLGDPR(-2) + 0.003 DDR (-2) – 0.16 ECM(-1)–
R2 = 0.26 DW = 1.5
The variables are defined in the previous footnote. The prefix D denotes that
variables are in first-difference form while ECM is the error correction term.
(money, capital and Government securities markets) along with such data as on
currency, credit extended by banks and financial institutions, fiscal position,
trade, capital flows, inflation rate, exchange rate, refinancing and transactions
in foreign exchange available on high frequency basis are juxtaposed with output
data for drawing policy perspectives in the process of monetary policy formulation.
3.53 This large panel of indicators is sometimes criticised
as a 'check list' approach, which tends to water down the concept of a nominal
anchor for monetary policy. It is certainly true that a single intermediate
target is much more theoretically appealing and operationally easier. At the
same time, it is very difficult to find a variable, which would be able to encapsulate
the larger number of factors, which need to go into monetary policy making at
this stage of transition from a relatively autarkic administered economy to
a relatively open market-oriented economic system. As channels of monetary policy
transmission shift course as a result of financial liberalisation, the central
bank has to naturally operate through all the paths that transmit its policy
impulses to the real economy. As discussed in Section I, given the environment
of high uncertainty in which monetary authorities operate, a single model or
a limited set of indicators is not a sufficient guide for the conduct of monetary
policy. The multiple indicators approach provides the required 'encompassing
and integrated set of data'.
Operating Procedures of Monetary Policy
3.54 With the shift away from the monetary targeting framework
towards a multiple indicator approach, the operating procedures of monetary
policy in India have undergone a significant shift. In particular, short-term
interest rates have emerged as instruments to signal the stance of monetary
policy. In order to stabilise short-term interest rates, the Reserve Bank now
modulates market liquidity to steer monetary conditions to the desired trajectory.
This is achieved by a mix of policy instruments including changes in reserve
requirements and standing facilities and open market (including repo) operations
which affect the quantum of marginal liquidity and changes in policy rates,
such as the Bank Rate and reverse repo/repo rates, which impact the price of
liquidity.
3.55 The Reserve Bank had originally conducted its monetary
policy through a standard mix of open market operations and changes in the Bank
Rate. The fiscal dominance during the 1970s and the 1980s changed the contours
of the operating framework of monetary policy. A natural corollary was that
the Reserve Bank's traditional instruments, the Bank Rate and open market operations,
began to loose their efficacy. As a consequence, the Reserve Bank began to turn
to changes in reserve requirements in order to modulate monetary conditions.
3.56 India, like most emerging market economies, saw a structural
shift in the financing paradigm in the 1990s. The Ninth Five Year Plan recognised
that the role of the financial system would have to be upgraded from mere channelisation
to allocation of resources in order to reap the benefits of higher growth. In
order to infuse a degree of efficiency in the allocation of resources by the
financial system, the Reserve Bank initiated a multi-pronged strategy of institutional
reforms to rekindle the process of price discovery in the financial markets
(Reddy, 2002).
3.57 First, the Reserve Bank began to deregulate interest rates,
beginning with the removal of restrictions on the inter-bank market as early
as 1989. This was supported by the process of putting the market borrowing programme
of the Government through the auction process in 1992-93. This was buttressed
by a phased deregulation of lending rates in the credit markets. At present,
banks are free to fix their lending rates on all classes of loans except small
loans below Rs.2 lakh and expor t credit. The deregulation of deposit rates
began later, especially as an incipient attempt in the late 1980s ended in a
price war between banks. Banks are now free to offer interest rates on all classes
of domestic deposits (except savings deposits), not only in terms of tenor but
also in terms of size. Interest rates on non-resident deposits are linked to
international interest rates and these are modulated from time to time, depending
on the macroeconomic - including the balance of payments - scenario.
3.58 Second, the process of interest rate deregulation had
to be supported by the development of market architecture, especially to address
the problem of missing markets at the short end. Two key reasons explain as
to why short-term instruments were not actively traded. First, the system of
cash credit shifted the onus of cash management from the borrowers to the banks.
Second, the availability of fixed rate 4.6 per cent Treasury Bills, with a discounting
facility from the Reserve Bank, on tap, in turn, allowed banks to pass the fluctuations
in liquidity onto the Reserve Bank balance sheet. To overcome these shortcomings,
the Reserve Bank began to introduce a number of money market instruments, such
as commercial paper, short-term Treasury Bills and cer tificates of deposits
following the recommendations of the Working Group on the Money Market (Chairman:
Shri N. N. Vaghul). The process of replacing cash credit with term loans, phasing
out of fixed rate tap Treasury Bills and the development of a repo market outside
the Reserve Bank is gradually generating a vibrant set of markets at the short
end of the interest rate spectrum.
3.59 Third, the introduction of new instruments was buttressed
by the parallel process of market development, beginning with the institution
of the Discount and Finance House of India as a market maker with two-way quotes
in the money markets. Although the call money market was initially widened by
introducing non-bank participants, they are now being phased out in tandem with
the parallel development of a repo market outside the Reserve Bank. The emergence
of a vibrant Government securities market, in particular, has played a key role.
3.60 Fourth, with a view to deepening inter-linkages, the development
of markets was supported by withdrawal of balance sheet restrictions which had
tied financial intermediaries to their primary segments of the financial markets.
Banks now operate across all the segments of the financial markets, including
equity and foreign exchange markets, albeit with prudential limits on
their exposures.
3.61 In brief, the liberalisation of the Indian economy required
a comprehensive recast of the operating procedures of monetary policy. The Reserve
Bank had to shift from direct to indirect instruments of monetary policy in
consonance with the increasing market orientation of the economy (Reddy, 1999,
2001 and 2002; Kanagasabhapathy, 2001). This required development of an array
of monetary policy instruments, which could effectively modulate monetary conditions
in alignment with the rejuvenated process of price discovery. Besides, shifts
in monetary policy transmission channels necessitated policy impulses which
would travel through both quantum and rate channels. Finally, the episodes of
volatility in the foreign exchange markets emphasised the need for swift policy
reactions balancing the domestic and external sources of monetisation in order
to maintain orderly conditions in the financial markets. Even within the set
of indirect instruments, the preference is for relatively more market-based
instruments such as open market operations. Accordingly, the cash reserve ratio
(CRR) has been gradually lowered from 15 per cent in the early 1990s to five
per cent by 2004, notwithstanding minor upward adjustments to deal with the
evolving liquidity situation in the economy. As the Reserve Bank's Internal
Working Group on Instruments for Sterilisation noted, the use of CRR as an instrument
of sterilisation, under extreme conditions of excess liquidity and when other
options are exhausted, should not be ruled out altogether by a prudent monetary
authority ready to meet all eventualities (RBI, 2004a).
3.62 The Reserve Bank is now able to influence short-term interest
rates by modulating the liquidity in the system through repo operations under
the Liquidity Adjustment Facility, reinforced by interest rate signals (Box
III.8) (RBI, 2000; Sen Gupta, Bhattacharyya, Sahoo and Sanyal, 2000; Dua, Raje
and Sahoo, 2003). The Reserve Bank has been largely able to enforce the interest
rate corridor defined by the reverse repo rate, the price at which it absorbs
liquidity and the repo rate/Bank Rate, the price at which it injects liquidity9
(Chart III.5).
Box III.8
Facets of Liquidity Management
The Liquidity Adjustment Facility (LAF), introduced in June
2000, allows the Reserve Bank to manage market liquidity on a daily basis and
also transmit interest rate signals to the market. The LAF, initially recommended
by the Committee on Banking Sector Reforms (Chairman: Shri M. Narasimham), was
introduced in stages in consonance with the level of market development and
technological advances in payment and settlement systems. The first challenge
was to combine the various sources of liquidity available from the Reserve Bank
into a single comprehensive window, with a common price. An Interim Liquidity
Adjustment Facility (ILAF), introduced in April 1999 as a mechanism for liquidity
management through a combination of repo operations, export credit refinance
facilities and collateralised lending facilities supported by open market operations
at set rates of interest, was upgraded into a full-fledged LAF. Most of the
alternate provisions of primary liquidity have been gradually phased out and
even though export credit refinance is still available, it is linked to the
repo rate since March 2004. Accordingly, the LAF has now emerged as the principal
operating instrument of monetary policy.
Analytically, the LAF experience with market stabilisation
can be partitioned into multiple sets of roles (Jadhav, 2003). First, the LAF
stabilises regular liquidity cycles, by allowing banks to tune their liquidity
requirements to the averaging requirements over the reporting fortnight and
smoothening liquidity positions between beginning-of-the-month drawdown of salary
accounts to fund household spending and end-of-the-month post-sales bulge in
business current accounts.
Second, it irons out seasonal fluctuations. It injects liquidity
during quarterly advance tax outflows or at end-March, when banks avoid lending
on call, which adds to their Capital to Risk-Weighted-Assets Ratio (CRAR) requirements.
It mops up liquidity in April to counter the typically large ways and means
advances drawn by the Government prior to the inception of its borrowing programme.
Third, it modulates sudden liquidity shocks, by injecting liquidity on account
of say, temporary mismatches arising out of timing differences between outflows
on account of Government auctions and inflows on account of redemptions. Fourth,
the LAF has emerged as an effective instrument for maintaining orderly conditions
in the financial markets in the face of sudden capital outflows to ward off
the possibility of speculative attacks in the foreign exchange market. Fifth,
by funding the Government through private placements and mopping up the liquidity
by aggressive reverse repo operations at attractive rates, the LAF helps to
minimise the impact of market volatility on the cost of public debt. Sixth,
the LAF bore much of the burden of sterilisation in the face of sustained capital
flows, especially since November 2000, by mopping up bank liquidity through
reverse repos and at the same time, gradually reducing reverse repo rates to
enable a softening of the interest rate structure. Finally, the Reserve Bank
tailors monetary policy action through both quantum and rate channels of transmission.
The LAF accords the Reserve Bank the operational flexibility to alter the liquidity
in the system (by rejecting bids) as well as adjusting the structure of interest
rates (through fixed rate operations) in response to evolving market circumstances.
3.63 Persistent capital inflows that India experienced since
2001-02 posed a challenge to the LAF operations. In view of large capital flows,
the LAF emerged as the key instrument of managing capital flows through sterilisation.
This was reflected in the outstanding reverse repo amount which increased from
Rs.2,415 crore as at end-March 2003 to Rs. 62,995 crore by late March 2004 and
further to Rs. 89,435 crore by mid-April 2004. Thus, instead of absorbing liquidity
of a short-term and temporary nature, the LAF window was absorbing funds of
a relatively more enduring nature. In order to address these issues, an Internal
Group of the Reserve Bank reviewed the operations of the LAF in a cross-country
perspective, keeping in view recent developments in the financial markets as
well as in technology. The Group noted that it is difficult to distinguish

9 With effect from October 29, 2004, the nomenclature of repo and reverse
repo has been interchanged as per international usage. Prior to that date,
repo indicated absorption of liquidity while reverse repo implied injection
of liquidity. The nomenclature in this Chapter is based on the new use of
terms even for the period prior to October 29, 2004 for comparability purposes.
operationally between the sterilisation operations and liquidity
management operations under the LAF. Nonetheless, it emphasised the need to
conceptually distinguish surplus liquidity of 'temporary' nature arising from
banks' cash management practices from surplus liquidity of a somewhat 'enduring'
nature arising from sustained capital inflows. The Group also added that it
would be desirable to de-emphasise the passive sterilisation attribute of the
LAF-reverse repo facility so that it could emerge as the exclusive policy signalling
rate. Accordingly, it felt a need for adequate instruments of sterilisation
in addition to the liquidity management facilities and, recommended, inter
alia, introduction of a standing deposit facility (Box III.9).
3.64 Pursuant to the recommendations of the Internal Working
Group on LAF as well as the Internal Working Group on Instruments for Sterilisation
(RBI, 2003b), a Market Stabilisation Scheme (MSS) was introduced in April 2004.
Under this scheme, Government of India dated securities of a maturity of less
than two years (so far) and Treasury Bills are being issued to absorb liquidity
(see Chapter IV). As on December 10, 2004, the outstanding issuances under the
MSS were Rs.51,334 crore, the pressure on the LAF window has gradually come
down. The outstanding reverse repo amount, therefore, fell from Rs. 89,435 crore
(mid-April 2004) to only Rs. 15,820 crore by December 10, 2004. The issuance
of securities under the MSS enables the Reserve Bank to improve liquidity management
in the system, to maintain stability in the foreign exchange market and to conduct
monetary policy in accordance with the stated objectives.
3.65 The Indian experience underscores the need for constant
innovation in terms of instruments and operating procedures for effective monetary
management. Apart from introduction of innovative instruments such as the MSS,
the policy framework has evolved in response to the changing environment. Illustratively,
the interest rates in the LAF auctions were initially allowed to emerge from
the bids, with the Reserve Bank holding occasional fixed rate auctions to transmit
interest rate signals. As market players began to bid at the prices signalled
by the Reserve Bank, the de jure market-determined LAF rates began to
turn into de facto fixed rates. It is in this context that the Reserve
Bank switched to a fixed auction format in March 2004. Second, while the reverse
repo rate, acted as the floor, the practice of supplying liquidity at multiple
rates, e.g., the Bank Rate and the repo rate, implied that there was
no unique ceiling. It is in this context that the Reserve Bank has increasingly
been resorting to pricing its liquidity at the repo rate, in recent years. Apart
from WMA which are still at the Bank Rate, all other forms of liquidity support
are at the repo rate.
Box III.9
Internal Group to Review the Liquidity Adjustment Facility:
Recommendations
In the light of substantial technological developments, the
objective of conducting LAF operation on real-time basis needs to be pursued
further.
Introduction of a deposit facility to afford more flexibility
to the Reserve Bank in using the reverse repo facility as a signalling device
while not sacrificing the objective of the provision of a floor to the movement
of short-term interest rates. As the Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934 in its
present form does not permit the Reserve Bank to borrow on a clean basis from
banks and pay interest thereon, this would necessitate a suitable amendment
to the Reserve Bank Act.
Pending amendments to the Reserve Bank Act, the Reserve Bank
should explore possibilities of modifying the current CRR provision to accommodate
a standing deposit type facility - placement of deposits at the discretion of
banks unlike CRR which is applicable to all banks irrespective of their liquidity
position.
The remuneration of CRR, if any, could be delinked from the
Bank Rate and placed at a rate lower than the reverse repo rate.
The minimum tenor of the repo/reverse repo operations under
the LAF facility should be changed from overnight to 7 days to be conducted
on daily basis to enable balanced development of various segments of money market.
The LAF auction could be a fixed rate auction enhancing its
policy signalling rate, with the flexibility to revert to variable price auction
format.
The Bank Rate under normal circumstances should be aligned
to the repo rate and, therefore, the entire liquidity support including refinance
should be made available at the repo rate/Bank Rate.
With intra-day liquidity (IDL) available under the RTGS system,
the timing of LAF could be shifted to the middle of the day, say, 12 noon to
ensure that marginal liquidity is kept in the system for a longer time. To take
care of unforeseen contingencies, the Reserve Bank may consider discretionary
announcement of timing of both repo auctions and reverse repo auctions at late
hours.
As proposed by the Reserve Bank’s Working Group on Instruments
of Sterilisation, Market Stabilisation Bills/ Bonds (MSBs) could be issued for
mopping up enduring surplus liquidity from the system over and above the amount
that could be absorbed under the day-to-day reverse repo operations of the LAF.
The maturity, amount, and timing of issue of MSBs may be decided by the Reserve
Bank in consultation with the Government depending, inter alia, on the
expected duration and quantum of capital inflows, and the extent of sterilisation
of such inflows.
3.66 The changes in the operating procedure of Reserve Bank's
monetary policy in tune with financial sector reforms during the 1990s have
impacted its balance sheet in terms of size and composition and sources of income
and expenditure (Reddy, 1997). In consonance with the international experience,
the programme of financial liberalisation was accompanied by several measures
to further strengthen the health of the Reserve Bank balance sheet, especially
as monetary policy emerged as the principal instrument of macroeconomic stabilisation
(RBI, 2004b; Jadhav et al, forthcoming) (Box III.10 and Table 3.9).
Box III.10
The Reserve Bank's Balance Sheet during the 1990s
The process of financial liberalisation during the 1990s was
accompanied by several measures to further strengthen the Reserve Bank's balance
sheet and financial position. The pursuance of the already conservative accounting
norms was accompanied by greater disclosures in the interest of transparency.
Over the past few years, the Reserve Bank has recognised the need to proactively
build up its internal reserves, i.e., Contingency Reserve (CR) and Asset
Development Reserve (ADR), in order to ensure a sound balance sheet and undertake
monetary and exchange operations without any overriding concerns on the impact
of such operations on the balance sheet. The Reserve Bank, as per the current
policy, aims at an indicative target of CR at 12 per cent of total assets by
June 2005. This would provide cushion with respect to losses which cannot be
absorbed by current earnings arising out of central bank operations/ interventions
in the money, Government securities and foreign exchange markets and depreciation
of domestic/foreign securities held by the Reserve Bank.
The size and composition of the Reserve Bank's balance sheet
underwent significant shifts during the 1990s and thereafter. The asset size
increased fivefold to Rs.6,09,738 crore as at end-June 2004 from Rs.1,23,836
crore as at end-June 1991. On the asset side, the share of foreign currency
assets and gold in the total assets increased to 89.1 per cent as at end-June
2004 from 8.9 per cent as at end-June 1991, reflecting mainly the consistently
overall balance of payments surplus throughout the intervening period.
The structural changes in the composition of the Reserve Bank's
assets were reflected in an increase in the share of income from foreign sources
in total income. Besides, changes in the manner of conducting monetary operations
have impacted the composition of income from domestic sources. Furthermore,
financial market deregulation has enhanced the interest sensitivity of domestic
income. The Reserve Bank's total income declined to 2.3 per cent of its assets
as at end-June 2004 from 3.7 per cent during 1990-91, reflecting mainly the
dominance of foreign currency assets, which carry relatively lower interest
in comparison with domestic assets comprising largely Government securities
(RBI, 2004b). Total expenditure declined to 1.3 per cent of assets as at end-June
2004 from 2.6 per cent as at end-June 1991, mainly as a result of decline in
the interest outgo on the eligible CRR balances. The share of the surplus transferred
to the Government in the total income has increased during the latter half of
the 1990s but simultaneously with higher transfers to internal reserves (Chart
III.6).
The increasing market orientation of monetary management was
accompanied by greater balance sheet transparency in line with international
best practices. The Reserve Bank follows conservative valuation and income recognition
norms. Its holdings of both domestic and foreign securities are valued each
month end at the market price or book value, whichever is lower. Foreign currency
assets are revalued every week to take into account the impact of exchange rate
changes. The resultant revaluation gain/loss is parked in a separate balance
sheet head called the Currency and Gold Revaluation Account. Gold is similarly
revalued at the end of the month at 90 per cent of the daily average price quoted
at London for the month. Over the years, significant disclosures in respect
of the Reserve Bank's accounts have been enhanced markedly in line with international
best practice. These relate to i) details of interest income and interest expenditure
in the Profit and Loss Account (since 1990); ii) statement of significant accounting
policies and notes to accounts (since 1992); and iii) details of other assets
and liabilities and contingency reserves (since 1993). The Advisory Group on
Transparency in Monetary and Financial Policies (Chairman: M. Narasimham) observed
that data dissemination by the Reserve Bank, including the balance sheet, bear
up well in comparison with central banks in developed countries.
Table 3.9: Reserve Bank’s Capital Account |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Per cent to total assets |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
End- |
|
Capital |
Contingency Reserves |
Currency and |
Exchange |
Total |
Memo Item: |
June |
|
Paid-up and |
(including Asset |
Gold Revaluation |
Equalisation |
|
National |
|
|
Reserves |
Development Reserve) |
Account |
Account |
|
Funds |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1 |
|
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 = |
7 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
1+2+3+4+5 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1991 |
|
5.2 |
4.5 |
2.9 |
4.4 |
17.1 |
4.7 |
1996 |
|
2.8 |
3.3 |
5.1 |
1.2 |
12.3 |
2.5 |
2004 |
|
1.1 |
10.2$ |
10.2 |
0.0 |
21.5 |
0.1 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
$Includes previous balances under the National Industrial Credit (Long-Term
Operations) Fund.
Note:The Working Group on Money Supply: Analytics and Methodology
of Compilation (Chairman: Dr. Y. V. Reddy)
expanded the definition of the Reserve Bank's capital account to include
capital paid-up, reserves, national funds,
contingency reserves, Currency and Gold Revaluation Account (formerly
Exchange Fluctuation Reserve) and
exchange equalisation account (RBI, 1998a).
Source:RBI Annual Reports.
|
III. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
3.67 It is now widely agreed that monetary policy can contribute
to sustainable economic growth by maintaining low and stable inflation. Within
this overall objective of price stability, central banks attempt to stabilise
output around its potential. In order to create enabling conditions for low
and stable inflation as well as inflation expectations, there is an emerging
consensus to secure the independence of monetary policy from the budgetary requirements
of the fisc. A number of countries now limit Government access to central bank
financing, reinforced by fiscal responsibility legislation.
3.68 With the growing globalisation and integration of economies,
monetary authorities are now required to pay greater attention to external developments.
Swings in trade flows and, especially capital flows are quite common and these
impart a high degree of volatility to exchange rates. Even in an environment
of price stability, the 1990s witnessed episodes of financial instability. The
presumption that price stability ensures financial stability is thus not true,
at least in the short-run. Ensuring orderly conditions in financial markets
and maintenance of systemic financial stability has thus emerged as an important
objective of monetary policy, even for central banks not involved with banking
regulation and supervision.
3.69 Financial innovations have also impacted upon the conduct
of monetary policy. In consonance with the preference for a degree of operational
flexibility in a complex macroeconomic environment, most central banks are beginning
to eschew setting unique intermediate targets or following some fixed rule of
monetary policy. They, instead, prefer to monitor a range of macroeconomic indictors,
which carry information about the ultimate objectives. Short-term interest rates
have emerged as operative target/ instruments of monetary policy. Most central
banks now prefer to manage liquidity to steer monetary conditions in consonance
with the overall policy objectives of price stability and growth. Central banks
usually forecast market liquidity and then conduct open market operations to
impact the interest rate structure to affect the real economy. Along with these
developments, central banks have strengthened their balance sheets in order
to be able to meet unforeseen contingencies that may arise from their market
operations.
3.70 In India, the opening up of the economy in the early 1990s
had a significant impact upon the conduct of monetary policy. Price stability
remains the key objective of monetary policy and there is virtually a national
consensus that high inflation is not good. Inflation expectations and inflation
tolerance have come down. Adherence to the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget
Management Act should stabilise inflation expectations and hence contribute
to the objective of price stability. While adequate availability of credit to
meet investment demand continues to remain an important objective, the growing
integration of the Indian economy with the global economy has led to financial
stability emerging as a key consideration in the conduct of monetary policy.
Although there are complementarities between the objectives in the long run,
there are certain trade-offs in the short run.
3.71 In order to meet challenges thrown by financial liberalisation
and the growing complexities of monetary management, the Reserve Bank switched
from a monetary targeting framework to a multiple indicator approach. Short-term
interest rates have emerged as indicators of the monetary policy stance. A significant
shift is the move towards market-based instruments away from direct instruments
of monetary management. In line with international trends, the Reserve Bank
has now put in place a liquidity management framework in which market liquidity
is now modulated through a mix of open market (including repo) operations and
changes in reserve requirements and standing facilities, reinforced by changes
in the policy rates, including the LAF rates and the Bank Rate. These arrangements
have been quite effective in the recent years in managing liquidity in the system,
especially in the context of persistent capital flows. The introduction of the
Market Stabilisation Scheme has provided further flexibility to the Reserve
Bank in its market operations.
3.72 As monetary policy emerges as the primary instrument of
macroeconomic stabilisation, the Reserve Bank, like most other central banks,
has initiated several measures to strengthen the health of its balance sheet.
Over the past few years, the process of monetary policy formulation has become
relatively more articulate, consultative and participative with external orientation,
while the internal work processes have also been re-engineered. The stance of
monetary policy and the rationale are communicated to the public in a variety
of ways, the most important being the monetary policy statements. The communications
strategy and provision of information have facilitated conduct of monetary policy
in an increasingly market-oriented environment.
3.73 To conclude, while financial and external liberalisation
present opportunities, they also throw challenges for policy authorities. Monetary
authorities are increasingly required to take cognisance of not only domestic
shocks but also external shocks. Given their objectives, central banks are required
to monitor various segments of financial markets to ensure orderly conditions.
Given the random nature of the shocks hitting the economy, central banks are
increasingly acting as shock absorbers. In order to manage these shocks effectively,
a steady stream of innovations is required by central banks in terms of instruments
and operating procedures while strengthening their balance sheets.
|