The Finance Commission (FC) was created as a constitutional body to address issues of vertical and
horizontal imbalances of federal finances in India. Apart from its constitutional tasks of deciding the
proportion of tax revenue to be shared with the States and the principles governing the grants-in-aid
of the revenues of the States, the scope of the FCs broadened over time as they were assigned several
other issues on government finances, particularly those relating to augmentation of State Consolidation
Funds to supplementing the resources of local bodies and debt-related issues. The approach of successive
FCs varied as they addressed concerns raised by States from time to time regarding the composition of
the divisible pool of central taxes and inter se distribution criteria. Recent constitutional changes have
simplified the sharing arrangement of the divisible pool of Central taxes by clubbing all shareable
Central taxes and excise duties. While determining the formula for horizontal distribution of inter se
shares of States, various FCs attempted to correct the differentials in revenue capacity and cost disability
factors inherent in the economies of States, while trying to foster fiscal efficiency at the State level.
However, differences have been noticed in selection, definition and weight of variables, that have been
used by FCs to prescribe the devolution formula for Central taxes. More recently, the Thirteenth FC
has placed greater emphasis on fiscal capacity distance and fiscal discipline, which is expected to facilitate
greater convergence among the States. In the context of grants, there has been some shift from a gapfilling
approach to a normative assessment of resource requirements and expenditure. The pattern of
transfers through the FC channel shows that the share in Central taxes has persistently been the
predominant component of revenue sharing since the First FC. As far as the extent of equalisation is
concerned, an analysis of transfers as recommended by four successive FCs (from the Tenth to the
Thirteenth) shows that it was the highest in the case of the Eleventh FC as the gap between recommended
and benchmark transfers was minimum.
1. Introduction
7.1 Centre-State fiscal relations and the
relative spheres of activities of the two levels of
the government constitute the most contentious
issue of federal finances. Most federal
governments are vested with powers to raise tax
revenues, while States are responsible for
undertaking a large part of the public expenditure.
The rationale underlying this design of
responsibilities lies in the fact that federal
governments are supposed to enjoy scale
economies in the collection of certain taxes, while
expenditure responsibilities are assigned to States
due to their proximity to local issues and needs. Similarly, taxes with an inter-State base and those
in which uniformity in rates is desirable are vested
in the Central government. Most federations
across the world have been following this fiscal
efficiency criterion for a long time (Kurian, 2008)8 .
7.2 Even in India, while the Central government
has greater access to tax resources, the State
governments have to face the greater responsibility
of delivery of public goods. The constitutional
division of taxation powers between the Centre and
the States rests on economic and administrative
considerations. The distribution of taxation powers
is intended to minimise tax problems in a federal
set-up, such as double taxation, tax rivalry among States, duplication of tax administration and tax
evasion. However, the allocation of taxation powers
vis-à-vis responsibilities per se creates an
imbalance referred to as vertical imbalance. In
addition, the existence of vast regional disparities
contributes to horizontal imbalances among States
in terms of their resource capacity relative to their
expenditure responsibilities. As the precise
estimation of the quantum of resource transfers to
address the vertical and horizontal imbalances is
difficult, the Central Finance Commission (FC)
plays an important role in this regard in the Indian
federal set-up.
7.3 The basic task assigned to the Central FC
is to recommend resource transfers aimed at
correcting the vertical and horizontal fiscal
imbalances in an equitable and efficient manner.
Vertical imbalances refer to the mismatch between
the revenue-raising capacity and expenditure
needs of the Centre and the States. Horizontal
fiscal imbalances exist on account of the inability
of some States to provide comparable services
due to inadequate capacity to raise funds. To
address these imbalances, the FCs have been
given a constitutional mandate to decide on (i) the
proportion of tax revenue to be shared with the
States and (ii) the principles which should govern
the grants-in-aid to States. In addition to the core
functions, the FCs are entrusted with the
responsibility to make recommendations on
various policy issues, as and when they arise. The
FC also tenders advice to the President on any
other matter referred to the Commission in the
interests of sound public finance. The
recommendations made by the FC are only
advisory and, hence, not binding on the
Government. Thus far, 13 FCs have been
constituted with the last one constituted, in
November 2007.
7.4 Against this backdrop, this chapter
assesses the effectiveness of FCs in reducing
fiscal imbalances through vertical and horizontal
distribution criteria. This chapter is organised into five sections. Apart from this introductory section,
Section 2 provides an overview of Central-State
fiscal relations and the constitutional mandate of
the FC in this regard. Section 3 discusses major
developments in the mandates of various FCs.
Section 4 deals with changes in the devolution
criteria of resources from the Centre to the States
since the First FC and examines the pattern of
the Centre’s transfers to States through the FC
channel across various award periods. In Section
5, an empirical exercise is undertaken to estimate
the vertical and horizontal components of resource
transfers recommended since the Tenth FC.
Section 6 provides the concluding observations.
2. Centre-State Financial Relations:
Indian Context
7.5 In India, Centre-State financial relations
relate to the distribution of power in resource
mobilisation between the Centre and States as also
the sharing of expenditure responsibilities. Most of
the important and buoyant revenue sources are
assigned to the Union Government, while major
expenditure responsibilities in the social and
economic sectors are assigned to State
governments. In fact, the architects of the Indian
Constitution drew on the experience of some extant
federations where the assignment of taxes with a
wide economic base to units had led to intractable
problems of conflicting tax jurisdictions (Sury,
2010)9 . The possibility of such conflicts was avoided
by assigning such taxes right from the beginning
to the Union Government. While the State
governments in India collect about only one-third
of the total tax revenue accruing to the government
sector, their expenditure obligations are
disproportionately high, accounting for threefourths
of the aggregate social expenditure and
more than one-half of the aggregate expenditure
on economic services. To enable the States to carry
out their expenditure responsibilities, the FC is
assigned the task of recommending the transfer of
resources from the Centre to the States.
7.6 The FC is constituted by the President under
Article 280 of the Constitution every fifth year or
earlier if necessary. The approach of each FC is
guided by the mandate of the constitutional
provisions and the terms of reference contained in
the Presidential order constituting it. The duties of
the FC are set out under Article 280 of the
Constitution, the core duties that relate to sharing of
Central taxes and the determination of grants for the
States are laid down under Article 270 and Article
275, respectively. The Indian Constitution provides
for Central transfers, but it neither indicates the share
of States in the divisible taxes nor presents any
principles for its distribution among the States. The
precise manner of sharing taxes and the actual
determination of grants is left to the FC.
3. Developments in Mandate
7.7 The Indian federal system has demonstrated
remarkable resilience in coping with new demands
made on it from time to time. The FC’s mandates
have been modified from time to time, taking into
account the parametric environment that defines the
economy and its immediate future. Accordingly, it is
noted in the Sixth FC Report (p.5):
“The provisions of the Constitution
concerning financial relations between the Centre
and the States seem to have been designed with
great care and circumspection so as to forestall
precisely the kind of difficulties that even the older
federations do not appear to have overcome in
securing closer correspondence between
resources and functions of the different layers of
Government... [T]he financial provisions of our
Constitution give enough room for reconciling such
conflicts of interests as may arise from time to time
between the Union and the constituent units.”
7.8 The first FC was appointed in 1952 and, so
far, 13 FCs have been appointed at intervals of
almost every five years. Since the first FC, the
nature of India’s economy and the macroeconomic
policy framework have changed dramatically.
Accordingly, fiscal transfers have been used to fulfil
a variety of objectives, with the design of the
transfer scheme getting closely linked to the intended purpose. The terms of reference (TOR)
of FCs have been expanded to include relevant
issues of topical importance from time to time. While
some of the issues were included under the TOR
of FCs in response to constitutional changes, other
issues were referred to FCs as and when they
emerged. In the following part of this section, some
of these issues are discussed.
Additional TOR with respect to Local Bodies
7.9 In the early 1990s, decentralisation reforms
assumed significance with a view to ensure the
empowerment of local people through local
governments. A notable development in this regard
was the 73rd and 74th amendments in the
Constitution in 1993. These constitutional
amendments aimed to provide an impetus to the
decentralisation process through a system of selfgovernment
for rural and urban local bodies and
devolve greater powers, functions and authority to
them. Decentralisation in governance bodes well
for efficiency augmentation as local representatives
are presumed to have a better understanding of
local preferences and needs for goods and
services. These amendments underscored the
organic link in the public finances of the multilayered
federal polity in India. Thus, it became necessary
to re-orient the mechanism of Central transfers to
take care of the resource requirements of rural and
urban local bodies.
7.10 Accordingly, for the first time the TOR of the
Eleventh FC required it to make recommendations
in accordance with these constitutional
amendments. Before this, the Tenth FC had
recommended ad hoc grants equivalent to 1.38 per
cent of the divisible pool, albeit without any mandate
under the TOR. The TOR for the Eleventh FC was
extended to include recommendations on the
measures needed to augment the consolidated fund
of the States so as to supplement the resources of
local bodies, viz., panchayats and municipalities.
The tasks of State FCs were spelled out under
Articles 243I and 243Y of the Constitution. In other
words, these amendments establish an organic link
between the two constitutionally created bodies –
the Central FC and the State FC (SFC).
7.11 In line with this mandate, the Eleventh FC
suggested measures to augment the Consolidated
Fund of the States. The purpose of these
measures was two-fold: (i) to help achieve the
underlying objectives of the 73rd and 74th
amendments of the Constitution by enabling local
bodies to function truly as institutions of selfgovernment,
and (ii) to ease the burden that State
exchequers may face in nurturing local bodies to
help them attain their potential and discharge their
appointed functions. The Eleventh FC
recommended ad hoc annual grants of `2,000
crore (0.78 per cent of the divisible pool) for
panchayats (`1,600 crore) and municipalities
(`400 crore), which were earmarked for priority
activities, viz ., maintenance of accounts,
development of databases and audit of local
bodies. Subsequently, the Twelfth FC raised the
grants to `25,000 crore (1.24 per cent of the
divisible pool) to be divided between panchayats
(`20,000 crore) and municipalities (`5,000 crore)
during the period 2005-10. It also suggested that
SFCs should be set up without delay. The
Thirteenth FC raised the share of grants to local
bodies to 2.28 per cent (`87,519 crore) in the
divisible pool of resources for the award period
2010-11 to 2014-15. These developments indicate
that the FC channel has played an important role
in strengthening fiscal decentralisation in India.
Alteration in the Pattern of shareable taxes
7.12 Another constitutional amendment was
necessitated when the vertical devolution process
was sought to be simplified by making all taxes and
duties in the Union list shareable with the States.
The States’ demand for a larger pool of shareable
taxes by including all Central taxes, particularly
corporation tax, was deliberated by various FCs.
The inclusion of certain other taxes and excise
duties (e.g., surcharge on income tax, surcharges
duties on excise, earmarked cesses and
miscellaneous receipts from penalties) in the
shareable pool of taxes had been a contentious
issue between the Centre and the States. Until the
Tenth FC, the net proceeds of income tax and Union
excise duties were the major shareable taxes for
which a separate distribution criteria was prescribed by the FCs. This changed after the 80th
Constitutional amendment in 2000 under which
Article 270 was amended.
7.13 This amendment, which was based on an
‘alternative scheme of devolution’ recommended
by the Tenth FC, fundamentally altered the pattern
of sharing of Central taxes between the Centre and
the States. Under the alternative devolution
scheme, the proceeds of all Central taxes, except
surcharges, were to constitute a common shareable
pool from which a share was to be devolved to the
States. The Scheme incorporated in the new Article
270 provided for a fixed percentage share of States
in all Central taxes and duties (except central sales
tax, consignment taxes, surcharges on Central
taxes and earmarked cesses). The Eleventh FC
was required to recommend the percentage of
taxes or duties referred to in the new Article 270.
This arrangement is expected to enable the States
to share the aggregate buoyancy of Central taxes
and facilitate the Centre’s process of tax reforms
without needing to consider the nature of the tax
(shareable or non-shareable). The impact of
fluctuations in Central tax revenues would,
therefore, be felt by Centre and the States alike.
7.14 Apart from the above issues, other issues
beyond the constitutional mandate such as the
restructuring of public finances, sustainability of
debt and calamity relief, have also been referred
to the FCs.
Debt position of States
7.15 Determining the correct size of the fiscal
deficit and the debt in relation to GDP is important
for prudent fiscal management. Debt-related issues
are dealt with by FCs as outlined in their respective
TORs. The Second FC was the first one to handle
the issue of State debt and to make
recommendations on rates of interest and terms of
repayment of Central loans made to States. From
the Sixth FC onwards, a review of the States’ debt
position has been explicitly included as a term of
reference. The Sixth FC was asked to make an
assessment of the non-Plan capital gap of the
States on a uniform and comparable basis for the
five years ending with 1978-79. This required a general review of the States’ debt position with
particular reference to the Central loans advanced
to them and likely to be outstanding as at the end
of 1973-74 with a view to suggest changes in the
existing terms of repayment. Since then, the
assessment of the debt position of States has been
a regular feature of TORs of most of the subsequent
FCs. It is observed that the major recommendations
related to grant of debt relief to States through
rescheduling and write-off of Central government
loans to mitigate the impact of high repayment
obligations on State finances. However, TORs for
the Ninth and Tenth FCs were more elaborate
because they were asked to review the entire debt
position of States rather than only Central
government loans advanced to them. These FCs
differed in their approach towards the issue of debt
relief to States. This was driven by the belief that
the debt relief measures by successive FCs created
anticipations about such measures in future with a
built-in adverse incentive. In recognition of the fact
that debt relief often underwrites lack of fiscal
discipline in the past, the Tenth FC recommended,
for the first time, that general debt relief be linked
to fiscal performance. The Eleventh FC continued
the same principle with some modification in
operational modalities.
7.16 The TOR in respect of the debt position of
States in the Twelfth FC was more elaborate. Apart
from suggesting debt sustainability measures, it
was asked to recommend debt relief measures
together with the objective of macroeconomic
stability. In addition, the recommendations were to
be linked to the performance of States in the fields
of human development and investment climate. The
Twelfth FC, therefore, followed a two-pronged
approach to debt relief. First, a general scheme of
debt relief applicable to all States by consolidating
the past debt and rescheduling it, along with interest
rate reduction, was devised. Second, a debt writeoff
scheme linked to fiscal performance, i.e., a
reduction in absolute level of revenue deficit, was
introduced. A significant development was the
stipulation by the Twelfth FC that fiscal
responsibility legislation by each State would be a
necessary pre-condition to avail of debt relief under
the debt consolidation and relief facility (DCRF). The Thirteenth FC was mandated to examine the
operation of the DCRF during 2005-10 as
implemented by the Centre and suggest measures
to ensure a stable and sustainable fiscal
environment that was consistent with equitable
growth. The Thirteenth FC held the view that the
benefits of consolidation under the DCRF facility,
limited to consolidation and interest rate reduction,
should be extended to those States that had not
yet availed of the same, subject to the enactment
of the FRBM Act. The Commission also suggested
that the benefit of interest relief on the NSSF and
write-off should be extended to States only if they
bring about the necessary amendments/
enactments of the FRBM.
Emphasis on Fiscal Reforms
7.17 Various FCs have been mandated to
examine concerns that have emerged from time to
time with regard to State finances. From the early
1990s, State finances came under stress as the
State governments started paying market-related
interest rates on loans from the banking system
and the Centre. Recognising the need to improve
the States’ financial position, State-level fiscal
reforms were explicitly emphasised in the TOR of
the Eleventh FC. In fact, under an additional TOR
the Eleventh FC was asked to review the position
of finances of the Union and the State governments
and suggest measures by which the governments,
collectively and severally, may restructure public
finances so as to restore budgetary balance and
maintain macroeconomic stability. In particular, the
Commission was mandated to draw a monitorable
fiscal reforms programme aimed at reducing the
revenue deficit of the States and recommend the
manner in which the grants to States to cover the
assessed deficit in their non-Plan revenue account
may be linked to progress in implementing the
programme.
7.18 Accordingly, the Eleventh FC recommended
creating a scheme of States’ Fiscal Reform Facility
(FRF) for the period 2000-01 to 2004-05, backed
by a Fiscal Reform Facility Incentive Fund to
incentivise States to collectively eliminate revenue
deficits by 2004-05. The FRF Incentive Fund was constituted by the Government of India and States
were advised to prepare their Medium-Term Fiscal
Reforms Programmes (MTFRP) aimed at bringing
about necessary correction in the revenue deficits.
The release from the Incentive Fund was linked to
an improvement in single monitorable fiscal
indicator, i.e., revenue deficit (as a percentage of
revenue receipts) by 5 percentage points annually
(2 percentage points for special category States
prospectively with effect from 2002-03). The
MTFRP was accepted by all 28 States and MoUs
were signed with 27 States. Realising the
importance of fiscal discipline, some States enacted
fiscal responsibility legislations, while many States
also put in place medium-term reform programmes
with specific monitorable targets.
7.19 While reviewing progress under the FRF,
the Twelfth FC concluded that the FRF failed to
play a significant role in improving State finances
and hence recommended its discontinuation.
However, recognising the need for improving the
States’ medium-term fiscal situation, the Twelfth FC
decided to reflect upon the shortcomings in the
earlier debt relief, and suggested a detailed fiscal
reform path to enable each State to reach the
targeted revenue balances by 2008-09. While taking
note of the deterioration in the finances of the
Centre and the States in 2008-09 and 2009-10, the
Thirteenth FC suggested a fiscal roadmap for them
backed by the objective of maintaining a stable and
sustainable fiscal environment consistent with
equitable growth. The Commission suggested that
the States should amend/enact the FRBM Acts to
enable them to move towards the fiscal reform path
worked out for them. State-specific grants
recommended for a State should be released only
upon compliance with the stipulated norms. The
Thirteenth FC has also designed grants with the
specific purpose of incentivising improvements in
accountability, transparency and the public goods
delivery process.
Broadening the Issue of Relief Expenditure
7.20 The provisions relating to disaster
management in the Constitution of India are
ambiguous. Neither relief for natural calamities nor disaster management fall anywhere in the Union,
State or Concurrent Lists. Under Entry 97 of the
Union List, a subject that is not specifically
mentioned in any of the lists would ordinarily have
to be dealt with by the Union Government.
However, by convention this responsibility lies with
the States, while the Central government plays a
largely supportive role with financial, technical and
material support, whenever necessary. The
expenditure on post-disaster response, relief and
rehabilitation is generally incurred by the State
governments and is met from the annual allocations
made to the States on the basis of
recommendations by the FCs. In fact, the entire
system of financing relief for calamity expenditure
in India has evolved around the recommendations
of the successive FCs.
7.21 The issue of funding relief expenditure has
been recognised by each FC since the Second
FC. Since then, the FCs have made
recommendations with regard to providing relief
expenditure out of the revenues of the States and
the amount of support to be extended by the
Centre to the States. However, an institutional
mechanism to deal with natural calamities has
been put in place, as recommended by the FCs.
For instance, the Ninth FC recommended setting
up Calamity Relief Funds (CRFs) for each State.
Going further, the Tenth FC recommended the
establishment of a National Fund for Calamity
Relief (NFCR) in addition to the CRF. The Eleventh
FC recommended discontinuing the NFCR and
suggested that a National Calamity Contingency
Fund (NCCF) be set up with an initial corpus of
`500 crore to be replenished by the levy of a
special surcharge on Central taxes for a limited
period. The TORs of the Twelfth and Thirteenth
FCs included a review of financing of disaster
management under the NCCF and the CRF. Apart
from expanding the list of natural calamities, the
Twelfth FC recommended strengthening both the
NCCF and the CRF. However, the Thirteenth FC
suggested merging the NCCF with the National
Disaster Response Fund (NDRF) and the CRF
with the State Disaster Response Fund of the
respective States. It also suggested considering
funding of man-made disasters from the NDRF.
Specific Grants
7.22 Specific or special grants are generally
provided to States that are unable to spend
adequately to deal with State-specific problems
because of fiscal capacity constraints. Before the
Sixth FC, the FCs did not have any specific
mandate for making earmarked provisions through
special purpose grants. Nevertheless, specific
amounts were allocated through grants-in-aid to
improve and augment services, viz., the special
grants by the First FC to expand primary education,
special grants-in-aid by the Second FC to some
States, and special grants by the Third FC to 10
States to improve road and communications. While
recommending the grants, the Sixth FC was
specifically mandated to examine the requirements
of States that were backward in standards of
general administration to upgrade the same and to
bring them at par with advanced States over a
period of 10 years. Since then, the TOR of each
FC (with the exception of the Ninth FC) has
mentioned the upgrading or special problem grants.
To ensure better targeting of expenditure in certain
important areas, the FCs have recommended
specific grants mainly for the education and health
sectors, maintenance of roads and buildings,
drinking water, infrastructure, forests, and
protection of historical monuments, archaeological
sites and heritage buildings (that are not with the
Archaeological Survey of India).
Sharing of Profits from Petroleum and Mineral oil
Companies with States
7.23 An issue that many States have been raising
with the Centre relates to the ownership of land
and minerals and the royalty payable to States.
Under the Oilfields (Regulation and Development)
Act, 1948, the Centre has the authority to increase
or reduce the royalty rates. Consequent upon the
reduction in the royalty rates by the Central
government for faster development of these
sectors, many States raised the issue of
compensation for the losses after the project starts generating profits. The Twelfth FC was asked to
examine the issue of sharing the non-tax revenue
of the Central government from the profits of the
petroleum sector with the mineral oil-producing
States. The Commission recommended that the
non-tax income of ‘profit petroleum’ companies to
the Union, arising out of contractual provisions in
the case of New Exploration Licensing Policy
(NELP) blocks, may be shared in the ratio of 50:50
with the States in which the mineral oils are
produced.
4. Devolution of Resources from Centre to
States
7.24 Although the role of the FCs has expanded
significantly over the years, the basic mandate for
FCs in respect of distribution of taxes and grantsin-
aid to States has remained unchanged. Each FC
is required to determine the aggregate and
individual shares of the States in the shareable pool
of Central taxes under Article 270. The Commission
has to determine the aggregate share of States in
shareable taxes, specify criteria for deciding the
shares of the individual States, and the weights
attached to different allocation criteria. The
shareable pool of Central taxes has changed in its
scope and composition. Each FC has exercised
varying value judgements to determine the
approach and size of the vertical revenue transfers
(Chalam and Mishra, 1997)10 .
7.25 Prior to the 80th Constitutional Amendment,
two major Central taxes were mainly shared with
the States, viz., income tax other than corporation
tax and Union excise duties. The sharing of income
tax was mandatory, but the sharing of Union excise
duties with States was discretionary and could be
shared if Parliament by law so provided. Following
the 80th amendment of the Constitution, it became
mandatory for the Centre to share all Central taxes
(except taxes under Articles 268 and 269 and
earmarked cesses, and surcharges under Article
271) with the States.
Evolution of the Sharing Process: Vertical
distribution
7.26 The Constitution of India specifies the
taxation powers of the Centre and States. To deal
with the vertical imbalances between the Centre
and the States, the FC recommends vertical
transfers. These transfers act as an instrument to
deal mainly with the extant asymmetric
decentralisation of expenditure responsibility and
revenue-raising authority. In the process of
devolution of resources from the Centre to States,
there are two major modes of transfers, viz.,
States’ share in Central taxes, and grants. The
key factors for determining the States’ share in
Central taxes (vertical distribution) have varied
across FCs. Grants to States can be unconditional
and general purpose or conditional and purposespecific.
7.27 The most vital aspect of intergovernmental
fiscal transfers is the size of the distributive pool
of taxes which is available for transfers. Various
FCs progressively enlarged the size of the States’
share in income tax collections. It increased from
55 per cent as recommended by the First FC to
85 per cent as recommended by the Ninth FC. The
rationale for increasing the size of the States’
share in net proceeds of income tax has differed
across FCs. For instance, by raising the share of
the States in net proceeds of income tax, the Third
and Fourth FCs tried to compensate the States
for the loss they incurred on account of exclusion
of corporation tax in the divisible pool; the divisible
pool shrank due to the reclassification in 1959 of
income tax paid by companies as corporation tax.
Similarly, for the first time, the Fifth FC included
advance tax collections in the divisible pool of
income tax and distributed the arrears while
retaining the share of the States at 75 per cent.
Subsequently, the Sixth FC realised that the
arrears were no longer available to States and
recommended an increase in the States’ share in
divisible pool of taxes from 75 per cent to 80 per
cent for the award period 1974-79. Considering
the States’ grievance with regard to the levy of
surcharge by the Centre as a normal tax measure,
the share of States was again raised by the Seventh FC. The Eighth and Ninth FCs did not
recommend any change in States’ share in net
proceeds of income tax. However, the approach
of the Tenth FC towards the sharing of Central
taxes differed from that of the earlier FCs; the
Tenth FC held the view that the authorities
engaged in levying and administering tax
collections should get a significant and tangible
interest in its yield but changes in the share of
States should not materially impact the level of
devolution. Hence, the Tenth FC recommended a
downward revision in the share of States in net
proceeds of income tax to 77.5 per cent for the
award period 1995-2000 (Table VII.1).
7.28 Consequent upon the 80th Constitutional
Amendment and the enlargement of the divisible
pool of shareable taxes by including all Central
taxes, the Eleventh FC recommended a share of
29.5 per cent for States. This share included 1.5
per cent of shareable Union taxes to be distributed
among States and not levying or collecting sales
tax on the commodities covered under the
Additional Excise Duties (Goods of Special
Importance) Act, 1957. The Twelfth FC
recommended increasing the States’ share from 29.5 per cent to 30.5 per cent on the premise that
additional transfers can be accommodated by
rationalising the Centre’s participation in areas that
fall directly under the purview of the States. Taking
into consideration the factors, viz., (i) the higher
buoyancy of the Centre’s taxes than that of the
States during 2000-08, (ii) the States’ increasing
responsibility with regard to rural and urban
infrastructure and (iii) the increase in the Centre’s
non-tax revenues particularly from royalties and the
telecommunications sector, the Thirteenth FC
recommended raising the States’ share in Central
taxes to 32 per cent for the award period 2010-15.
Table VII.1: Recommended Share of States
in Major Divisible Taxes |
(Per cent) |
Finance Commission |
Income Tax
(%) |
Basic Excise
Duties (%) |
Number of
Commodities
Covered |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
First FC (1952-57) |
55 |
40 |
3 |
Second FC (1957-62) |
60 |
25 |
8 |
Third FC (1962-66) |
66.6 |
20 |
35 |
Fourth FC (1966-69) |
75 |
20 |
All |
Fifth FC (1969-74) |
75 |
20 |
All |
Sixth FC (1974-79) |
80 |
20 |
All |
Seventh (1979-84) |
85 |
40 |
All |
Eighth FC (1984-89) |
85 |
45 * |
All |
Ninth FC (1989-95) |
85 |
45 |
All |
Tenth FC (1995-2000) |
77.5 |
47.5 * |
All |
|
All Central Taxes# |
Eleventh FC (2000-05) |
29.5 |
Twelfth FC (2005-10) |
30.5 |
Thirteenth FC (2010-15) |
32.0 |
# Inter se Share of States in net proceeds of all shareable union taxes
and duties.
* 40% of the net proceeds to be distributed while the remaining 5%
would be earmarked for the non-plan revenue deficit States.
** 40% of the net proceeds to be distributed while the remaining 7.5%
would be earmarked for the non-plan revenue deficit States.
Source: Finance Commission Reports. |
7.29 Apart from sharing net income tax, States
were also dependent on their share in Union excise
duties to meet their revenue needs. As Table VII.1
shows the First FC made a modest beginning by
sharing Union excise duties with the States in
respect of three commodities, viz., tobacco,
matches and vegetable products. Successive FCs
recommended larger devolutions to the States
either by increasing the coverage of shareable
items or by increasing the States’ share. The
number of items included in the list of shareable
excise duties was increased from 3 to 8, albeit with
a reduced share of 25 per cent, by the Second FC.
The shareable basket of commodities in respect of
Union excise duties was further expanded to 35
commodities by the Third FC, but the share was
reduced to 20 per cent. Consequent upon the
demand by the States, the coverage of items for
the States’ share in union excise duties has been
made universal since the Fourth FC. The Seventh
FC recommended increasing the share of the
States in Union excise duties to 40 per cent, on
the grounds that providing sufficient resources to
States would reduce their dependence on the
Centre. The Eighth FC further enhanced this share
to 45 per cent but the increment of 5 per cent was
used to meet the assessed post-devolution revenue
deficit of States. The Ninth FC retained this scheme
in its first Report submitted for 1989-90, but in its
second Report for 1990-91 to 1994-95, the Ninth FC recommended distributing the entire amount of
45 per cent as a consolidated amount without any
separate component to be used for reducing States’
non-Plan revenue deficits11 . The Tenth FC
recommended a share of 47.5 per cent for States
in the net proceeds of Union excise duties while
setting apart 7.5 per cent of the Union excise duties
for distribution on the basis of assessed deficits.
With the 80th Constitutional Amendment, a single
pool has been prescribed for all shareable Central
taxes (except under Articles 268 and 269) since
the Eleventh FC.
7.30 To sum up, an analysis of the
recommendations of the FCs in respect of
shareable taxes and excise duties suggests that
various FCs have given due importance to States’
concerns with regard to their share in the divisible
pool and its composition. With the clubbing of most
Central taxes since the Eleventh FC, the shareable
pool of taxes has not only expanded but the States’
share in it has also increased.
Shareable Taxes and Union Excise Duties:
Horizontal Distribution Criteria
7.31 As regards the determination of the inter se
shares of the States, the basic objective of the FC
transfers has been to (i) correct the differentials in
revenue capacity and cost disability factors inherent
in the economies of the States and (ii) foster fiscal
efficiency among the States. The criteria used in
the past for these purposes can be grouped under
(a) factors reflecting needs, such as population and
income measured either as distance from the
highest income or as an inverse; (b) cost disability
indicators such as area and infrastructure distance;
and (c) fiscal efficiency indicators such as tax effort
and fiscal discipline.
7.32 As regards the weight of different variables
in the distribution criteria of net proceeds of income
tax, only two factors were taken into account till
the Seventh FC. Population was a dominant factor with the highest weight of 80 to 90 per cent, while
contribution in tax collection was a minor factor.
There was no change in the horizontal distribution
criteria of net income tax proceeds except that there
was some adjustment between the respective
weights of population and contribution. In contrast,
the Fifth FC felt that the appointment of a new FC
should provide an opportunity for a fresh look at
various issues in the light of changed
circumstances and available information. The Fifth
FC identified several inadequacies with regard to
contribution criteria (based on tax collections)
recommended by earlier FCs. It highlighted that (i)
contribution was determined by the convenience
of the assessees without reference to the origin of
income, and (ii) large amounts of tax deduction at
source on dividends, interest payments, etc. gave
the undue benefit of larger collections to States with
metropolitan and industrial centres. Therefore,
apart from population (with a weight of 90 per cent),
the Fifth FC added ‘assessment’ instead of
‘collection’ with 10 per cent weight in the distribution
scheme of income tax proceeds. This distribution
scheme remained unchanged till the Seventh FC
(Appendix Table 22).
7.33 Keeping in view the memoranda submitted
by various States, the Eighth FC noted that the
criteria for allocating income tax should be more
progressive. It recommended that 90 per cent of
States’ share in income tax remaining after
distributing 10 per cent on the basis of contribution
should be allocated based on population (with a
weight of 22.5 per cent, i.e., 25.0 per cent of 90
per cent), income-adjusted population (with a
weight of 22.5 per cent, i.e., 25.0 per cent of 90
per cent) and the distance of per capita income
(with a weight of 45 per cent, i.e., 50.0 per cent of
90 per cent)12 . The distance of per capita from the
highest per capita income was considered as a
measure of the relative backwardness of States.
Since population was used as a scale factor in determining the ‘distance’ and ‘inverse of per
capita’, its weight in the overall scheme was much
larger than 22.5 per cent. Subsequently, the Ninth
FC made a major change by introducing a
composite measure of backwardness with a weight
of 11.25 per cent. The composite indicator of
backwardness comprised two indices, viz .,
(i) population of Scheduled Castes and Scheduled
Tribes and (ii) number of agricultural labourers in
different States as revealed by Census 1981. The
Tenth FC adopted a different approach from the
previous FCs and stopped using ‘contribution’ as
one of the factors for the distrubution criteria. It
argued that the country as a whole represents a
common economic space and market, and
economic interdependence among States was
growing. Therefore, it was difficult to identify locally
generated income in the non-agriculture sector and,
hence, there was no need to retain ‘contribution’
as a criterion. The Tenth FC also discarded the
inverse income formula due to the implicit
convexity: middle-income States have to bear a
higher burden of this adjustment. Instead, it
assigned a larger weight of 60 per cent to distance
of per capita income along with population (20 per
cent) and some new factors, viz., tax effort (10 per
cent), area adjusted (5 per cent) and index of
infrastructure (5 per cent)13 . Therefore, there was
an explicit emphasis on incentivisation of States
for their tax efforts.
7.34 Assessing the prevailing fiscal situation of
the States, the Eleventh FC recommended
restructuring States’ finances through in-built
incentives for fiscal discipline and linking them to
the principles of devolution. The Eleventh FC
introduced a new index of fiscal discipline; tax effort
and the index of fiscal discipline were together
given a weight of 12.5 per cent. The Twelfth FC
evolved a new formula that balanced equity with
fiscal efficiency. Equity considerations, however,
dominated in the scheme of federal transfers implementing the equalisation principle.
Accordingly, it accorded 50 per cent weight to
income distance along with 25 per cent weight to
population. While ‘area’ was assigned a weight of
10 per cent, better fiscal management in terms of
tax efforts and fiscal discipline was given a higher
weight of 15.0 per cent by the Twelfth FC compared
with the 12.5 per cent weightage given by the
Eleventh FC.
7.35 The Thirteenth FC recommended using the
concept of ‘fiscal capacity distance instead of
‘income distance’. Instead of using a single
average of GSDP to assess the fiscal distance
between States, it recommended estimation of per
capita fiscal capacity at reasonably comparable
levels of taxation from their respective group
averages of non-special category and special
category States. The Thirteenth FC accorded the
highest weight to fiscal capacity distance (47.5 per
cent), followed by population (25 per cent), fiscal
discipline (17.5 per cent) and area (10.0 per cent).
7.36 In respect of Union excise duties,
population continued to be the largest determining
factor in the criteria for inter se share of States up
to the Sixth FC, although its weight decreased
from 100 per cent to 75 per cent. This weight was
further reduced to 25 per cent (a fall of 50
percentage points from the preceding
Commission) by the Seventh FC. Up to the
Seventh FC, the formulae used to determine the
income tax shares were clearly distinct from those
for the Union excise duties. Since the Eighth FC,
there has been a convergence between the two
sets of formulae (Appendix Tables 22 and 23).
There was a move towards unifying the formulae
for the inter se distribution of both income tax and
Union excise duties. Thus, the Eighth, Ninth and
Tenth FCs followed a unified formula for sharing
of income tax and Union excise duties. As noted
by the Twelfth FC in respect of sharing the formula
of Union excise duties, among need-based factors,
population and income distance gained
acceptance; among the cost disability factors, area
and infrastructure index distance tended to be the
preferred indicators; and among the fiscal efficiency factors, tax effort and fiscal discipline,
as measured by the ratio of own tax revenue to
revenue expenditure, were regarded as
appropriate.
7.37 The above discussion suggests that while
determining the formula for horizontal distribution
of inter se shares of States, the basic aim of the
FCs has been to correct the differentials in revenue
capacity and cost disability factors inherent in the
economies of States and to foster fiscal efficiency
among States. The choice, definition and weight of
the variables used to define a devolution formula
kept changing across the FCs. While the greater
weight to ‘fiscal capacity distance’ in the tax
devolution formula of the Thirteenth FC is expected
to facilitate convergence among the States, the
increase in weight for ‘fiscal discipline’ would
encourage a reversion to the path of fiscal
consolidation.
Principles Governing the Design of Grant-in-Aid:
Shift from Gap-filling Approach to Normative
Approach
7.38 Besides the shareable Central taxes,
another important source of resource transfers to
the States from the Centre is grants-in-aid
contributions. Grant-in-aid are mainly targeted
towards achieving a degree of equalisation.
Generally, the amount of grants-in-aid provided
to the States by different FCs has been in respect
of their revenue gaps. Grants-in-aid under the FC
are meant to fill a gap which represents the State’s
expenditure not covered by its own revenue and
share in Central tax. Grants have been under the
constitutional obligation of the Union Government
as per Articles 273 (1) and 275 (1). In addition,
other kinds of grants have been given to the States
to (i) reduce disparities in the availability of various
administrative and social services across States;
(ii) allow particular States to meet special financial
burdens emerging as a result of their particular
circumstances; and (iii) provide resources for
specific activities considered to be national
priorities. In fact, grants-in-aid are considered as
an important instrument to make the scheme of transfers more comprehensive and address issues
spelt out in the TOR. Unlike the devolution
formula for Central taxes, grants provide greater
scope to make corrections for cost disabilities
faced by many States.
7.39 The guiding principles for grant allocation
among States as recommended by the First FC
were broadly followed by most of the subsequent
FCs. Under Article 275, the First FC recommended
that grants should be determined based on (i) the
budgetary needs of States, (ii) tax efforts, (iii)
economy in expenditure, (iv) equalisation of
standard of social services, (v) State-specific
obligations and (vi) broad purposes of national
importance. According to Srivastava and Rao
(2009), the First FC explicitly stated the best
theoretically accepted principles for guiding the
determination of fiscal transfers. The Second FC
observed that grants-in-aid should be a residuary
form of assistance given in the form of general
and unconditional grants; it was of the view that
grants for broad purposes may be given, provided
they were spent exclusively for that purpose. The
Third FC also recommended specific-purpose
grants for improvements in communications. Most
of the subsequent FCs generally agreed to the
principles laid out by the First FC, but they were
primarily in favour of unconditional revenue grants.
The Seventh FC made some departures from the
previous FCs while recommending capital grants
to meet capital expenditure as well. This was in
recognition of the fact that revenue grants were
not adequate for meeting the maintenance
expenditure on administrative and residential
buildings. Even though it was out of the purview
of their TOR, the recommendation of `908.8 crore
as capital grant was accepted by the Government.
7.40 Grants-in-aid are an important component
of FC transfers. The determination of grants
requires a comprehensive review of both the Central and State finances. The FCs have often
been criticised for their gap-filling approach that
leads to significant adverse incentives (Srivastava
and Rao, 2009)14. Under the gap-filling approach,
larger transfers depend mainly on a larger gap in
the revenue account in the past, irrespective of
whether the available revenue capacity was
adequately exploited or whether there was undue
growth in expenditures. Singh (2006) argues that
the gap-filling approach of grants reduced State
government incentives for fiscal discipline while
doing little to reduce inter-State inequalities15 .
However, the FCs, particularly from the Ninth FC,
to some extent have applied normative principles
to assess State’s own tax and non-tax revenues
as well as revenue expenditures. Under the
normative approach, adverse incentives can be
effectively neutralised as States are assessed in
terms of revenues that they ought to raise given
their respective capacities. Similarly, expenditures
are assessed on the basis of needs consistent with
an average or minimum acceptable level of
services and the relevant cost norms, and are not
driven by the past history of expenditures.
7.41 While recommending grants, the most
debatable issue across various FCs has been with
respect to coverage of Plan and non-Plan
accounts. The Constitution places no restrictions
on whether revenue account or only non-Plan
revenue account can be considered to assess the
resource needs of States. However, the Third FC
considered the needs of the States for the Third
Five-Year Plan and recommended that the
quantum of grants-in-aid should be fixed in such
a way that it enabled the States, along with surplus
out of devolution, to cover 75 per cent of the
revenue component of their plans. However, this
recommendation was rejected by the Government.
Subsequently, the consideration of needs of
revenue expenditure on Plan accounts was
dropped explicitly from the purview of the FC through specific stipulations in the TOR. However,
the TOR of the Ninth FC made it optional for the
Commission to consider Plan revenue expenditure
requirements. The Tenth FC again restricted the
ambit of consideration to the non-Plan account.
The TOR of the Eleventh FC explicitly included
consideration of both the Plan and non-Plan
requirements of States. Despite the Eleventh FC
considering revenue requirements only in respect
of the non-Plan account, the Twelfth and the
Thirteenth FCs were required to consider the
entire revenue account of the States.
7.42 To sum up, grants recommended by the
FCs have generally been unconditional and largely
based on the projected gaps between non-Plan
revenue expenditure and post-tax devolution
revenue receipts. This approach has often been
criticised as it does not provide for fiscal discipline
at the State level. However, of late there has been
an increasing emphasis on a normative
assessment of resource requirements and
expenditures while recommending grants to
States.
Pattern of Fiscal Transfers
7.43 In the present scheme of transfers, tax
devolution plays a dual role of correcting vertical
as well as horizontal imbalances. Grants-in-aid are
mainly targeted towards achieving a degree of
equalisation. In the transfer scheme of FCs, the
share in Central taxes has persistently dominated.
The share of grants-in-aid, intended mainly to fill
the non-Plan revenue gap, has remained less than
that of the States’ share in Central taxes, reflecting
the importance accorded by the FCs to the tax
efforts of States in the resource transfer to States.
Despite the grants being the more effective and
predictable transfer instrument for State-specific
and purpose-specific targeting, States have
preferred devolution of Central taxes as they are
unconditional.
7.44 A review of the awards by successive FCs
reveals that the quantum of resources transferred
to the States has grown significantly from `382
crore under the First FC to as high as `17,06,676
crore under the Thirteenth FC. However, the total
resource transfers in the form of States’ share in
taxes and grants exhibited compositional shifts over
various commission award periods. These shifts
are due to the interplay of factors such as changes
in the ratio of tax sharing between the Centre and
the States (vertical distribution), revenue buoyancy
in Central taxes (being shared with the States),
fiscal performance of individual States including
their non-Plan revenue deficit position and special
problems with regard to transfer of grants-in aid
(Kannan et al., 2004)16 . As Table VII.2 shows, the
States’ share in Central taxes in total transfers
declined from 87.9 per cent under the First FC to
75.8 per cent under the Fourth FC. The
recommended share in Central taxes was reduced
because the Fourth FC explicitly included financial
assistance to meet the residual deficit as grants
instead of share in Central taxes. Since the Seventh
FC, the share of Central taxes in total transfers
ranged between 80 and 90 per cent. In view of the
need to ensure a larger role for equalisation
transfers, the Twelfth FC had proposed to increase
the share of grants in the total transfers. However,
the Thirteenth FC has recommended a lower share
of grants in total transfers, as States are expected
to revert to the fiscal consolidation path and reduce
their non-Plan revenue deficit, which was witnessed
from 2004-05 to 2007-08.
7.45 Table VII.2 shows that there were
differences between actual share of devolution of
taxes (SCT) and grants (FCGR) and the respective
shares recommended by the FCs, though these
were not very significant. Srivastava and Rao (2009)
argue that the observed differences reflected nonadherence
to the stipulated conditions or delays in
submitting the relevant utilisation certificates for procedural reasons. The contribution of FC
transfers to revenue receipts of the State
governments remained in the range of 16 per cent
to 26 per cent across the award periods. However,
since the Sixth FC, transfers through the FC
channel have consistently accounted for around 25
per cent of the total revenue receipts of States. If the Central transfers through all other channels are
included, they contributed 28-42 per cent of the total
revenue receipts, during different award periods.
Similarly, the transfer of resources through the FC
channel enabled the States to meet around
one-fourth of their revenue expenditure in recent
years (Chart VII.1).
Table VII.2: Pattern of Transfers from Centre to States by Finance Commissions |
(Per cent) |
Finance Commission |
Recommended Transfers |
Actual Transfers |
Actual Transfers
from all agencies |
Taxes |
FC Grants |
Taxes |
FC Grants |
Share in Taxes |
Grants* |
First FC (1952-57) |
87.9 |
12.1 |
91.6 |
8.4 |
53.6 |
46.4 |
Second FC (1957-62) |
81.2 |
18.8 |
76.2 |
23.8 |
48.6 |
51.4 |
Third FC (1962-67) |
81.4 |
18.6 |
77.0 |
23.0 |
49.5 |
50.5 |
Fourth FC (1966-69) |
75.8 |
24.2 |
73.1 |
26.9 |
48.4 |
51.6 |
Fifth FC (1969-74) |
86.6 |
13.4 |
85.2 |
14.8 |
54.4 |
45.6 |
Sixth FC(1974-79) |
73.9 |
26.1 |
75.0 |
25.0 |
50.6 |
49.4 |
Seventh (1979-84) |
92.3 |
7.7 |
92.3 |
7.7 |
58.6 |
41.4 |
Eighth FC (1984-89) |
90.4 |
9.6 |
89.0 |
11.0 |
53.8 |
46.2 |
Ninth FC(1989-95) |
82.9 |
17.1 |
88.9 |
11.1 |
53.2 |
46.8 |
Tenth FC(1995-2000) |
91.0 |
9.0 |
90.2 |
9.8 |
60.1 |
39.9 |
Eleventh FC (2000-05) |
86.5 |
13.5 |
84.2 |
15.8 |
55.4 |
44.6 |
Twelfth FC (2005-10) |
81.1 |
18.9 |
82.5 |
17.5 |
54.6 |
45.4 |
Thirteenth FC (2010-15) |
84.8 |
15.2 |
– |
– |
– |
– |
‘–’ : Not applicable
Note: *: Includes grants by FCs and agencies other than FC.
Source: (i) Reports of Finance Commission, (ii) State Finances: A Study of Budgets (various issues), (iii) Rangarajan and Rao, 2008. |
5. Extent of Equalisation
7.46 The fiscal transfer system is expected to
address the issues of vertical and horizontal
imbalances. The equalisation component of
transfers is quite important in federations like
Canada where they have been mandated
constitutionally since 1982 to ensure that sufficient
resources are available to the provincial
governments for providing comparable levels of
public services at comparable levels of taxation.
The Australian system of equalisation transfers is
based on the criteria of cost differentials and equal
efficiency in the provision of goods and services
across provinces. The Australian equalisation
differs from the Canadian equalisation due to the
reference to efficiency and standard of services.
In a federal set-up like India where regional
variations in terms of per capita income, tax base
and population are quite large, the equalisation
component of central transfers assumes greater
significance. In the Indian context, Srivastava
(2006) argued that “for most of the early Finance
Commissions, transfers followed a fragmented
approach with different components of tax
devolution being subjected to different
considerations and the unconditional grants
followed a gap-filling approach. Since different
agencies dealing with transfers follow different
approaches, without much coordination, a unified
approach to transfers has not been developed. The
net outcome of this segmentation has been that
transfers have been far from equalising.”17
7.47 Unlike other federations like Canada, the
horizontal imbalance in India is resolved through
a combination of tax devolution and revenue-gap
grants. Based on the assessment of State finances
and macroeconomic conditions for the award
period, the FCs recommend State-wise total
transfers comprising the States’ share in Central
taxes and grants-in-aid. However, actual transfers to States may vary from the recommended
transfers, as some of the assumptions may not
hold throughout the award period. Despite this
conceptual distinction, it is difficult to separate the
vertical and horizontal (equalisation) components
of recommended fiscal transfers from the Centre
to the States (Rangarajan and Srivastava, 2008)18 .
However, a few studies have attempted to quantify
the vertical and equalisation components of
recommended transfers. In the Indian context,
Rangarajan and Srivastava (2008) attempted to
work out the equalisation component of total
transfers recommended by the Twelfth FC.
7.48 The framework adopted by Rangarajan and
Srivastava (2008), though subject to certain
qualifications, is being used in the study to quantify
the degree of equalisation in the total transfers
recommended by the recent four FCs (Tenth FC
to Thirteenth FC). It is found that the degree of
equalisation achieved was the highest in the case
of the Eleventh FC as the gap between the
benchmark and actual transfers was minimal. The
State-wise distribution of transfers appears to be
progressive as the State with the highest GSDP
gap has been recommended for higher
equalisation transfers, albeit less than the desired
level, particularly in non-special category States.
Furthermore, most of the special category States
received transfers for cost differential and special
needs (Box VII.1).
7.49 An analysis shows that the equalisation
component in the recommended transfers has
been less than the desired level in the case of all
four FCs. Given the level of disparities in India,
properly redistributing transfers to achieve full
equalisation is a formidable challenge. Unlike
other federations like Australia and Canada, the
major proportion of the Indian population resides
in recipient rather than donor States. In such a
scenario, it becomes a challenging task to achieve full equalisation as the extent of
redistribution implicit in the equalising scheme
is far larger. With income disparity among the
States being sizeable (the richest State had a
per capita GSDP nine times higher than the
poorest during 2005-10), equity has been an
important component in determining relative
fiscal needs since the Sixth FC. As observed by
Rangarajan and Srivastava (2008), these findings
need to be interpreted keeping in view various
qualifications20 .
Box VII.1: Transfers from the Centre to States: Degree of Equalisation
Fiscal transfers are deemed to correct not only the asymmetries
in decentralisation of expenditure to the States and the revenueraising
authority of the Centre (vertical imbalances) but also to
equalise the differences in fiscal capacities across States
(horizontal imbalances). However, the mechanisms to achieve
these goals have varied across countries. While Canada and
Germany follow an explicit equalisation mechanism of transfers
to attain equity, India has an elaborate framework of tax revenue
sharing, supplemented by revenue-gap grants. Even though the
Finance Commissions in India have recommended fiscal transfers
to address both horizontal and vertical imbalances, the
quantification of these two components of transfers is a complex
process. Rangarajan and Srivastava (2008) adopted a framework
to separate the vertical, horizontal and residual components of
per capita transfers to the States as recommended by the Twelfth
FC. The present exercise updates the results based on the same
framework to assess the degree of equalisation achieved across
the States since the Tenth FC.
Under the framework of Rangarajan and Srivastava, the vertical
component of transfers can be represented by the per capita transfer
made on the basis of the resource gap of the richest state, assuming
this to be the minimum benchmark allocation for any State.
Incorporating this principle, the total vertical transfers should be
proportional to the population of each State. The horizontal
component of transfers (equalisation transfers) allocable to a State
needs to be based on its per capita income gap relative to the richest
State; this incorporates the horizontal equity principle that States
with lower fiscal capacity, i.e., per capita GSDP, would get a higher
amount of transfers and vice versa in a progressive scheme of
transfers. This framework can be represented as:
ti= (e-βyn) + β(yn-yi) + resi for a State where resi > 0,
where ti denotes the recommended per capita transfers for ith State
government; [e-β.yn] (assuming that e>β.yn) represents the vertical
component with e being assumed to be constant based on per capita
expenditure norm, β denoting the average tax-effort, and yn the per
capita fiscal capacity of the highest income State; β(yn-yi) represents
the desired horizontal component; and resi denotes the residual
transfers for special needs.
The total transfers to States are derived by scaling up the per capita
components of transfers with their respective size of population.
An analysis of the relative shares of the three components in total
transfers shows that the share of actual equalisation transfers works
out to be the least and that of the vertical component the highest in
the case of the Tenth FC. In contrast, the vertical component
accounted for only 43.7 per cent of the total transfers recommended
by the Eleventh FC, while the share of the equalisation component
was the highest. As a result, the degree of equalisation, i.e., the
ratio of actual amount of equalisation transfers recommended by
the FC to the amount needed for equalisation, turned out to be the
highest in the case of the Eleventh FC. Although the Twelfth FC
emphasised the equalisation approach by focusing on education
and health, the degree of equalisation is estimated to be lower for
the Twelfth FC award period than that for the Eleventh FC period19 .
The degree of equalisation is estimated to have come down further under the recommended transfers of the Thirteenth FC. An analysis
of estimates for the residual components across the FCs since the
Tenth FC shows that around 13 per cent of transfers were used for
special needs (Eleventh FC) that have gone mainly to special
category States. The share of special need transfers declined in
the case of the Twelfth and Thirteenth FCs (Table A). A recent
study by Srivastava (2010), however, found that the transfer scheme
recommended by the Thirteenth FC would achieve equalisation to
the extent of 90.5 per cent of the desired level. The variation in the
estimated degree of equalisation to be achieved through the transfer
scheme of the Thirteenth FC appears to be mainly due to differences
in assumptions of the GSDP in terms of periodicity. While Srivastava
(2010) assumed average per capita comparable GSDP at current
prices for 2004-05 to 2006-07, centred in 2005-06 as used by the
Thirteenth FC to be the macro proxy for the tax base, the present
exercise uses the same during 2005-06 to 2009-10 (based on
projected GSDP for 2009-10 as explained in Chapter V).
Table A: Recommended Transfers by Finance Commissions:
Vertical and Horizontal Component |
(` crore) |
|
10th FC |
11th FC |
12th FC |
13th FC |
Total Transfers |
2,26,643 |
4,34,905 |
7,55,752 |
17,06,677 |
Annual Transfers |
45,329 |
86,981 |
151,150 |
3,41,335 |
Amount used for Vertical Transfers |
28,327 |
38,024 |
75,624 |
1,86,390 |
Amount for Equalisation Transfers |
13,301 |
37,856 |
63,388 |
1,39,064 |
Amount used for cost differential and special needs |
3,700 |
11,102 |
12,132 |
15,881 |
Amount Needed for full Equalisation |
30,328 |
42,388 |
97,971 |
2,64,729 |
Share of Vertical Transfers (%) |
62.5 |
43.7 |
50.0 |
54.6 |
Share of Equalisation Transfers (%) |
29.3 |
43.5 |
41.9 |
40.7 |
Share of transfers for cost differential and special needs (%) |
8.2 |
12.8 |
8.0 |
4.7 |
Degree of Equalisation achieved (%) |
43.9 |
89.3 |
64.7 |
52.5 |
The State-wise distribution of recommended and benchmark
transfers shows that the recommended equalisation transfers have
been progressive and generally followed the same pattern as the
desired equalisation transfers determined at the average tax-GSDP
ratio. Chart A presents State-wise recommended and benchmark
transfers in descending order in terms of per capita GSDP gap for
non-special category States except Goa. It shows that States with
a higher per capita output gap, in general, received higher per capita
transfers and vice versa, thereby satisfying the principle of horizontal
equity. A comparison of recommended and benchmark transfers
across different FCs also confirms that the degree of equalisation
was the highest in the case of the Eleventh FC as the gap between
the recommended and benchmark equalisation transfers was
minimum. As observed by Rangarajan and Srivastava (2008), the
findings for the non-special category States suggest that the pattern
of transfers in general follows an equalising approach and not a
gap-filling approach. They also found that all special category States
(except Assam) got substantial transfers under cost disability and
special need considerations (Statements 49 to 52).

|
References:
Government of India, Finance Commission Reports (10th FC to
13th FC).
Rangarajan, C. and D. K. Srivastava (2008), Reforming India’s
fiscal transfer system: resolving vertical and horizontal imbalances, Madras School of Economics Working Paper No. 31/
2008.
Srivastava, D.K. (2010), Vertical sharing and horizontal
distribution of resources: the equity and efficiency trade-off,
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. XLV, No. 48, November 27.
6. Conclusion
7.50 To sum up, the FCs have played a distinctive
role in inter-governmental fiscal relations in India. The
major points that emerge from the above discussion
can be summarised as: (i) even though the core
functions of the FCs have remained broadly
unchanged with respect to distributing the net
proceeds of taxes between the Union and the States
and defining the guiding principles for grants-in-aid of
revenues, the role of the FCs has considerably expanded as new challenges in the economic and
political environment emerged from time to time; (ii)
the approach of the FCs while defining the distribution
criteria and principles for distributing grants has
changed with a focus on relevant issues and concerns
of the States; (iii) despite the efforts made by various
FCs to capture State/region-specfic socio-economic
variations in their scheme of transfers, the impact of FC transfers on horizontal equity has been somewhat
limited as vast gaps continue to exist between the
actual and desired level of transfers for equalization;
(iv) the recommended transfers have been progressive
as the horizontal equity principle was generally
followed and States with lower per capita fiscal
capacities had a higher per capita share than others
and vice versa.
8 Kurian, N.J. (2008), ‘‘Equalising transfers through the Finance Commission’’, Economic and Political Weekly, 43(29), July 19–25.
9 Sury, M.M. (2010), Finance Commissions and Fiscal Federalism in India, Indian Tax Foundation, New Delhi.
10 Chalam, K. S. R. V. S and Rajiv Mishra (1997), ‘‘Streamlining norms: a renewed approach for Finance Commission’’, Economic and Political Weekly, June 21.
11 Instead of earmarking a separate portion out of shareable Union excise duties, the Ninth FC introduced a variable non-Plan revenue
deficit in its distribution formula of Union excise duties.
12 Income-adjusted population was worked out on the basis of the inverse of per capita income multiplied by the population of the State in
1971. Distance of per capita income of a State is worked out from that of the highest per capita income multiplied by the 1971 population
of the State concerned.
13 Tax effort was suggested to be measured by the ratio of per capita own tax revenue of a State to the square of per capita income of the
State. Thus, the respective shares were worked out after scaling by population.
14 Srivastava, D.K. and C. Bhujanga Rao. (2009), “Review of Trends in Fiscal Transfers in India”, at http://fincomindia.nic.in/writereaddata/
html_en_files/report02.pdf.
15 Singh, Nirvikar (2006), ‘‘State Finances in India: A Case for Systemic Reform’’, In S. Narayan (ed.), Documenting Reforms: Case Studies
from India. India: Macmillan.
16 Kannan, R. et al. (2004), ‘‘Finance Commission awards and fiscal stability in States’’, Economic and Political Weekly, January 31.
17 Srivastava, D.K. (2006), ‘‘Equalising health and education: approach of the Twelfth Finance Commission’’, Madras School of Economics
Working Paper No. 6/2008.
18 Rangarajan, C. and D. K. Srivastava (2008), ‘’Reforming India’s fiscal transfer system: resolving vertical and horizontal imbalances’’,
Madras School of Economics Working Paper 31/2008.
19 This estimate varies from that of Rangarajan and Srivastava (2008) mainly because per capita GSDP (yi) and own tax revenue as a ratio
to GSDP (β) in the present exercise are computed using the latest available data on GSDP for 2000-05 while they used GSDP for 1999-00 to 2001-02.
20 First, the equalisation benchmark is calculated with a revenue side approach using average tax effort while excluding expenditure side
considerations. Second, fiscal capacity has been measured in terms of revenue base available in terms of GSDP. Third, the highest per
capita GSDP among States, excluding Goa, is used as the benchmark. Fourth, shortfalls from the equalisation benchmarks are equally
weighted. Ideally, higher weight needs to be assigned to lower per capita income States for having shortfalls in equalisation transfers.
|