Regime shifts, first from the automatic monetisation of fiscal deficits to limited monetisation and then to Fiscal
Responsibility and Budget Management Act-led further curbing of monetisation, have considerably enhanced the
degree of freedom for monetary policy setting in India. However, newer challenges have emerged for fiscal-monetary
co-ordination under the new regime that requires attention on (i) the inflationary potential of large fiscal deficits
even without conventional monetisation, (ii) pro-cyclicality of fiscal spending exerting demand management
pressures on monetary policy and (iii) debt dynamics causing crowding out of private investment and impacting
monetary management. Against this backdrop, there is a need for new fiscal rules and for reassessing the welfare
costs of fiscal dominance of monetary policy.
I. Introduction
3.1 This chapter provides an assessment of
fiscal-monetary co-ordination in India, covering
institutional developments and empirical trends
and analysis. The evidence in the chapter suggests
that while several institutional changes have helped
bring about improved fiscal-monetary co-ordination
and moderated the fiscal dominance of monetary
policy, new challenges have surfaced that impinge
on monetary policy efficacy.
3.2 Section II discusses how large fiscal deficits
and consequent large market borrowings pose risks
of monetisation of deficits in newer forms and may
lead to a game-theoretic environment of sharing the
burden of adjustment amongst fiscal and monetary
authorities. Section III covers the evolution of
fiscal-monetary co-ordination in different phases
of institutional frameworks. Section IV focuses on
fiscal and monetary policy co-ordination in inflation
management. Section V analyses cyclicality in
government expenditure and its implications for
aggregate demand management. Section VI provides the empirical analysis on debt-deficit
dynamics in India. Section VII summarises the
policy implications of the analysis undertaken in
the chapter, making a case for tighter but cyclically
adjusted fiscal rules to further reduce fiscal
dominance of the monetary policy in India.
II. Fiscal Imperatives on Monetary Policy
Fiscal dominance of monetary policy moderates
but has not waned
3.3 Fiscal dominance of monetary policy has
moderated in India as a result of a series of fiscal
and monetary policy reforms undertaken over
the past two decades. The most notable of these
were (i) moving to a market-determined interest
rate system by introducing auctions of government
debt, (ii) phasing out of the automatic monetisation
of fiscal deficits through the two Supplemental
Agreements between the Government of India
and the Reserve Bank of India, and (iii) curbing
the monetisation of debt by enacting the Fiscal
Responsibility and Budget Management (FRBM)
Act, 2003 that prevented the Reserve Bank from
subscribing to primary issuances of government
securities from April 1, 2006. These landmark steps
have considerably reduced the fiscal dominance of
monetary policy.
3.4 During the same period, the Reserve Bank
undertook far-reaching monetary reforms, moving
from direct instruments to indirect instruments of
monetary policy by developing market-based public
debt markets. This, in turn, helped the economy
step out of a regime of financial repression
based on administered interest rates to vibrant
money and debt markets that allowed interest
rates to be largely determined by the market. The reforms pursued by the fiscal and monetary
authorities in tandem helped improve the efficacy
of macroeconomic management. However, newer
challenges emerged. Large subsidies, especially for
fuel, apart from adding to fiscal deficits limited the
demand adjustments and spilled over to the current
account. Large capital inflows financed the current
account gap but the capital flow volatility added to
interest rate and exchange rate pressures. At the
same time, open market operations (OMO), though
essentially a monetary tool, had to factor in the
large market borrowing at times to maintain orderly
financial conditions. In periods when inflation was
high, this, in turn, added to pressures on monetary
management. These require revisiting the issues
relating to fiscal-monetary co-ordination with a view to explore further changes in the broad framework
provided by the institutional and legal arrangements,
as well as instruments and practices. The changes
should help improve the efficacy of monetary and
fiscal policies by bringing about independence,
accountability and greater co-ordination.
3.5 On the one hand, there has been a regime
shift from the days of financial repression. The
automatic monetisation of debt has been phased
out. On the other, fiscal dominance of monetary
policy remains through high fiscal deficits and
administered price mechanisms or price rigidities
in the pricing of utilities despite big steps taken
towards reducing it. The conceptual debate on
what constitute monetisation of debt is discussed in
Box III.1.
Box III.1
Monetisation of Debt: Conceptual Debate
Monetisation of debt is a difficult concept to comprehend,
as it is not clearly defined. It can occur through several
practices that may be transparent, translucent, opaque
or hidden. For long, monetisation of debt was understood
as “converting government debt to money” or “the central
bank’s purchase of government bonds when they are
issued”. Either definition has its problems. Typically, the
government can finance its deficits by printing money or
issuing debt. The former directly attenuates monetary
control. In the modern world, with central banks in charge
of controlling the aggregate money supply, governments
typically finance their deficits by issuing government
bonds. They can either be purchased by the public from the
existing supply of money or by central banks by increasing
the monetary base, and hence the money supply. The key
question is whether any purchase of government securities
by the central bank would tantamount to monetisation of
debt.
Central banks, conducting monetary policy through open
market operations, purchase (or sell) securities to infuse
(or absorb) liquidity. They do so to adjust the monetary
base and/or the interest rates in line with their targets.
These operations are often conducted on a day-to-day
basis, sometimes more than once a day. So, if mere
purchase of government securities by the central bank is
seen as monetisation, almost all central banks do it almost
all the time. So, does monetisation reflect the central
bank’s purchase of government securities in primary but
not secondary markets? This distinction would only work
as long as central banks do not indulge in open market
purchases to support the government’s debt financing. If the central banks go on infusing liquidity to support the
banking sector’s purchases of government bonds even
while not subscribing to its primary issuances, the net result
would be the monetisation of debt. Central bank purchases
of government securities expand the monetary base,
but the finer distinction for monetisation is whether such
purchases are in support of government debt operations.
In practice, it is still hard to make a black-and-white
distinction between what portion of the central bank’s
purchases of government securities is for the purpose
of the conduct of monetary policy and what proportion is
in support of government’s borrowings. The key to this
judgment lies in central bank’s purchases of government
bonds being in alignment with its target of base money
and money supply expansion. These targets should be
set independently of debt management considerations. In
practice, many central banks today do not target monetary
aggregates. They instead rely on interest rate targeting
and operate on the short-term policy rate – typically, the
overnight rate or a 14-day repo rate. They exercise control
over bank reserves and interest rates through open market
operations that are conducted both through repo operations
and outright sales/ purchases at the longer end of maturity.
This is particularly true in the case of quantitative easing.
Consequently, monetisation of some form can occur by
impacting the yield curve.
Reference
Thornton, Daniel S. (2010), “Monetising the Debt”,
Economic Synopses No.14, Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis.
3.6 Although the enactment of the FRBM
Act, 2003 has prohibited the Reserve Bank from
participating in primary issuances of government
securities, it is evident that large fiscal deficits can
potentially lead to some form of monetisation of
debt. This is more important if large borrowings
crowd out private credit and compel monetary
authorities to provide greater liquidity through
open market purchase of government bonds. This
attenuates monetary policy efficacy (Chart III.I).
3.7 India has made rapid strides towards
phasing out the monetisation of debt. For long,
government deficits were automatically monetised
through the issuance of ad hoc treasury bills. These
bills of 91-day maturity were non-marketable
instruments that were automatically issued to the
Reserve Bank to replenish the central government’s
cash balances with it to meet the government
deficit. This problem of automatic monetisation was
in addition to the financial repression caused by
issuances of 91-day treasury bills “on tap” (at a
fixed discount of 4.6 per cent per annum), which
were taken up mainly by banks for short-term
investment or to comply with the requirements of
maintaining the Statutory Liquidity Ratio (SLR).
Financing government expenditure by issuing ad hoc
treasury bills to the Reserve Bank caused an
increase in the reserve money. In addition, the
Reserve Bank also rediscounted the tap treasury
bills subscribed to by the banks, thus adding to the
monetisation. Recent measures to reduce monetisation of debt in India are discussed in
Box III.2.
3.8 Fiscal dominance of monetary policy
goes beyond the monetisation issue. It occurs in
several forms. Large fiscal deficits have inflationary
consequences even when they are not financed by
the central bank. For instance, suppressed inflation
remains a significant drag on inflation management
even after the government has taken some steps to
deregulate administered prices in the energy sector.
At the first stage, suppressed inflation feeds into
inflation as the subsidies necessitated by the price rigidity widen the fiscal deficit. At the second stage,
as subsidies become unsustainable, they sooner
or later necessitate large discrete price adjustment
that feeds into inflation expectations. At the current
juncture, if prices are adjusted in one go to remove
total under-recovery of the oil marketing companies
and prices of coal and electricity are adjusted
upwards by a moderate 10 per cent each, the direct
impact would increase wholesale price index (WPI)
by 4 per cent. This suggests the persistence of fiscal
dominance of monetary policy. In terms of the Fiscal
Theory of Price Level (FTPL), fiscal dominance
occurs in a weak or a strong form. In the weak form,
fiscal dominance occurs when money growth rises
to accommodate fiscal deficit and so exerts upward
pressure on inflation. In the strong form, even if the
level of money supply does not change in response
to the fiscal gap, the latter independently raises
the level of inflation because of its impact through
aggregate demand. The weak form suggests that
a central bank cannot target inflation because
it cannot control money supply under the fiscal
dominance. The strong form implies that inflation is
not necessarily a monetary phenomenon and fiscal
policy instead drives inflation.
Box III.2
Monetisation of Debt in India
Since the late 1980s, several steps were taken to reduce
the fiscal dominance of monetary policy. First, the Reserve
Bank and the government moved to establishing a market-based
public debt market. Auctions of 182-day treasury
bills was introduced from November 1986, 364-day
treasury bills from April 1992, and 91-day treasury bills
from January 1993. As auction-based yields were higher,
an increasing part of the government borrowings came
to be financed through market sources, enabling a better
control of reserve money by the Reserve Bank.
Second, two Supplemental Agreements were signed
between the Reserve Bank and the Government of India.
The first, signed on September 9, 1994, limited the creation
of ad hoc treasury bills during the three-year period ending
1996-97. The net issue of ad hoc treasury bills was capped
on an end-year basis. Also, it was agreed that if it exceeded
the stipulated limit for 10 consecutive working days during
the year, the Reserve Bank would automatically reduce the
excess by auctioning the treasury bills or dated securities. The Second Supplemental Agreement signed on March
6, 1997 completely phased out funding through ad hoc
treasury bills and the outstanding amount of treasury bills
as at end-March 1997 was converted into special undated
securities at a yield of 4.6 per cent.
A system of Ways and Means Advances (WMA) was put
in place from April 1, 1997. Under the WMA system, the
Reserve Bank has been extending short-term advances up
to the pre-announced half-yearly limits, fully payable within
three months. The Government of India has also been
allowed to incur an overdraft but at an interest rate higher
than that of the WMA. Effective April 1, 1999, the overdraft
has been restricted to a maximum period of 10 working
days. Further, it was agreed that the Reserve Bank would
trigger fresh floatation of government securities whenever
75 per cent of the WMA limit was reached. It was also
agreed that the government’s surplus cash balances with
the Reserve Bank, beyond an agreed level would be
invested in governments own securities.
Even after a cessation of automatic monetisation of
debt through termination of the ad hoc treasury bills,
monetisation continued in another form. The Reserve Bank
continued to subscribe to the primary issuances of public
debt as a result of devolvement of auctions on the Reserve
Bank as the underwriting capacity of the primary dealers
(PDs) was limited. As such, the third major step towards
phasing out the monetisation of debt was taken with the
enactment of the FRBM Act, 2003 that barred the Reserve
Bank from subscribing to the primary issuances of the
government from April 1, 2006.
Has the monetisation been completely phased out in
India now that the Reserve Bank no longer subscribes to
the primary issuances in government auctions? De-facto
monetisation has been considerably phased out, but not
completely. As long as fiscal deficits remain large, the
size of market borrowings would also remain large and
impinge upon the conduct of monetary policy, no matter
how the debt management is conducted. The size of the
government’s net market borrowing programme (dated
securities) increased nearly 9.7 times in eight years to `4.9
trillion in 2012-13. In addition, the government resorted
to an additional funding of `1.16 trillion through 364-
day treasury bills. During this period, the Reserve Bank
conducted large net open market purchases that included
`945 billion in 2008-09, `755 billion in 2009-10, `672 billion
in 2010-11 and `1.3 trillion each in 2011-12 and 2012-13
(untill January). While in principle the Reserve Bank uses
open market operations to impact liquidity and monetary
conditions, in practice it is not easy to decipher what part
of the open market operations were undertaken purely on
these very considerations and what part might have been
influenced by the consideration that large government borrowing may not be market disruptive. During 2008-
09, OMOs were in sync with monetary policy easing
undertaken in that year on the back of the global financial
crisis. However, between March 2010 and October 2011
monetary policy was clearly in a tightening mode. Whether
OMO purchases in this period attenuated monetary policy
efficacy could be a matter of debate and research. On
balance, OMO purchases undertaken since 2009-10 have
not resulted in monetary expansion beyond what was
envisaged under the monetary policy. OMO purchases
during this period, by and large served both monetary
policy and debt management objectives. For instance,
during 2011-12 the government did aditional market
borrowings of nearly `2 trillion (including treasury bills) over
the budgeted amount, while the central bank needed to
create reserve money to ease the tight liquidity situation.
OMOs also helped to reduce the liquidity tightness arising
out of foreign exchange market intervention by the Reserve
Bank. During 2012-13, however, with the interest rate cycle
reversing, high government borrowing, through its impact
on yield, may have weakened the transmission of lower
policy rates to other segments of the financial markets.
Therefore, the sheer amount of borrowings could still put
pressures on monetary policy.
Further, during 2008-09 when monetary and fiscal policies
acted in tandem to meet the extraordinary challenge
posed by the global financial crisis, monetisation of debt
also occurred through Special Market Operations (SMOs)
conducted by the Reserve Bank. The SMOs, introduced
in June 2008, enabled public sector oil marketing
companies to sell oil bonds to the Reserve Bank to raise
foreign exchange. These SMOs, de facto, weakened the
FRBM Act regime as it indirectly monetised government
deficits in two steps. First, the government by issuing oil
bonds understated the true fiscal deficit. Second, if the
government was to fund it through its own dated securities,
the Reserve Bank could not have subscribed to it in
primary issuances. However, as oil bonds lacked liquidity,
the Reserve Bank stepped in to provide the same, while
also resolving the dollar funding requirements of the oil
companies. This innovative instrument helped minimise the
pressure on interest rates as well as exchange rates. While
SMOs were small in size, they helped serve the crisis
management objectives. Large government borrowing
and large open market purchases, however, at times pose
a macroeconomic challenge to the extent that they could
lead to monetisation of debt.
References
Rangarajan, C. (2007), “Indian Banking System:
Challenges Ahead”, First R.K. Talwar Memorial Lecture,
Indian Institute of Banking and Finance, July 31, 2007.
III. Interaction between fiscal and monetary
policy under different regimes
3.9 Fiscal and monetary policy interactions
have evolved over the past three decades in
accordance with the frameworks adopted for fiscal
and monetary policies. Based on these frameworks,
the following five broad phases may be identified.
Phase I: High fiscal dominance from 1980-81 to
1990-91
3.10 The decade of the 1980s saw excessive
deficits. The Centre’s gross fiscal deficit (GFD)/GDP
ratio averaged 6.7 per cent, which was markedly
higher than the average of 3.8 per cent for the
1970s. The states’ fiscal position also deteriorated
with their average GFD/GDP ratio widening to 2.8
per cent from 2.0 per cent during the same period.
Other deficit indicators worsened as well. The
fiscal slippage was more from the centre’s side and mainly originated from its revenue expenditure
side. Both tax and non-tax revenues as well as
capital receipts showed some improvement, but
capital spending remained constrained. The fiscal
deterioration placed a large burden on monetary
policy, with ad hoc treasury bills turning out to be the
route for automatic monetisation of fiscal deficits,
thus limiting central bank autonomy for achieving
monetary policy objectives.
3.11 Net Reserve Bank credit to the government
expanded at a rapid pace in the 1980s. This was a
direct consequence of the monetary accommodation
of high fiscal deficits in the 1980s. Reserve Bank
monetised deficits through ad hoc treasury bills.
This resulted in a sharp accretion in Net Domestic
Assets (NDAs). Monetary pressures were felt as
a consequence despite a sharp deceleration in
Net Foreign Assets (NFAs). Currency with the
public continued to see a secular decline, but the
expansion in NDAs came increasingly out of the net
Reserve Bank credit to the government. After two
oil price shocks, inflation did moderate until 1985-
86, but returned later on the back of large fiscal
expansion that could not be countered by monetary
contraction.
3.12 During the period, a regime shift in monetary
policy occurred with the decision to move from credit
budgeting to monetary targeting. Following the
Report of the Committee to Review the Working of
the Monetary System (Chairman: Prof. Sukhamoy
Chakravarty, 1985), the Reserve Bank introduced
monetary targeting in the mid-1980s. However,
the credit budgeting framework of direct allocation
of credit prevailed for most of the period. During
this period, the Reserve Bank announced its credit
policy twice during a fiscal year following periodic
credit budget meetings with the commercial banks.
The Reserve Bank indicated the broad guidelines
for deposit and credit growth, as also credit
deployment, to major scheduled commercial banks
(SCBs) after assessing macroeconomic aggregates
such as growth and inflation.
3.13 Fiscal dominance of monetary policy turned
out to be a binding constraint for monetary policy during this period. The Reserve Bank provided
liquidity to smoothen temporary mismatches
between sources and uses of funds of the
government and repeatedly expressed concern
about the link between fiscal deficit and excess
liquidity creation. The Chakravarty Committee
Report, which prompted the government to widen
the definition of ‘budget deficit’ so as to better
reflect the monetisation of the budgetary deficit,
also expressed similar concerns. The acceptance
of the wider concept of budget deficit was a major
step towards greater co-ordination between the
fiscal and monetary policies. The Committee, while
recommending the adoption of monetary targeting,
noted that the interrelationships among output,
money and prices are subject to complex lags and
that it is difficult to set out the precise operations of
these lags. As such, the link between money, output
and prices cannot be viewed exclusively within the
narrow time-frame of one year.
3.14 The transition to monetary targeting was
phased in only during the 1990s. No specific
monetary target was set during 1985-90 except
for fixing a credit ceiling linked to the average M3 growth in the previous year(s). As such, credit
budgeting continued to be the broad framework
for moderating monetary growth, but targets were
generally overshot, since the private sector required
credit support in the face of the large draft of the
government on household savings. Credit policies
during the period were largely contractionary,
but their efficacy was dampened by the need to
maintain orderly conditions in the debt market.
3.15 The Reserve Bank juggled with the Cash
Reserve Ratio (CRR) as well as the Statutory
Liquidity ratio (SLR) and selective credit controls to
serve the conflicting interests of monetary control
and to meet large credit requirements. The CRR
reached its statutory ceiling of 15 per cent in 1989.
The Reserve Bank resorted to additional CRR on
incremental net demand and time liabilities (NDTL)
on various occasions until 1992. The Reserve Bank
also used administered interest rates – deposit
and lending rates – to conduct monetary and credit
policy.
3.16 A monetary policy framework based on an
explicit monetary targeting regime was adopted
only in 1991-92, when a real GDP growth of 3 to
3.5 per cent, an inflation rate of not more than 9 per
cent, and a significant slowdown in M3 expansion to
about 13 per cent was envisaged. Monetary targets
so set were overshot by a wide margin, with M3 growth turning out to be 19.3 per cent. Monetary
targeting for 1992-93 was based on the underlying
assumption of reduction of the monetised deficit
(net Reserve Bank credit to the central government)
which was “consistent with the government’s
declared objective of reducing the gross fiscal deficit
from 6.5 per cent of GDP in 1991-92 to 5.0 per cent
in 1992-93”.
3.17 Credit budgeting in India was not very
successful in the face of large fiscal dominance. It
ended up generating financial repression that kept
real interest rates low and disincentivised both
savings and investments. As a result, the economy
witnessed lower growth while inflation shot up.
Phase II: Exit from financial repression from
1991-92 to 2002-03
3.18 The second phase saw financial sector
reforms. It was marked by a gradual development
of market-based instruments to finance government
debt. The blueprint for these reforms was laid by the
Report of the Working Group on the Money Market
(Chairman: N. Vaghul) in 1987 and the Report of
the Narasimham Committee I, 1991. Several steps
were taken over a period of time. These included
the development of money market instruments,
the introduction of auctions of Government of
India (GOI) treasury bills, a reduction in statutory
pre-emptions through CRR and SLR and partial
deregulation of interest rates. Although 182-day
T-bill auctions were introduced in November 1986,
the price discovery at the short-end could improve
only after the introduction of 364-day treasury bills in
April 1992 and the extension of the auction system
to 91-day treasury bills in January 1993. These
policy initiatives together with the two Supplemental
Agreements (Box III.2) enabled a sizeable reduction in monetisation of deficits, which helped to moderate
the fiscal dominance of monetary policy.
3.19 During this period, monetary targeting was
actively pursued. M3 growth targets witnessed a
secular decline. The financial sector reforms during
this period, especially the development of an active
secondary market for government securities, laid
the foundation for moving from direct to indirect
instruments of monetary control in the medium-term.
The statutory pre-emptions for banks were
reduced from around 63 per cent in early 1992 to
35 per cent in a span of six years. The interest rate
structure was rationalised and term deposit rates
were deregulated.
3.20 The period was marked by a distinct
lowering of fiscal deficits until 1996-97. Around
the same time, the credit compression of 1995-96
contributed to economy slowing down beyond what
was envisaged. This resulted in both monetary
and fiscal policies facing unforeseen difficulties.
Monetary policy did ensure a substantial decline in
inflation in 1995-96, but with broad money growth
decelerating to below trend, there were persistent
costs for the real economy. Though fiscal-monetary
co-ordination improved during the period, there
were spells, especially during the credit crunch of
1995-96, when greater co-ordinated action may
have yielded better results.
Phase III: Fiscal and monetary prudence from
2003-04 to 2007-08
3.21 The financial sector reforms enabled the
Reserve Bank to shift from direct instruments to
indirect instruments of monetary control and the
period 2003-04 to 2007-08, as a result, was marked
by a regime shift. Simultaneously, fiscal reforms
were undertaken at an unprecedented pace with
the enactment of the FRBM Act, 2003. These policy
initiatives taken together helped to significantly
lower the fiscal dominance of monetary policy.
At the same time, surge in capital inflows during
this period, posed challenges for macroeconomic
management. The Reserve Bank resorted to large
OMOs to absorb surplus liquidity so as to sterilise capital inflows. In fact, OMOs were in liquidity
absorption mode through the second half of the
1990s and into the early 2000s.
3.22 The most critical reform that enabled an
improvement in the operating procedures for
the conduct of monetary policy related to the
introduction of the Liquidity Adjustment Facility
(LAF) in phases. In 1998, the Committee on
Banking Sector Reforms (Narasimham Committee
II) recommended the introduction of LAF, under
which the Reserve Bank would conduct auctions
periodically, if not necessarily daily. The Committee
envisaged that the Reserve Bank could reset its
repo and reverse repo rates, which would provide
a reasonable corridor for the call money rates. In
pursuance of these recommendations, the Reserve
Bank introduced an Interim Liquidity Adjustment
Facility (ILAF) to conduct repos and reverse repos,
which replaced the general refinance facility. The
ILAF helped reduce fluctuations in the money
market rates. In June 2000, the ILAF was replaced
by LAF with variable rate repo auctions. In April
2003, the multiplicity of rates at which liquidity
was being absorbed/injected under the back-stop
facility was rationalised. These changes enabled
the Reserve Bank to use LAF as a principal tool for
effecting changes in liquidity at the margin and to
conduct monetary policy by using the indirect tool of
LAF, inter alia, by setting repo/reverse repo rates.
3.23 The FRBM Act, which was enacted on
August 26, 2003 and came into force from July
5, 2004, unleashed a regime of fiscal rules to
restrain discretionary policies that tend to have an
inherent deficit bias. The move was prompted by
international experience that showed that several
countries facing huge fiscal imbalances had gained
through similar legislations and rules such as the
Medium-Term Financial Strategy in the UK, the
Gramm Rudman Hollings Act of 1985 in the US, and
the fiscal responsibility legislations in New Zealand
in 1994, Argentina in 1999, Peru in 1999 and Brazil
in 2002.
3.24 The Act stipulated that the central
government should take appropriate measures to reduce the fiscal deficit and eliminate the revenue
deficit by March 31, 2008 and thereafter build up
adequate revenue surplus. The Union Budget
for 2004-05, however, deferred the target for
eliminating the revenue deficit to 2008-09. The Act
also prohibited direct borrowings by the Centre from
the Reserve Bank from 2006-07 except through
Ways and Means Advances (WMAs) to meet
temporary mismatches in receipts and payments or
under exceptional circumstances.
3.25 In exercising the powers conferred by the
FRBM Act, 2003, the central government framed
the ‘Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management
Rules, 2004’, effective from July 5, 2004. Under
these rules, annual targets were set for the phased
reduction in key deficit indicators over the period
ending March 31, 2008. The rules also imposed
annual ceilings on government guarantees and
additional liabilities.
3.26 Fiscal-monetary policy co-ordination also
received a fillip from the Debt Swap Scheme
(DSS), which was recommended by the Finance
Commission. It enabled the state governments
to substitute their high-cost loans from the centre
with fresh market borrowings and a portion of small
saving transfers. Under the scheme, the states
swapped high-cost loans. During 2002-03 to 2004-
05, states swapped `1.02 trillion of their debt with
the central government. They financed this through
additional market borrowings of `536 billion or 53
per cent at interest rates below 6.5 per cent and the
remainder through the issue of special securities
to the National Small Savings Fund (NSSF) with
the interest rate fixed at 9.5 per cent. Though the
scheme was debt-neutral, it brought about long-term
benefits in lowering the cost of servicing debt
for the state governments.
3.27 Another example of fiscal-monetary co-ordination
in this period came in the form of
introduction of the Market Stabilisation Scheme
(MSS). The scheme aimed at improving monetary
policy that was expected to lose its efficacy in the
face of paucity of instruments to sterilise liquidity
arising from large capital inflows that required intervention in the foreign exchange markets.
The initial burden of sterilisation was borne by the
outright transactions involving the sale of dated
securities and treasury bills. However, due to the
depletion in the stock of government securities, the
burden of liquidity adjustment shifted to LAF. The
LAF was essentially designed to handle marginal
liquidity surpluses/deficits. For absorbing the
liquidity of a more enduring nature, the MSS was
conceived.
3.28 The Government of India and the Reserve
Bank signed a Memorandum of Understanding
(MoU) on March 25, 2004 and the MSS scheme
was launched on April 1, 2004. Under the MSS,
treasury bills and dated securities were issued by
the government. The proceeds of the MSS were
sequestered by holding them for the government
in a separate identifiable cash account maintained
and operated by the Reserve Bank. The amounts
credited into the MSS account could be appropriated
only for the purpose of redemption and/or buy-back
of the treasury bills and/or dated securities issued
under the MSS. MSS securities were treated as
eligible securities for the SLR, repo and LAF.
3.29 A large number of countries, such as Chile,
China, Colombia, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Peru,
Philippines, Russia, Sri Lanka, Taiwan and Thailand
have issued central bank securities. However, the
central banks of many of these countries faced
deterioration in their balance sheets. As such, the
MSS considerably enhanced the degree of freedom
for monetary policy. It strengthened the Reserve
Bank’s ability to conduct exchange rate and
monetary management operations. It also enabled
the Reserve Bank to use the MSS tool flexibly to
both absorb and impart liquidity later when needed.
Phase IV: Co-ordinated and unco-ordinated
responses from 2008-09:
3.30 The last phase starting 2008-09 is an
interesting one. On the one hand, it witnessed a
high degree of co-ordinated fiscal-monetary policy
response in the face of the contagion from the
global financial crisis and the resultant slowdown of the global economy. Fiscal and monetary policies
provided a co-ordinated stimulus to counter the
sudden loss of confidence that could have rapidly
caused a downward spiral in the domestic economy.
Following the collapse of Lehman Brothers, the
Reserve Bank announced a slew of monetary
and liquidity easing measures from October 2008
to January 2009. For example, in a co-ordinated
move in early December 2008, the fiscal authorities
simultaneously announced a package that included
an across-the-board 4-percentage points cut in
central VAT for non-petroleum products, a support
package to Micro, Small and Medium Enterprises
(MSMEs), sops to exporters, and permission for
India Infrastructure Finance Company Limited
(IIFCL) to raise `100 billion (about US$2 billion) through tax-free bonds. The Reserve Bank’s steps
included a 100 basis points cut in its policy rates
and an additional refinance package of `110 billion.
3.31 The fiscal-monetary co-ordination in
the aftermath of the global financial crisis was
accompanied by less co-ordination on how the
fallout of the stimulus might be handled. As a
result, there were some un-co-ordinated responses
during the period of exit from the stimulus. An
underfunded budget and the fiscal stimulus of
2008-09 left awry the budgeting mathematics
during the year. Net market borrowings more
than doubled from the initial estimates, providing
a setting for a ‘game of chicken’ to be played
between the fiscal and monetary authorities
(Box III.3).
Box III.3
Monetary and Fiscal Policy Interactions and the Game of Chicken
Monetary and fiscal policies need co-ordination for
macroeconomic management. In practice, this co-ordination
sometimes brings about a game-theoretic
environment in which fiscal and monetary authorities face
a two-person non-co-operative game. Following Buiter
(2010)’s description of ‘Game of Chicken’ used to analyse
the interaction of the central bank and the Treasury in the
euro area, there has been a recognition that central banks
and fiscal authorities often test each other to see who blinks
first and makes the required adjustment to accommodate
the other.
In the game of chicken, also known as the hawk-dove or
snowdrift game, each player prefers not to yield to the other
and the worst possible outcome occurs when both players
do not yield. An easy real life situation to understand this
game is when two car drivers are headed on a collision
course. One of the drivers must swerve to avoid a crash
that could kill both, but if one driver swerves he is called
“chicken” or a coward. In terms of payoffs, the loss from
swerving (or being called “chicken”) is trivial compared to
the huge loss to both in the case of a crash. A typical pay-off
example is:
|
Swerve |
Go head-on |
Swerve |
(0,0) |
(-1,+1) |
Go head-on |
(+1,-1) |
(-10, -10) |
The pure strategy equilibriums are ones in which one player
swerves and the other does not. But in the absence of co-ordination, neither can know if the other one will swerve
and a reasonable strategy, therefore, would be to swerve
before a fatal crash. But if one believes one’s opponent is
reasonable, one may decide not to swerve at all, ending up
in the worst Nash-type outcome.
An oft-cited example of the game of chicken has been the
current strategic interaction between the European Central
Bank (ECB) and the several national fiscal authorities in
the euro area. The ECB by law is mandated to seek price
stability and pursue any other objective, if and only if, it
does not conflict with its prime objective of price stability.
However, with fiscal authorities, in some of its member
countries, facing a sovereign debt crisis, ensuring solvency
has become one of its proximate goals, if not an explicit
one. The ECB knew that a sovereign default in any of the
PIIGS (Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, and Spain) could
spark uncontrollable contagion, posing financial stability
and growth risks that would be difficult to manage.
The ECB is seen to want price and financial stability, while
fiscal governments are perceived to want ECB financing
to avoid default on government debt. The fiscal authorities
may encourage the ECB to undertake quasi-fiscal activities
by taking sovereign and private credit risk on its balance
sheet. However, the ECB’s concern is that any quantitative
easing (QE) it undertakes should be non-inflationary. The
ECB has a monopoly in supplying base money and so the
seigniorage benefits at least initially are appropriated by it.
However, monetisation of public debt may have occurred in
some form as a result of the ECB’s 3-year Long-term Repo
Operations (LTRO) since December 2011.
Even before the onset of the global financial crisis,
Buiter and Sibert (2005) proposed a radical change in
the operating procedures of the ECB aimed at restoring
market discipline and tackling unsustainable fiscal deficits.
The ECB was seen as trying to restore a first-mover
advantage in the game of chicken. The ‘Fiscal Theory of
Price Level (FTPL)’ suggests that fiscal deficits may or may
not lead to high inflation depending on whether there is
fiscal dominance or monetary dominance in this game of
chicken. In the case of fiscal dominance, runaway deficit
increases, which eventually forces the central bank to blink
and to monetise the deficit, i.e. to increase seigniorage and
use the inflation tax to finance an exogenous fiscal deficit
path. If there is monetary dominance, the central bank
commits not to monetise the fiscal deficits and then the
fiscal authority is forced to blink and adjust its budgetary
policy by cutting spending or raising taxes to satisfy its
inter-temporal budget constraint. If neither authority blinks,
the default risk increases as interest rates go higher and
the debt dynamics worsens.
The FTPL offers a resolution of Sargent and Wallace’s
(1981) unpleasant monetarist mathematics that provides
a setting for the game of chicken in macroeconomic
management. In a seminal 1981 paper titled, “Some
unpleasant monetarist arithmetic”, they show that even
if inflation in the short-run is a monetary phenomenon, it
remains a fiscal phenomenon in the long-run. This follows
from the government budget constraints and the limits
to public debt that can be held by the private sector.
Together, these ensure that in the long-run, the growth
of money stock is governed by the fiscal deficit as fiscal
authorities act as Stackelberg leaders, while monetary
authorities act as Stackelberg followers. The Stackelberg
model is a strategic game in economics in which the leader
firm moves first while the follower firms move sequentially,
and it offers a solution to well-known price determinacy puzzles. More fundamentally, the FTPL suggests that the
consolidated government present value budget constraint
is an optimality condition, rather than a constraint on
government behaviour and it shows how Ricardian and
non-Ricardian notions of wealth effects play a role in price
determination and household consumption. Strong forms
of the FTPL suggest strange cases where this no-blink twosided
game leads to a jump of the initial price level (high
inflation) to ensure that the government’s inter-temporal
budget constraint is satisfied.
In a real world, in the game of chicken, generally fiscal
dominance is a rule and monetary dominance turns out to
be the exception. India is not unique to this general rule.
Large fiscal deficits have at times caused ‘game of chicken’-
like situations. If the central bank pursues its monetary
objectives by not accommodating the debt financing in its
strategy calculations, the macroeconomic outcome may be
inferior for both the fiscal and monetary authorities, as well
as for the economy as a whole. As such, macroeconomic
management has to be conducted keeping the compulsion
to avoid disastrous consequences.
References
Buiter, Williams and Anne C. Sibert (2005), “How the
Eurosystem’s Treatment of Collateral in its Open Market
Operations Weakens Fiscal discipline in the Eurozone
(and What to Do About it)”, Conference ‘Fiscal Policy and
the Road to the Euro’, organised by the National Bank
of Poland and the Central Bank of Hungary in Warsaw,
June 30 - July 1, 2005.
Libich, Jan, Dat Thanh Nguyen and Petr Stehlik (2011),
“Monetary Exit Strategy and Fiscal Spillovers”, CAMA
Working Paper 4/2011, Australian National University
Rapoport, A. and A.M. Chammah (1966), “The Game of
Chicken”, American Behavioral Scientist, 10.
Sargent, T. and N. Wallace (1981), “Some Unpleasant
Monetarist Arithmetic”, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, Quarterly Review 1–17.
3.32 Fiscal dominance has, however, been
reduced in India considerably by adopting a co-operative
framework with a view to minimise
‘game of chicken’ situations. The Supplemental
Agreements, the FRBM Act, the Finance
Commission reports, and the Market Stabilisation
Scheme (MSS) are all examples that have
contributed to developing co-operative strategies
for fiscal-monetary policy interactions. Often both the authorities have formally or informally discussed
their plans with one another and/or signalled
their intentions convincingly before a ‘game of
chicken’ situation develops. Credible signalling
is a useful strategy to further co-ordination. For
fiscal authorities, the fiscal rules are the best form
of credible signalling for swerving. However, these
rules have been reneged upon in events of stress
or due to political cycles.
3.33 The year 2008-09 proved to be one example
when the Union government ended up with a GFD/
GDP of 6.0 per cent against the budgeted deficit of
2.5 per cent and the net market borrowings turned
out to be `2.34 trillion against the budgeted level of
`1 trillion. The fiscal slippage was unprecedented.
Fiscal authorities did not clearly signal such
slippage early on and the sudden large extra market
borrowings in the last quarter resulted in 10-year
benchmark yield that had fallen to 5.0 per cent at
end-December 2008 to rise by 200 basis points to
7.0 per cent by end-March 2009. This was in spite
of the Reserve Bank undertaking outright open
market purchases of about `890 billion in the last
quarter of 2008-09 to avert a possible interest rate
shock at a time when monetary policy resorted to
unprecedented easing.
3.34 During 2009-10, the GFD-GDP ratio turned
out to be 6.4 per cent against the budgeted deficit
of 6.5 per cent. The net market borrowings were
`3.98 trillion, in line with the budgeted amount. In
contrast, in the year 2010-11, the government had a
one-off revenue windfall through spectrum auctions
and divestments that helped in temporary fiscal
consolidation. As a result, the GFD-GDP ratio fell
to 4.6 per cent, which was well below the budgeted
level of 5.5 per cent. The year 2011-12 saw again
a fiscal slippage of 1.3 percentage points from the
budgeted level of 4.6 per cent. At the start of the
year, the central bank was credibly committed to
maintaining tight monetary policy, but extra market
borrowings of around `2 trillion (including treasury
bills) put some upward pressure. However, liquidity
tightened excessively due to several factors,
including the RBI’s foreign exchange intervention
to check volatility in the market since August 2011.
OMO purchases were, therefore, to a large extent in
sync with the central bank’s objective of reduction
in excessively tight liquidity conditions. Avoiding
a game of chicken could best be pursued with
tighter fiscal and monetary policy rules and credible
commitment to these rules. These rules should
have some in-built flexibility to meet cyclicality –
economic as well as political – but could avoid
widening of structural deficits.
3.35 The exit from stimulus was far less co-ordinated
than the provision of the stimulus. The
CENVAT roll-back was deferred, putting added
pressures of monetisation of debt on monetary
policy. It was not clear who would be the hawk
and who would be the dove while withdrawing the
stimulus. The durability of quick recovery remained
uncertain and price pressures remained unclear for
long. The monetary policy again accommodated the
larger part of the exit burden. The widening of the
fiscal deficit following the global financial crisis that
includes a large structural component constrains
fiscal-monetary coordination. The revised fiscal
roadmap accepted by the government in 2012-13
would in part set the course correction. However,
the revised roadmap is more a response to
significant macroeconomic deterioration that had
already set in since 2011-12. The roadmap does
not sufficiently address the issue of quality of fiscal
consolidation. There has been over-dependence
on non-durable resources of revenue, inadequate
pruning of subsidies and undesirable reduction in
capital spending as part of this fiscal consolidation
strategy.
IV. Fiscal-Monetary Co-ordination in Inflation
Management
3.36 Maintaining a low and stable level of
inflation is one of the major goals of macroeconomic
policy. Since inflation is viewed by the traditional
monetarist approach as a monetary phenomenon,
monetary policy is recommended as the major tool
for inflation management. However, the role of
fiscal policy in inflation control is also recognised
both in terms of the impact of high fiscal deficit on
aggregate demand and inflation as well as short-term
inflation management through its policy of
taxes and subsidies. Also, given the two-way
interaction between fiscal deficit and inflation,
optimal co-ordination between monetary and fiscal
policies would be critical to achieve the goal of
price stability. This section attempts to understand
the role of fiscal and monetary policies in inflation
management and the implications of the interaction
between these policies on inflation.
Inflation and Fiscal versus Monetary Policy
3.37 Conventional economic theory promotes
the idea that monetary policy should focus on
business cycle stabilisation through counter-cyclical
policies when demand-side shocks to
output and inflation dominate, while fiscal policy
should focus on stabilising the impact of supply-side
shocks, keeping in view inter-temporal and inter-generational
budget constraints that arise from the
debt-deficit dynamics. The basic theoretical premise
of such an argument is that sustained high inflation
is generally caused by monetary factors. Also high
inflation is generally the result of high aggregate
demand, and control of aggregate demand could be
better achieved through monetary policy.
3.38 There also is a large empirical literature
on the link between fiscal policies and inflation in
terms of both the short-term and long-term effects
(Rother, 2004). The impact of high fiscal deficits
on inflation is seen from two different angles. An
increase in fiscal deficit would imply enhanced
government spending, which could lead to an
increase in aggregate demand and this could turn
out to be inflationary if the economy is operating at
or above potential level of output. Fiscal expansion,
however, may not raise inflation in the short-run if
the economic growth is below potential. It has been
argued that the unprecedented fiscal stimulus that
was used in India during the global economic crisis
had no immediate impact on inflation as it primarily
worked as a tool to partially offset the deceleration
in consumption and investment demand (Reserve
Bank Annual Report, 2009-10).
3.39 The short-term impact of the fiscal deficit
on inflation could also depend on the mix of
policies that the government plans to undertake
for macroeconomic management. If the fiscal
deficit increase is on account of a decrease in
indirect taxes, like the reduction in excise duty for
most manufactured products in India in the period
immediately after the global crisis, this could have
a dampening impact on final prices. Similarly, an
increase in generic subsidies could keep prices
below market clearing prices, thus making inflation suppressed in the short-run. Subsidies in the form
of direct cash transfers to final consumers, on the
other hand, could be inflationary in the short-run as
increased demand may push up prices. The impact
of a lower fiscal deficit on short-term inflation could
also vary depending on how the reduction in deficit
is achieved. If an increase in indirect taxes is used
as a tool to reduce the fiscal deficit, final prices
could go up in the short-run. Reduction in generic
subsidies could raise short-term inflation but would
have a favourable impact on inflation in the medium-term.
3.40 Persistent fiscal deficits would sooner or
later lead to the creation of money, which would
have inflationary consequences. Sargent and
Wallace (1981) argue that under conditions of fiscal
dominance, inflation could turn out to be more of
a fiscal problem. Empirical work exploring the link
between fiscal dominance regimes and inflation
has shown that governments often resorted to
seigniorage (or inflation tax) during times of fiscal
stress, which had inflationary consequences.
3.41 Studies that look at long-term trends try to
establish to what extent large and persistent deficit
levels have an impact on inflation. Short-term
studies, on the other hand, focus on the impact
of changes in fiscal policies, i.e., the impact of
fiscal shocks on inflation. More recent theoretical
developments based on the ‘FTPL’ suggest that
medium-term price stability not only requires
appropriate monetary policy, but also appropriate
fiscal policy. This theory considers price level
as the crucial adjustment variable to ensure the
fulfilment of the government’s inter-temporal budget
constraint. This constraint equates, in real terms,
the government’s current liabilities to the net present
value of government revenues, i.e., future primary
surpluses and revenues from money creation.
Under the condition that Ricardian equivalence
does not hold and with a strongly committed and
independent central bank, imbalances in the inter-temporal
budget constraint need to be adjusted
through shifts in the price level.
3.42 All these theoretical propositions explore
the link between fiscal policy and inflation based on
the premise that fiscal policy is a cause for inflation
and not a tool to control inflation. However, when
inflationary pressures emanate from the supply
side, the role of fiscal policy as a tool for inflation
control becomes crucial. Supply shocks generally
affect relative prices by raising the prices of some
commodities more than the general increase in
the price level. Thus, the problem of short-term
stabilisation can involve fiscal response to all types
of shocks, some of which may be distortionary as
prices are characterised by nominal rigidities. Fiscal
policy can mitigate cost-push shocks through off-setting
changes to tax rates/subsidies. Thus fiscal
policy can influence cost-push inflation in a more
effective manner. However, cost-push shocks
cannot be eliminated by fiscal or monetary policy
in isolation, because they influence the relationship
between the output gap and inflation usually in the
opposite direction (Kirsanova et al., 2009). Supply
shocks impact relative prices initially, but tend to get
generalised over time through second-round effects
from the wage price spiral. Therefore, monetary
policy would have to ward against supply shocks
causing generalised inflation by anchoring inflation
expectations.
Nature of Inflation in India and role of Fiscal and
Monetary Policy
3.43 The repeated occurrence of supply shocks
has been a key factor that influences the inflation
path in India. Since 1952-53, considering 5-6
months of double-digit inflation as high, nine
episodes of high inflation can be identified for India
(Mohanty, 2010). Supply-side factors like drought,
war, oil and international commodity price shocks
have been the major reasons behind most of these
observed inflation spikes. An analysis of inflation
experience in the recent period suggests that during
the past 20 years, the weighted contribution of
the ‘food’ and ‘fuel’ groups to overall WPI inflation
exceeded their combined weight in 16 of the 20
years (Chart III.2). This points to the structural
nature of inflation, because if supply shocks are assumed to be transitory, then high inflation in
food or fuel is supposed to be followed by low
inflation in the same category in the subsequent
period, thereby breaking the inflation persistence.
Conventional monetary policy tools to deal with
inflation might not be effective in a situation of
structural inflation, and inflation management would
require the fiscal intervention to correct imbalances,
notwithstanding the risk of a higher fiscal deficit,
which also could be inflationary. Fiscal interventions
with higher subsidies could only suppress inflation in
the short-run, which will manifest over time. On the
other hand, fiscal interventions to augment supply
through higher capital expenditure may increase
fiscal deficit, but could help contain inflation in the
medium-term.
3.44 Since the second half of the 1990s the
contribution of ‘non-food non-fuel’ inflation to overall
inflation has declined somewhat, whereas the
supply shocks have kept inflation highly volatile
(Chart III.3).
3.45 The causality of inflation emerging from
supply shocks to overall inflation indicates that
the inflation in the fuel group gets transmitted
to generalised inflation, while such effect is not
visible in the case of food inflation (Table 3.1).
The causality test indicates that the fuel inflation
does not get transmitted to food inflation, perhaps
indicating that the subsidised fuel for agriculture
limits the pass-through. Even though food inflation
does not directly cause generalised inflation, it
could indirectly impact generalised inflation through
the wage-price spiral.
3.46 Both domestic and external factors
contribute to the occurrence of supply shocks.
While domestic factors largely emanate from the
highly volatile output from the agricultural sector,
external factors include a spurt in international
commodity prices, particularly in the case of fuel and fertilisers. Increases in global fuel prices have
been quite significant in recent years, and have
become a major source of inflationary pressures.
Most countries (with the exception of the major
OECD countries) have employed either direct or
indirect government interventions on petroleum
price-setting (Kirit Parikh Expert Group, 2010). The
nature and mode of intervention, however, vary
from country to country. In India, the Administered
Pricing Mechanism (APM) was applied to the entire
oil sector to shield the Indian economy from the high
and volatile oil prices generated by the first oil price
shock in 1973-74.
Table 3.1: Pair-wise Granger Causality Tests Between Food,
Fuel and Core Inflation |
Period: April1996- March 2012. |
Null Hypothesis: |
F-Statistic |
Prob. |
FOOD does not Granger Cause FUEL |
0.63 |
0.64 |
FUEL does not Granger Cause FOOD |
1.65 |
0.16 |
CORE does not Granger Cause FUEL |
2.37 |
0.05 |
FUEL does not Granger Cause CORE |
3.89 |
0.00 |
CORE does not Granger Cause FOOD |
0.24 |
0.91 |
FOOD does not Granger Cause CORE |
0.41 |
0.79 |
Note: Core inflation is represented by non-food manufactured products. |
3.47 The APM was completely abandoned in
April 2002. Between April 2002 and January 2004
oil marketing companies (OMCs) changed the
domestic consumer prices of petroleum products
based on market factors. The sharp increases in
international crude prices thereafter forced the
government to re-impose controls on the prices
of petrol, diesel, kerosene and domestic LPG,
resulting in significant increases in the under-recoveries
of OMCs. With crude prices touching
historic peak in 2008, under-recoveries rose to
alarming proportions (Chart III.4). With an uptrend
in international crude prices from the later part of 2010, the under-recoveries of OMCs exhibited
sharp increases during this period.
3.48 The impact of the government’s fiscal
intervention in fuel pricing on inflation can be seen
from the divergent pattern of inflation in the ‘fuel’
group among administered and non-administered
products. Since the government control on fuel price
started to re-emerge from April 2004, a comparative
analysis of trends in fuel prices during this period
reveals the extent of inflation that the government
has absorbed through fiscal intervention
(Chart III.5).
3.49 Administered prices have remained
significantly below non-administered prices,
indicating that the administered price policy helped
keep domestic prices significantly low. Products
under administered prices include domestic LPG,
kerosene and diesel, which together have a weight
of 6.3 per cent in the WPI compared with the freely-priced
products under the mineral oils group with a
combined weight of 3.0 per cent. If one assumes
that inflation of non-administered prices is the likely
scenario in the absence of fiscal intervention, one
could estimate the extent of suppressed inflation as
the difference between the inflation of freely-priced products and the inflation of administered prices
(Chart III.6). It can be seen that administered prices
have been used as a fiscal policy tool to significantly
even out the volatility that otherwise would have
emerged if the full pass-through of global fuel
price shocks to domestic prices was allowed.
This volatility, apart from its impact on input costs,
could also have unanchored inflation expectations
significantly, thereby creating a situation where
monetary policy would have to be much more
proactive. Therefore, when supply shocks impart
significant volatility to the inflation path, fiscal-monetary
co-ordination becomes crucial.
3.50 Administrative measures to insulate the
domestic economy from commodity price shocks
may yield lower inflation in the short-run, but the
increased fiscal burden could lead to an increase
in inflation in the medium-term. The appropriate
policy mix would be to use fiscal/administrative
measures only for the purpose of insulating the
impact of sharp volatility in commodity prices on
domestic inflation, whereas any shift in level should
ideally be passed through as it would also help in
demand adjustment. Recent announcement by the
government to introduce open market pricing of
diesel for bulk consumers and staggered increases in retail price of diesel, could add to near-term price
pressures but it is a step in the right direction.
3.51 The government has been providing fertiliser
subsidies, as it is one of the key inputs for the
agriculture sector. It can be seen that international
fertiliser prices have exhibited sharp increases in
recent years and, as in the case of fuel products,
the government has used subsidies as a major
tool to insulate domestic prices from such volatility
(Chart III.7). Although subsidies can be used as
a tool for inflation management in the short-term,
persistent high prices in the international market
could lead to a substantial burden on the fiscal
front and the pass-through of high import prices to
domestic prices might become inevitable, especially
when the import dependence is considerable.
Impact of Inflation on Government Finances
3.52 One major channel through which the
interaction between monetary and fiscal policy
works is through the causal relationship between
inflation and government finances. If government
revenues and expenditures respond differently to
inflation, the fiscal balance would change depending
on the net response of these components to
inflation. If the elasticity of government expenditure to inflation is higher than that of revenue to inflation,
an increase in inflation would lead to a widening of
the deficit and vice-versa. Seminal work in this area
was done by Aghevli and Khan (1978). They found
a self-perpetuating process of inflation in emerging
economies. Previous empirical studies on India
(Sharma 1984, Jadhav and Singh, 1990) found
support for the validity of the hypothesis of inflation-induced
deficits in the Indian context.
3.53 The interaction between inflation and
government finances is empirically examined in
Box III.4. It can be seen that the expenditure
elasticity to inflation is much higher and statistically
significant than revenue elasticity. This could be
because most government expenditure is planned
in real terms and gets automatically indexed to
inflation. For instance, project costs escalate with
inflation whereas salaries are indexed to inflation.
Also, the subsidy expenditure on key items viz.,
food and fuel is highly sensitive to inflation.
Given that higher level of fiscal deficit could be
inflationary, these results also point to the risk of
self-perpetuating cycle of inflation and fiscal deficit.
V. Cyclicality of government spending
3.54 Keynesian approaches suggest that fiscal
policy should ideally be countercyclical, that is,
fiscal deficits should decline when the economy
is expanding and increase during economic
downturns. The cyclicality of government spending
is normally defined in terms of how spending
moves with the output gap. If government spending
increases when there is a negative output gap
(i.e., output is below its potential), then spending is
countercyclical. This implies lower spending when
output is high, relative to its trend. Therefore, pro-cyclicality
can be defined as an above-average
spending-to-output ratio whenever output is above
its potential.
3.55 Fiscal policies in several countries turn
out to be pro-cyclical rather than counter-cyclical.
Borrowing constraints, fiscal rules and weak
institutions contribute to this phenomenon. Policies,
especially government spending, often turn out to be expansionary in booms and contractionary in
recessions. This is potentially damaging from the
viewpoint of macroeconomic stability. It also has
adverse welfare consequences. Further, fiscal
policies in good times are not fully offset in bad
times and leave an uncorrected deficit bias. This
can risk debt sustainability and increase the default
probability. Ideally, tax policies should be used to
smooth tax distortions and expenditures over the
business cycle, but pro-cyclical fiscal policies tend
to exacerbate business cycle fluctuations. In India,
a comparison between the growth rate of GDP and
government final consumption expenditure (GFCE)
indicates the nature of pro-cyclicality (Chart III.8).
Box III.4
Inflation and Government Finances: Is it a self-perpetuating cycle in India?
The empirical estimation of the inflation-deficit nexus in the
Indian case is attempted by estimating the co-integrating
relationship under a vector error correction model framework
(VECM).
For a co-integrating relationship to exist, all the variables
should be integrated of the same order. The variables were
tested for stationarity and it was found that all the variables
were non-stationary at levels but stationary at first difference,
indicating that there could be a co-integrating relationship
between these variables.
The presence and number of co-integrating vectors in the
relationship between government revenue, inflation and
growth has been estimated using the trace test and maximum
Eigen value statistics following the methodology suggested
by Johansen and Juselius (1992). Both tests indicate the
presence of one co-integrating vector for the government
revenue equation and government expenditure equation.
This is in conformity with the arguments presented in
economic theory. While government revenues (REV) could
be positively affected by inflation and economic growth, the
expenditure of the government (EXP) can both be a cause
and an effect of high inflation. The estimated relationship (by
specifying the relationship between government revenue,
expenditure, inflation and growth in a VECM model) yielded
the following results for the period 1990-2012.
Government Revenue |
Log REV= |
-5.90 + 0.88 LogWPI + 0.75 LogGDP |
t value |
(1.35) |
(2.51)* |
Government Expenditure |
Log EXP= |
-10.21 + 2.72 LogWPI -0.03 LogGDP |
t value |
(2.56)** |
(-0.06) |
* Significant at 5 per cent, |
** Significant at 1 per cent |
The empirical results indicate the following major implications
in terms of the interaction between growth, inflation and
government finances. It is seen that the long-term impact of
inflation is much larger and significant on government
expenditure than on government revenue. Government
revenue responds positively to growth. This implies that high
inflation can lead to higher government expenditure, which
in turn would widen the fiscal deficit. Given that high fiscal
deficit is inflationary in the long-term, the inflation-government
finances nexus could lead to a self-perpetuating cycle as
was argued by Aghevli and Khan (1978). Thus the
co-ordination between monetary and fiscal policies in terms
of inflation management becomes even more critical as high
inflation in the long-run can be self-perpetuating. These
results also indicate that higher growth may not necessarily
lead to improvement in government finances, if inflation is
not kept under control.
Reference
Aghevli and Khan (1978), “Government Deficits and the
Inflationary Process in Developing Countries”, IMF Staff
Papers, Vol.25, 383–416
3.56 To test pro-cyclicality, the following two
exercises were carried out: (i) the fiscal spending
and output relationship was tested in an errorcorrection
framework that allows us to distinguish
between the short-term effect of output on
government spending and any longer-term effect
between these two variables, and (ii) the OLS
regression equation of the cyclical component
of the government consumption spending/GDP
(GFCE/GDP_C) ratio (real) and the cyclical
component of GDP (real GDP_C) was estimated to
understand the relationship between government
spending and output1. The results for the period
1950-51 to 2011-12 were
3.57 The results indicate that GFCE and GDP
are co-integrated and that government spending is
pro-cyclical both in the long-run and the short-run.
However, for a shorter period (1980-81 to 2011-
12) the results are statistically insignificant. This
may have been caused by counter-cyclical fiscal
expansion undertaken in 2008-09 in the backdrop
of global financial crisis.
3.58 Since the coefficients of real GDP_C are
found to be positive, government spending is again
found to be pro-cyclical. The above results present
evidence on the pro-cyclicality of government
spending. This is further corroborated by the
movements in clyclical component of GDP and
GFCE (Charts III.9 & III.10).
3.59 Pro-cyclicality of fiscal spending in a
developing economy is not unusual and empirical evidence is in substantial support of this, even
though such behaviour defies common wisdom.
Governments should borrow in “bad times” when
revenues shrink and “social” spending rises, and
repay debt in good times. However, fiscal policies
do not smooth tax receipts and expenditures over
the business cycle in EMDEs because of several
reasons that include: (i) already stretched fiscal
positions that leave limited space for counter-cyclical
policies, (ii) insufficient provision in
fiscal rules to support counter-cyclical policies,
(iii) borrowing constraints faced by these economies,
(iv) weak institutions that allow in-built deficit bias,
(v) corruption that reduces the response of primary
balance to output gap, (vi) voracity effect, wherein
windfall revenue exacerbates the pressures for
fiscal redistribution and accentuates the common
pool problem. India is not devoid of such problems.
VI. Debt-Deficit Dynamics and Monetary
Management
3.60 The behaviour of deficit and debt may
play a significant role in shaping monetary
management, even though the central bank
conducts debt management as an agency function
of fiscal authority. Theoretically, monetary and fiscal
policies interact in a number of ways to condition
the short-run and long-run levels and the path of
macroeconomic variables, such as output and
inflation. This section analyses the interaction
between debt-deficit dynamics and monetary policy
in India during the past three decades.
3.61 Debt-deficit dynamics originate from the
government’s decision to finance its expenditure
through two alternative sources, viz., tax (plus
non-tax and other non-debt receipts) financing and
debt financing. The rollover of debt financing of
government expenditure over the years in higher
proportions may add to the stock of public debt even
if the government is making regular repayments.
In India, during the period 1980-81 to 2012-13,
on average, one-third of the total government
expenditure was financed by borrowing, i.e., for
every `100 spent by the government, `33 were borrowed.
3.62 Despite the persistence of debt financing,
its share witnessed a decline during the 2000s,
reflecting the enactment of the Fiscal Responsibility
and Budget Management (FRBM) Act, 2003 by the
government, which brought about fiscal discipline
in a gradual manner. Thus, the FRBM Act and
the subsequent FRBM rules were milestones in
the history of fiscal policy in India under which the
government was legally required to achieve gross
fiscal deficit of not more than 3 per cent of GDP by
2007-08, which was extended by a year to 2008-
09. In fact, the central government was ahead of the
target when it was able to achieve a fiscal deficit-to-
GDP ratio of 2.5 per cent in 2007-08. However,
the declining trend in debt financing was reversed
with the onset of the global financial turmoil as
the government implemented fiscal stimulus
programmes to offset the impact of the global
slowdown on aggregate demand in the economy.
3.63 Thus, in recent years, i.e., 2008-09 to 2012-
13, the share of debt financing of expenditure has
gone up. The moderate decline in the share of debt
financing in the financial year 2010-11 reflected
the impact of a partial exit from an expansionary
fiscal policy, supported by strong growth in revenue
receipts, including non-tax receipts, and recovery in
economic growth. However, in 2011-12 and 2012-
13, the presistent low economic growth reduced
the revenue resources of the government, and thus,
expenditure fianancing through debt was slightly
higher than in 2010-11 (Chart III.11).
3.64 The debt financing of expenditure entails
a repayment obligation on the government, which
according to the Ricardian equivalence will have
to be financed by future tax and non-tax revenues.
However, if the government is not able to raise
adequate revenues in future to finance its past
debt, it may have to resort to fresh borrowings to
finance the old debt. This, in fiscal parlance, is
popularly known as ponzi financing. Theoretically,
to avoid this, the government has to generate a
primary revenue surplus that is adequate to finance
the interest payment obligations. In India, the central government has been running a primary
revenue surplus for the past three decades except
during recent years. However, during the past
two decades, this primary revenue surplus was
inadequate to finance the entire interest payments.
With the implementation of the FRBM Act, when
the government moved to a rule-based fiscal policy
framework, the percentage of interest payments
financed by primary revenue surplus witnessed
an improvement in the fiscal arena. However, the
fiscal stimulus programme with its expansionary
mode eliminated the primary revenue surplus, and
consequently the government reported a primary
revenue deficit during recent years, which indicates
that fresh borrowings were used to finance part of
the interest payments (Chart III.12).
3.65 The implementation of the FRBM Act by the
government played a major role in determining the
level and path of fiscal deficit and debt in the Indian
economy during the past decade. It is also argued
in the literature that fiscal discipline is a mirror
image of monetary independence. This is because
while the amount of debt is the result of the fiscal
policy of the government, the composition of debt is the result of debt management policy (Tobin,
1963). In many countries (including India), the
debt management policy is vested with the central
banks.2 While central banks do not generally have
any control on the amount of deficit, large fiscal
deficits often make it necessary that fiscal-monetary
co-ordination is achieved to enable the smooth
conduct of both monetary and debt management.
Cross-country experiences suggest that this is
either done through an institutional arrangement,
where the co-ordination is achieved with the central
bank conducting the debt management on behalf
of the government, or by setting up a separate
agency for debt management. The latter would
nevertheless require a co-ordination mechanism
that can become difficult in the case of large
government market borrowings. As the latter has
implications for interest rates, liquidity management
and credit flows, an integrated view at one place
has its own advantages. The amount of borrowing
as an outcome of deficit, which is determined by
the government, is exogenously given to central
banks to arrange for its financing. Ipso facto, the
standard theoretical arguments in the realm of fiscal-monetary interface rest on the interactions
between debt management policy and monetary
policy. Thus, the ways in which the deficit/debt is
financed is as important as the size of deficit/debt.
Further, given that the deficit/debt can be financed
easily when its size is small, implies that fiscal
discipline with commitment to bring down deficit/
debt will improve the manoeuvrability available to
central banks while conducting monetary policy.
External Financing of GFD and its Monetary Impact
3.66 Apart from being the monetary authority, in
terms of Sections 20 and 21 of the Reserve Bank
of India (RBI) Act, 1934, management of the public
debt of the Government of India and the issuance
of new loans is vested with the Reserve Bank
of India. Further, under Section 21A of the RBI
Act, the Reserve Bank may undertake the debt
management of states, by agreements with the
state governments. Thus, in India both the debt
management policy and monetary policy are vested
with the same institution.
3.67 As far as the financing of deficit is
concerned, it is primarily financed through internal
sources in India. During the past three decades, on
average, 6.1 per cent of the total GFD in India was
financed using resources raised through external
sources. However, over the years, the extent
of external financing of GFD declined. Further,
although foreign institutional investors (FIIs) are
allowed to invest in government securities, the
government debt held by FIIs is only a small portion
of the total government debt. The loans from
multilateral and bilateral creditors are other sources
of external financing. Moreover, the government
has not directly accessed the international capital
market as a sovereign entity. Thus, the usual risks
associated with such borrowing has been practically
absent (GoI, 2011). Such risks on soveriegn debt
have exacerbated the crisis in the euro area.
Further, in India, the sub-national governments are
not allowed to raise external loans on their own.
3.68 Theoretically, the financing of GFD through
external sources adds another dimension to the fiscal-monetary interface through the net capital
inflows. According to the Mundell-Fleming open
economy model, an independent monetary policy
is impossible when there is intervention in the
foreign exchange market to keep the exchange
rate at tolerable levels (or at a fixed rate) in the
context of huge net capital inflows often resulting
in appreciation of the currency. Thus, financing
the GFD through external resources at higher
proportions can have repercussions not only on
fiscal sustainability but also on the impossible trinity,
i.e., open capital account, fixed exchange rate and
independent monetary policy. The dependence on
external finance for financing GFD has never been
high and it has declined in the recent period, which
is a welcome development in the Indian context.
Importantly, from 2002-03 to 2004-05, the share
of external financing turned negative, as high-cost
external loans were pre-paid during this period
(Chart III.13).
Net Capital Inflows, Market Stabilisation Scheme
and its Monetary Impact
3.69 During the 2000s, India built up significant
foreign exchange reserves, indicating the
absorption of a part of net capital inflows by the
Reserve Bank during this period. Theoretically, the absorption of net capital inflows by the Reserve
Bank creates reserve money, which through the
multiplier effect leads to the creation of M3 in the
economy. However, the reserve money as a ratio
of GDP did not show any jump during this period,
despite the absorption of high net capital inflows
by the Reserve Bank. The Market Stabilisation
Scheme (MSS) put in place by the Reserve Bank
of India and Government of India in 2004, was used
to sterilise the impact of foreign exchange market
intervention thus, limiting the monetary impact of
net capital inflows. The interest payments on MSS
bonds are borne by the government. Thus, in the
process of neutralising the monetary impact of net
capital inflows, fiscal costs were incurred, leading
to higher gross fiscal deficit. However, fiscal policy,
in this process, increased the flexibility of monetary
policy rather than constraining it. In fact, the MSS
stands out as an example of effective fiscalmonetary
co-ordination that not only helped in
monetary contraction to offset the surges in capital
inflows, but also in monetary expansion through
the unwinding of the MSS after the global financial
crisis set in motion an economic downturn.
Internal Financing of Government Debt and its
Monetary Impact
3.70 In India, more than 90 per cent of government
debt is financed through internal sources.
Theoretically, if the public debt is held domestically,
then the risk of public debt is perceived to be low
from the point of view of external sustainability. The
recent experience of Portugal, Ireland, Greece and
Spain, demonstrated that sizeable external holding
of public debt has the potential to precipitate a
sovereign debt crisis. From this viewpoint, the
position of India is comfortable as the majority of
India’s public debt is held domestically. However,
if the domestically-held public debt is excessive, it
is still subject to refinancing risks and has certain
monetary impacts through the channels of interest
rate, crowding out and monetisation.
3.71 Theoretically, higher fiscal deficit, by
appropriating a higher share of total loanable funds in the economy, may push up interest rates for the
private sector. The high interest rates may reduce
private sector investment and finally result in a lower
aggregate supply. A shift in the aggregate supply
curve to the left implies that a new equilibrium
between supply and demand would be associated
with a higher price. Thus, the fiscal deficit through
the crowding out effect may increase the price level
in the economy with a corresponding reduction in
the overall output.
3.72 According to Sargent and Wallace, the
resultant tight money and interest rate conditions
may lead to an unsustainable debt financing process
and, thus, higher inflation in the long-run. In this
framework, inflation is a fiscal-driven phenomenon,
and nominal monetary growth is endogenously
determined by the need to finance the exogenously
given deficit to satisfy the budget constraint.
3.73 Further, if the monetary authority decides
to offset the impact of higher interest rates by
preventing crowding out of private investment, it may
have to increase the money supply. This implies a
rightward shift of the LM curve with a corresponding
reduction in the interest rate and an increase in the
output. However, if the economy is operating at
near-full employment level, the increase in money
supply may not result in an increase in output;
rather it may push up the price level in the short-run
as the short-run aggregate supply curve is vertical.
3.74 The different theoretical arguments outlined
above rest on the financing of GFD through market
borrowings. In India, the share of GFD financed by
market borrowings has witnessed an increase over
the past three decades. The reserve money as
a per cent of GDP also witnessed an increase, at
a lower rate, though inflation was lower in the last
decade. Notably, during the past decade almost 74
per cent of the total GFD was financed by market
borrowings (Table 3.2). The technical analysis to
understand the dynamics of debt, deficit and money
is attempted later.
3.75 As alluded to earlier, various institutional
reforms relating to the link between debt management policy and monetary policy beginning
1996-97 have considerably improved monetary
independence.
Table 3.2: Market Borrowing, Deficits,
Reserve Money and Inflation |
Average |
Market
Borrowing as per
cent of GFD |
WPI
Inflation |
Reserve
Money as per
cent of GDP |
1980-81 to 1989-90 |
26.9 |
8.0 |
13.4 |
1990-91 to 1999-00 |
37.3 |
8.1 |
14.8 |
2000-01 to 2009-10 |
73.4 |
5.4 |
15.9 |
3.76 The monetisation issue, however, remains.
Who ultimately finances government deficit
depends not on who first subscribes to government
securities in the primary market, but on who finally
holds the government securities. In India, a portion
of government securities is held by the Reserve
Bank, and if this holding increases consequent to
debt financing it leads to monetisation through
secondary market operations. Thus, as Sargent and
Wallace have pointed out, government deficits and
debt will eventually be monetised over the long-run,
resulting in reserve money creation. These issues
were dealt with in detail in the earlier part of this
chapter.
3.77 The relationship between debt-deficit
dynamics and monetary management may also be
affected by the wealth effect of government bonds
(Kia, 2006). The proponents of the FTPL argue
that in a non-Ricardian world, bondholders may
not consider bonds as future taxes. Thus, as the
government issues bonds to finance its deficit, the
wealth of the nation is perceived to have gone up.
This higher wealth effect may increase the demand
for goods and services and may drive up prices in
the short-run.
3.78 The theoretical possibilities outlined above
are debatable, as the exact interface between
fiscal and monetary policies will be conditioned by
a number of factors in different country contexts.
Thus, which theoretical relationship holds in a
particular country depends on the macroeconomic priorities, political will, and other strengths and
weaknesses of the economy. Some of the empirical
evidence on the relationship between debt-deficit
dynamics and monetary management is provided in
Box III.5.
Empirical Analysis
3.79 In the empirical analysis, the combined
debt of the central and state governments was
taken for the following three reasons: First, as
alluded to earlier, it is the debt management policy
that has implications for monetary management.
Moreover, the implications of fiscal deficit may get
reflected in the debt management policy, as debt is
an accumulation of past deficits. Second, it is not
only the first subscription of government securities
in the primary market, but also the final ownership
of government securities through the secondary
market operations, that matters for monetary
management. Thus, taking the combined debt of
the government as an explanatory variable may
capture these dynamics better than the fiscal deficit
of the government. Third, the combined debt is used
for the reason that the central government debt
alone may not be the right variable for assessing
the relationship between debt and reserve money,
as the state governments have also accumulated
substantial amounts of debt over the past decades.
Further, like the central government, state
governments also approach the market to finance
their deficits. The securities issued by the state
governments also have SLR status in India and
their debt issuances are managed by the Reserve
Bank. Thus, the implications of states’ debt for
monetary management may be as important as the
central government’s debt.
3.80 To empirically analyse the dynamics of the
relationship between debt and money, an autoregressive
distributed lag (ARDL) model is applied3.
The first step in the ARDL bounds testing approach
is to estimate the two equations by ordinary least
squares:
Box III.5
Debt-Deficit Dynamics and Monetary Management: Empirical Evidence
In the empirical literature, there have been several attempts
to understand the relationship between fiscal and monetary
policies in different countries, including India. Metin (1998)
and Hamburger and Zwick (1981) found that monetary
policy is strongly influenced by government expenditure
rather than deficits. Tekin-Koru and Ozmen (2003) found
no direct relationship between deficit and inflation in
Turkey. According to this study, inflation in Turkey was
also not a result of seigniorage; instead both money and
inflation are jointly determined. Similar results are obtained
by King (1985) in 12 countries, Joines (1985) for the U.S.,
Karras (1994) for 32 countries and Sikken and Haan (1998)
for 30 developing countries. Giannaros and Kolluri (1985)
found that, in general, the government budget deficit is
not a determinant of money supply growth or of inflation,
either directly or indirectly. The U.S. is an exception, with
some statistical evidence of direct and indirect effects of
the budget deficit on inflation. Using data for the 1954-
76 period, Barro (1978) concluded that it is government
expenditure rather than deficits that influence monetary
growth in the US. Using similar data, Niskanen (1978)
found that government deficits do not have any significant
effects on the inflation rate operating either through the rate
of money growth or independent of it.
Cagan (1965) argues that money supply exhibits both
endogenous and exogenous properties. For short-run and
cyclical fluctuations, Cagan proposed a relation in which the money supply is endogenously determined by changes
in the real sector. However, in the long-run, secular trend
movements in money supply are independent of the real
sector and are determined exogenously. Parida, Mallick and
Mathiyazhagan (2001) find that fiscal deficits and money
supply are influenced by each other. Further, the price level
does not influence either the fiscal deficit or money supply,
but rather is being influenced by both the variables.
Khundrakpam and Goyal (2008) in the Indian context find
that money and real output cause prices both in the short
as well as in the long-run. However, money is neutral to
output. Further, the evidence shows that government deficit
leads to incremental reserve money creation, even though
the Reserve Bank financing of government deficit almost
ceased to exist during most of the current decade. They
argued that the government deficit, by influencing the level
of sterilisation, impacts the accretion of net foreign assets to
the Reserve Bank balance sheet and, therefore, continues
to be a key factor causing incremental reserve money
creation and overall expansion in money supply. Given
the fact that money leads to inflation, government deficit
remains relevant for stabilisation.
Reference
Khundrakpam, Jeevan K. and Rajan Goyal (2008), “Is the
Government Deficit in India still Relevant for Stabilisation?”,
Reserve Bank of India Occasional Papers, Vol. 29, No. 3:
1-21.
3.81 To test for the existence of a long-run
relationship among the variables, an F-test for the
joint significance of the coefficients of the lagged
levels of the variables was conducted, i.e.,
The results were confirmed by a t-test on the
coefficient of the lagged dependant variable, i.e.,
The results are provided in Table 3.3.
3.82 The existence of a long-run relationship
between the variables was confirmed using both
an F-test and t-test on the coefficient of the lagged
dependent variable. The results of both tests
indicate a co-integrating relationship between
combined government debt and change in reserve
money. The direction of causality is from combined
government debt to change in reserve money4. The test for reverse causality was inconclusive with
a significant F statistic and insignificant t statistic.
Once long-run relationship is established, the
second step is to estimate the long-run coefficients.
The long-run relationship was estimated using the
following equation.
Table 3.3: Bounds Test for Co-integration between
Government Debt and Reserve Money |
Variables |
Model |
F-test |
t-test |
Null
Hypothesis
(No Co-
integration) |
Test
Statistic |
Lower
Critical
Value
(95 per
cent) |
Upper
Critical
Value
(95 per
cent) |
Δ Log RM/
Log CTD |
Intercept
and no
Trend |
10.058* |
4.934 |
5.764 |
3.620** |
Rejected |
Log CTD/
Δ Log RM |
Intercept
and no
Trend |
7.050* |
4.934 |
5.764 |
-0.671 |
Not
Rejected/
Inconclusive |
*: Significant at 5 per cent level.
**: Significant at 1 per cent level.
Where RM is change in reserve money and CTD is combined total debt. |
3.83 The lag length of the model was determined
based on Schwarz information criteria. The long-run
coefficient of combined government debt on change
in reserve money is estimated to be significant. The
short-run dynamics of the relationship was captured
by estimating an error correction model associated
with the long-run estimates. The error correction
model associated with this long-run estimate is
provided below. The estimation results are provided
in Table 3.4.
3.84 The error correction term obtained from the
long-run relationship is negative and statistically
significant, confirming the causality from combined
government debt to change in reserve money. The
speed of adjustment to equilibrium following a shock
is quite high, with the coefficient of the error correction
(EC) term at -0.99.
Table 3.4: Error Correction Model for
Reserve Money |
Dependent variable: log change in reserve money |
Explanatory Variable |
Coefficient |
t-Statistic |
p-value |
d log CTD |
-4.059 |
-0.843 |
0.406 |
ECM(-1) |
-0.997 |
-4.974* |
0.000 |
*: Significant at 1 per cent level. |
VII. Concluding Observations
3.85 In this chapter, we presented anecdotal
as well as formal empirical evidence that fiscal
dominance on monetary policy remains to the
extent that the monetary authorities have to
modulate the use of various policy instruments
keeping in view the financing requirements of fiscal
deficit. However, the direct pressure on monetary
policy has moderated as a result of institutional
reforms that have been actively pursued in the
area of fiscal as well as monetary management.
Notwithstanding the improvement in fiscal-monetary
frameworks, greater fiscal-monetary co-ordination
would be needed in the times ahead. This co-ordination
is important from the standpoint of
inflation management, because, in the long-run,
inflation leads to deterioration in the fiscal position
as the expenditure response to inflation outstrips
the revenue response.
3.86 The analysis in the chapter shows that
on the whole government spending has been
pro-cyclical. This pro-cyclicality of government
expenditure can be accommodated if it is associated
with a proportionate increase in revenue receipts,
thereby keeping the fiscal deficit under check. In the
absence of this, the pro-cyclicality of government
expenditure could be risky, with higher fiscal deficit.
This call for further institutional reforms to provide
a more binding framework of fiscal rules that can
withstand business and electoral cycles.
3.87 The empirical results also show that
government debt granger causes reserve money
growth in India, and the speed of adjustment
to equilibrium following a shock is quite fast with a high adjustment coefficient. This causal
relationship over the period 1982-2011 may reflect
the monetisation of debt by the Reserve Bank up
to 1997 through ad hoc treasury bills and through
primary subscription to government debt untill
March 2006. In the subsequent period, this impact
may still have persisted on account of large OMO
purchases. Such fiscal dominance is particularly
detrimental to overall macroeconomic stability if it
leads to reserve money growth above the desired
level, which is required for broad money expansion
consistent with economic growth and inflation. In
this context, further attention would be required
in designing institutional frameworks as well as practices. To conclude, an enduring reduction in
fiscal deficits can further reduce fiscal dominance
and enable monetary policy to play a more effective
role. It is in this backdrop that the revised fiscal
roadmap following the Report of the Committee on
Raodmap for Fiscal Consolidation (Chairman: Dr.
Vijay L. Kelkar) assumes critical importance. The
raodmap envisages lowering the GFD-GDP ratio
to 3.0 per cent by 2016-17. The fiscal adjustment
roadmap on the revenue account perhaps
needs to bring about a quicker adjustment. The
implementation of a strict rule-based fiscal regime
would imrpove fiscal-monetary co-ordination and
facilitate the overall macroeconomic management.
|