For the Year July 1, 2011 to June 30, 2012
PART ONE: THE ECONOMY: REVIEW AND PROSPECTS
II - ECONOMIC REVIEW
The Indian economy’s performance in 2011-12 was marked by slowing growth, high inflation and widening
fiscal and current account gaps. The economy grew at its slowest pace in nine years with mining, manufacturing
and construction dragging growth down. Weakening of both domestic and external demand contributed to the
slowdown. Importantly, in spite of slowing growth, inflation stayed high for larger part of the year. In response, the
Reserve Bank persisted with tightening till October 2011 and paused before easing in April 2012. Slowing growth,
high inflation and widening twin deficits, along with global flight to safety amidst a deepening euro area crisis put
pressures on the financial markets and the exchange rate during the year.
II.1.1 The Indian economy was one of the fastest
growing economies in the post-crisis period. During
2011-12, however, there was continuous
deceleration of economic activity in each of the
four quarters which pushed the expansion of the
economy to below potential, which is the maximum
level of output that the economy can sustain
without creating macroeconomic imbalances.
There has been a deceleration in all sub-sectors
of the economy, barring ‘electricity, gas and water
supply’ and ‘community, social and personal
services’.
II.1.2 Growth slowed down due to multiple factors.
One of the reasons was the persistence of inflation
at a much higher level than the threshold for two
successive years. Persistent and high inflation
necessitated continued tightening of monetary
policy. Recent research suggests that real interest
(lending) rates explain only about one-third of GDP
growth. As of March 2012, real weighted average
lending rates, that have an inverse relationship with
investment activity, were lower than they were in
the pre-crisis period between 2003-04 and
2007-08, when investment boomed.
II.1.3 This suggests that non-monetary factors
played a bigger role and accentuated the slowdown
to beyond what was anticipated while tightening the
monetary policy. Recession in the euro area and
general uncertainty regarding the global economic
climate chipped the external demand as well.
Domestic policy uncertainties, governance and
corruption issues amidst lack of political consensus
on reforms led to a sharp deterioration in investment
climate. Structural constraints emerged in key
investment drivers in the infrastructure space –
telecom, roads and power – which increased the
disinflationary costs. High inflation kept aggregate
demand and business confidence subdued.
II. THE REAL ECONOMY
Growth falters in 2011-12 after a sharp recovery
in the previous two years
II.1.4 After a sharp recovery from the global
financial crisis and two successive years of robust
growth of 8.4 per cent, GDP growth decelerated
sharply to a nine-year low of 6.5 per cent during
2011-12 (Appendix Table 1). The slowdown was
reflected in all sectors of the economy but the industrial sector suffered the sharpest deceleration
(Appendix Table 2 and Chart II.1 a).
|
II.1.5 The slowdown in agriculture sector growth
was on account of the base effect which dragged
down its contribution to GDP growth by half (Chart
II.1 b). In the case of industry, the sharp moderation
in manufacturing sector growth along with decline
in mining and quarrying output offset the
improvement in ‘electricity, gas and water supply’ growth. The industrial sector’s weighted percentage
contribution to economic growth dropped to single
digits, the first time in ten years. The moderation in
services sector growth was led by sharp deceleration
in ‘construction’ and ‘trade, hotels, transport and
communication’. Despite the moderation, the
predominance of the services sector remains a
unique feature of the overall growth story and the
process of structural change in India (Box II.1).
Box II.1
Structural Change Index – A cross-country comparison
Structural transformation of an economy is considered to be
both an outcome of as well as a pre-requisite for economic
development. The most commonly observed structural change
across countries, in line with increases in their real incomes
over time, is the decline in the share of agriculture in GDP
and corresponding increases in the shares of industry and
then in services. The trend in the share of industry has,
however, been observed to follow an inverted-U path
particularly in developed countries, with a declining share
observed in most countries around the middle of the twentieth
century, irrespective of their initial conditions. Consequently,
in the recent period, the share of the industrial sector in many
countries has been found to be close to the level nearly two
centuries earlier. The trend in the shares of agriculture and
services has generally been monotonic.
The factors underlying structural change in economies
operate both on the demand and the supply sides. The income
elasticity of demand is the highest for services, followed by
industrial products and agricultural goods. Hence, progressive
increases in GDP typically result in the tapering of demand
for agricultural products and increase in the demand for
industrial goods and services. On the supply side, agricultural
production faces constraints on account of a fixed factor of
production (land) and consequently, the law of diminishing marginal returns sets in earlier and results in progressively
lower contribution in GDP. In contrast, the greater scope for
the use of capital and technology in the industrial and services
sectors facilitates increased production in these sectors over
time.
Structural Change Indices
The extent of structural change in economies could be
measured using Structural Change Indices (SCIs). One such
SCI, the Norm of Absolute Values (NAV), also known as the
Michaely Index or Stoikov-Index (Cortuk and Singh, 2010),
is:
The SCI is bound between zero and 100, with zero
representing no structural change and 100 indicating a
complete reversal of structure. SCIs are sensitive to three
important factors – the level of classification of the sectors
(greater the granularity, higher would the index), the time
period of the analysis (since the SCI compares sectoral
shares at two time points), the price measure of output
(current prices capture both price and volume changes over
time).
Cross-country Perspective
In order to measure the changing structural dynamics, the
SCI is estimated for selected advanced and emerging market/
developing countries for the period 1990 to 2009 using annual
GDP data (Table 1).
Table 1: Cross Country Comparison of Structural Change |
Country |
Difference in Average Share between
1990-92 and 2007-09 (in percentage point) |
SCI |
Agriculture |
Industry |
Services |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
Australia |
-1.6 |
-9.7 |
11.4 |
11.4 |
Brazil |
-2.0 |
-10.8 |
12.8 |
12.8 |
China |
-13.9 |
4.8 |
9.1 |
13.9 |
France |
-1.7 |
-6.7 |
8.5 |
8.5 |
Germany |
-0.5 |
-7.5 |
8.0 |
8.0 |
India* |
-11.4 |
1.8 |
9.6 |
11.4 |
Japan |
-0.9 |
-10.5 |
11.4 |
11.4 |
Korea |
-5.4 |
-5.0 |
10.5 |
10.5 |
Russia |
-8.3 |
-10.9 |
19.2 |
19.2 |
Sri Lanka |
-13.7 |
3.9 |
9.8 |
13.7 |
South Africa |
-1.1 |
-6.6 |
7.7 |
7.7 |
UK |
-1.0 |
-10.1 |
11.1 |
11.1 |
US |
-0.8 |
-5.7 |
6.6 |
6.6 |
*: Industry includes construction sector.
Note: Data on gross value added at factor cost at current US Dollar has been used.
Source: Estimated using data from the World Bank Development Indicators. |
No clear pattern between SCI and level of development across
countries is evident from Table 1. The extent of structural
change in India over the period is similar to that in developed
countries such as Australia, Japan and the UK, and to some
extent, Korea. Countries such as Brazil, China and Sri Lanka
had higher SCIs than India. Structural change in Russia was
clearly substantially higher than that in any of the other
economies.
Using the Central Statistics Office (CSO) data and the same
methodology, the extent of structural change in India was
found to be not very different in the pre-reform (1968-71 to
1987-90) and post-reform (1990-92 to 2009-11) periods. The
SCIs were 13.6 and 13.2, respectively.
References:
Cortuk, O. and Nirvikar Singh (2011), “Structural Change and
Growth in India”, Economics Letters, March.
Kuznets, S. (1971), “Economic Growth of Nations: Total Output
and Production Structure”, Cambridge, Harvard University
Press.
Papola, T.S. (2005), “Emerging Structure of Indian Economy:
Implications of Growing Inter-sectoral Imbalances”,
Presidential Address, 88th Conference of the Indian Economic
Association, December.
Productivity Commission (1998), “Aspects of Structural
Change in Australia”, Research Report, Government of
Australia.
Investment downturn accentuates demand
slowdown1
II.1.6 There was a sharp moderation in the growth
rate of GDP at market prices from 9.6 per cent in
2010-11 to 6.9 per cent in 2011-12 on account of
all-round deceleration in demand – consumption
(both private and government), investment and
external (net exports) (Chart II.2a).
II.1.7 Expenditure-side GDP data for Q4 of 2011-
12 suggests that growth was 5.6 per cent and
investment improved sequentially. The expenditureside
GDP data, however, have well known
limitations that are also evident from the large and
volatile pattern of discrepancies in the data. The
contribution of ‘statistical discrepancy’ (i.e., the
difference between the estimates of GDP from the
supply side and the sum of the estimates of the components of the expenditure side, adjusted for
net indirect taxes) to the overall growth sharply
increased to around 42 per cent in 2011-12 and
exceeded the contribution of gross fixed capital
formation (Chart II.2b).
II.1.8 The large and volatile discrepancies in the
expenditure side GDP data co-exist with unreliable
data on various components of aggregate demand.
For instance, there is an incorrect representation
of external demand as Q4 data estimates net
exports as a positive figure. This is in contrast to
the record current account deficit (CAD) posted
during the quarter, as per data released by the
Reserve Bank. Also, sufficient supplementary
evidence exists to suggest that investment has
slowed down. Information collected from phasing
details of corporate projects sanctioned financial assistance suggests that corporate fixed planned
investment dropped sharply in H2 of 2010-11 and
declined further in 2011-12. Anecdotal evidence
supplements this view.
|
II.1.9 Capital goods production also contracted
sharply, though this was partly on account of
substitution by imported capital goods. Hence,
investment decelerated faster than other
components of domestic demand. Global
uncertainties further worsened the investment
climate and also slowed down growth through the
net export channel.
Falling saving and investment rates may impact
potential growth
II.1.10 There has been a decline in the average
saving rate since 2008-09, led by a sharp decline
in public sector saving rate that has not been offset
by private savings (Appendix Table 3 and Table II.1).
The reduction in the average public sector savings rate in the post-global crisis period largely reflects
the impact of fiscal stimulus measures as well as
the decline in the contribution of non-departmental
enterprises. Average investment rate has also
declined in the post-crisis period.
II.1.11 Preliminary estimates show that the net
financial saving of the household sector declined
further to 7.8 per cent of GDP at current market
prices in 2011-12 from 9.3 per cent in the previous
year and 12.2 per cent in 2009-10 (Chart II.3 and
Appendix Table 4). The moderation in the net
financial saving rate of the household sector during
the year mainly reflected an absolute decline in
small savings and slower growth in households’
holdings of bank deposits, currency as well as life
funds. At the same time, the persistence of inflation
at a high average rate of about 9 per cent during
2011-12 further atrophied financial saving, as
households attempted to stave off the downward
pressure on their real consumption/lifestyle.
Table II.1: Savings and Investment Rate |
(Per cent to GDP) |
|
Savings |
Investment |
Households |
Private
Corporate |
Public
Sector |
Total |
Households |
Private
Corporate |
Public
Sector |
Total* |
Financial (Net) |
Physical |
Sub-Total |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
11 |
2005-06 to 2007-08 |
11.6 |
11.4 |
23.0 |
8.3 |
3.7 |
35.0 |
11.4 |
15.1 |
8.4 |
34.9 |
2008-09 to 2010-11 |
11.0 |
12.9 |
23.9 |
7.8 |
0.9 |
32.7 |
12.9 |
12.0 |
9.1 |
34.1 |
Change |
-0.6 |
1.5 |
0.9 |
-0.4 |
-2.7 |
-2.2 |
1.5 |
-3.1 |
0.8 |
-0.9 |
*: Exclusive of investment in valuables. |
|
II.1.12 Furthermore, with real interest rates on
bank deposits and instruments such as small
savings remaining relatively low on account of the
persistent high inflation, and the stock market
adversely impacted by global developments,
households seemed to have favoured investment
in valuables, such as gold. In the post-global crisis
period, valuables have increased from 1.3 per cent
of GDP at current market prices in 2008-09 to 2.8
per cent in 2011-12; the share of valuables in
investment (gross capital formation) has also
increased from 3.7 per cent to 7.9 per cent, over
this period. The apparent proclivity of households
towards investment in valuables such as gold could
have also impacted the pace of their investment in
physical assets such as housing in 2011-12.
II.1.13 The trend of falling savings rate, particularly
that of public sector savings, needs to be reversed
for adequate resources to be available to support
a high growth trajectory during the Twelfth Plan.
II.1.14 The rate of gross fixed capital formation
(investment) has declined persistently from a peak
of 32.9 per cent in 2007-08 to 30.4 per cent in
2010-11. The slackening of overall fixed investment
was largely reflected in the private corporate sector as a result of both monetary and non-monetary
factors. Sluggish growth rate of capital raised
through initial public offerings (IPOs) during
2011-12 further impacted investment. The
correlation between IPOs as a ratio to GDP and
the fixed investment rate between 2000-01 and
2011-12 was 0.71.
II.1.15 Persistent decline in investment rates tend
to adversely impact potential output. There has
been a decline in potential output over the previous
two years as a result of structural impediments and
high inflation. On current assessment the potential
output growth is around 7.5 per cent and the actual
output growth is lower, resulting in a negative output
gap. Going by the positive yet lagged relationship
between output gap and inflation, the positive
output gap during 2009-10 and 2010-11 cast some
downward stickiness to the inflation rate (Box II.2).
Agricultural growth moderates on high base
II.1.16 Agricultural sector grew around trend level
during 2011-12 on top of a good performance in
2010-11 (Appendix Table 5). The south-west
monsoon in 2011 was normal, but the north-east
monsoon was deficient by 48 per cent. Nevertheless,
the trend level growth in agriculture was maintained.
As per the Fourth Advance Estimates for 2011-12,
production of foodgrains in general and rice and
wheat in particular, is estimated to be the highest
ever.
II.1.17 In 2012-13, however, the south-west
monsoon is likely to be deficient with cumulative
rainfall (up to August 16, 2012) for the country as
a whole being 16 per cent below the LPA. The
deficiency as measured by the Reserve Bank’s
production-weighted rainfall (PRN) index is even
higher at 21 per cent. The deficiency is highest for
north-west India with the rainfall being 25 per cent
below LPA with scanty rainfall in Punjab and
Haryana. Overall, 47 per cent of the geographical
area of the country, including Gujarat, west
Rajasthan, parts of Maharashtra and Karnataka
received scanty/deficient rainfall.
Box II.2
Is Output Gap a Leading Indicator of Inflation?
The output gap is defined as the gap between the actual and
the potential output, where potential output is the maximum
possible level of output that is consistent with a stable and
low rate of inflation. In a traditional Phillips curve framework,
a positive (negative) output gap, signifying excess aggregate
demand (supply), results in an increase (decline) in the
inflation rate. The impact of the output gap on inflation could
be instantaneous or could occur with a lag. Several other
factors could, of course, impact inflation such as lagged
inflation, the exchange rate and the indirect tax rate.
Apart from the level, a change in the output gap – termed as
the ‘speed limit’ effect – could also impact inflation. This
reflects the emergence of temporary supply bottlenecks when
the pace of increase in demand outstrips the build-up of new
capacity, even though the level of the output gap may still be
negative. Empirical studies have found evidence of
asymmetries/non-linearities in the relationship between
output gap/growth and inflation for India (Mohanty et al,
2011).
Against this backdrop, the trends in output gap (with the
potential output based on the H-P filter) and WPI inflation in
India over the period 2000-01:Q1 to 2011-12:Q4 were studied
(Chart). It was found that the output gap Granger caused WPI
inflation at one lag, corroborating the leading indicator
properties of the output gap.
Simple linear regressions of the WPI inflation rate on its own
lags, output gap and a dummy variable (for period-specific
outliers) for the period 2000-01:Q1 to 2011-12:Q4 yield
statistically significant coefficients (Table). Inflation up to two
lags is significant. While the positive sign of the first lag of
inflation reflects inflation persistence say, through inflationary
expectations or actual price rigidities, the negative sign of the
second lag of inflation possibly shows that the inflation series
is mean-reverting or stationary. Output gap is positive and
significant at the first and third lags. In effect, a one percentage
point increase in the output gap resulted in 0.2 and 0.3 percentage point increase in the WPI inflation rate after one
and three quarters, respectively. The simple linear formulation
did not detect any speed limit effects.
|
Table: Estimation Results |
Explanatory Variable |
Estimated
Coefficient |
P-Value |
Constant |
1.96 |
0.00 |
Inflation (-1) |
1.15 |
0.00 |
Inflation (-2) |
-0.50 |
0.00 |
Output Gap (-1) |
0.20 |
0.07 |
Output Gap (-3) |
0.29 |
0.01 |
Dummy Variable |
2.90 |
0.00 |
Adjusted R-square |
0.82 |
|
Lagrange Multiplier Test (Lag 3) |
0.86 |
|
Prob (F-Statistic) |
0.00 |
|
Normalised impulse response functions of a bi-variate VAR
model consisting of output gap and the WPI inflation rate
(alternatively, headline and core) show that a one standard
deviation shock to output gap results in an increase in both
headline and core inflation, which reaches a maximum after
three quarters and the impact wears off after 6-8 quarters or
around 2 years.
Given that growth has slowed down significantly in the recent
period, these results thus indicate that inflation, especially
core, could moderate with a lag. However, the pace and extent
of moderation could be conditional on other determinants of
inflation such as supply shocks from food, global commodity
price movements and exchange rate pass-through as well
as the overall fiscal position. Currently most of these pressures
persist, which partly explains the stickiness in inflation despite
growth slowing down.
References:
Baghli, M., Christophe Cahn and Henri Fraisse (2006), “Is the
Inflation-Output Nexus Asymmetric in the Euro Area?” Banque
de France Working Paper No.140, April.
Dwyer, A, Katherine Lam and Andrew Gurney (2010),
“Inflation and the Output Gap in the UK”, Treasury Economic
Working Paper No.6, March
Meier, A. (2010), “Still Minding the Gaps – Inflation Dynamics
during Episodes of Persistently Large Output Gaps”, IMF
Working Paper WP/10/189, August.
Mohanty, D., A.B. Chakraborty, Abhiman Das and Joice John
(2011), “Inflation Threshold in India: An Empirical Investigation”,
Reserve Bank of India Working Papers, October.
II.1.18 This has affected the kharif sowing in 2012-
13. The sown area as of August 17, 2012 is greater
than the normal for this period of the year for rice
and non-foodgrains such as sugarcane, cotton and
jute and mesta. The total deviation from normal is
4 per cent for foodgrains led by decline in sown area
in relation to the normal of 16 per cent and 12 per
cent for coarse cereals and pulses, respectively.
Notwithstanding some improvement in monsoon in
August 2012, the gap in area sown for coarse
cereals and pulses is likely to persist. While this
could have an adverse effect on agricultural output
in 2012-13, the situation during the year so far (up
to August 16, 2012) seems better than what was
seen in the comparable period of the drought year
of 2009-10 (Chart II.4).
II.1.19 The India Meteorological Department (IMD)
has pegged the probability of El Nino conditions
emerging in the later part of the season at 65 per
cent. Deficient rainfall has also affected the level of
water in the 84 reservoirs under the Central Water
Commission (CWC). If September rains are not
good, it would impact the soil moisture and reservoir
levels and thus put the rabi output also at risk.
II.1.20 Even as the dependence of Indian agriculture
on rainfall has reduced over the years, it remains
predominantly rain-fed. About 16 per cent of the
country’s geographical area is drought prone. This
is mostly in the arid, semi-arid and sub-humid areas.
Rain-fed agriculture accounts for around 56 per cent of the total cropped area, with 77 per cent of
pulses, 66 per cent of oilseeds and 45 per cent of
cereals grown under rain-fed conditions. The
dependence of agriculture on rainfall is manifested
by decline in kharif output in 2008-09 and 2009-10,
when the south-west monsoon was acutely
deficient. Deficient north-east monsoons in the
recent past adversely affected the production of
rabi crops such as oilseeds, pulses and rice. On
the contrary, during 2010-11, when both summer
and winter rainfalls were above normal, production
of most kharif and rabi crops increased significantly.
II.1.21 The government has prepared contingency
plans which entails ensuring sufficient availability
of all seeds, fodder, power and diesel, additional
wage allocation under Mahatma Gandhi National
Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MGNREGA)
and sufficient funds under the National Disaster
Relief Fund. An inter-Ministerial Group has been
constituted to review the situation on a weekly basis.
Contingency plans such as production of fodder,
short duration pulses and conservation of moisture
for early planting of rabi crops such as toria,
sorghum and gram are being implemented.
Food security challenges would require further
policy/ operational changes
II.1.22 Foodgrain stocks in India are currently at
very high levels (76.2 million tonnes in July 2012),
thus providing some insulation from weather shock
in the current year (Appendix Table 6). However, availability of pulses, groundnut and coarse cereals
may be constrained. Extremely dry and hot weather
conditions during May-June 2012 in countries such
as the US, China, and Russia affected crop
conditions. Therefore, domestic shortages may not
be readily covered by imports.
II.1.23 In spite of the record level of foodgrain
stocks, food security concern persists. The food
security issues in respect of foodgrains persist more
in terms of likely increased entitlements (under the
proposed National Food Security Bill 2011) and
lack of storage capacity. However, given the
changing food habits a greater emphasis is
necessary to augment supply of protein-rich items,
vegetable and fruits, where demand-supply gaps
are putting a pressure on prices.
II.1.24 In recent years, per capita availability of food
items such as foodgrains and pulses has shown a
declining trend. Compared with the 1990s, production
of foodgrains and horticultural crops grew at a slower
pace during the 2000s despite increasing
diversification of the consumption basket. Rising
expenditure on high value foods, namely, fruits,
vegetables, milk, eggs, meat and fish has reduced
the dominance of cereals in the consumption
basket, as confirmed by the consumer expenditure
survey of 2009-10 conducted by the National
Sample Survey Office (NSSO). Increase in income
will lead to further increase in demand for these food
items, which will eventually have a bearing on the
overall food and nutrition security preparedness of
the country. Raising the growth rate of agricultural
production, including foodgrains, to levels above the
growth rate of population, therefore, is crucial for
long-term food security. The country has large
import dependence for items such as pulses and
oilseeds. According to the working group for the 12th
Five Year Plan (2012-17) constituted by the Planning
Commission, demand for pulses and oilseeds could
exceed the domestic supply by 1-4 million tonnes
and 18-26 million tonnes, respectively, by 2016-17.
II.1.25 Further, the distribution and delivery
mechanism under the existing Targeted Public Distribution System (TPDS) suffers from inefficiency
and leakages. The existing storage facilities are
already stretched to their limits, often leading to
wastage. Thus, scaling up the coverage and
entitlement under TPDS would require an overhaul
in the entire chain of food management systems.
Measures such as augmenting storage capacity
and reducing leakages apart from exploring the
possibilities of introducing cash transfer, food
coupon systems and digitalisation of TPDS are
expected to help solve the problems facing the
sector to a large extent.
Technological breakthrough, investments in protein
– key to higher agriculture growth
II.1.26 Technology breakthroughs, especially in dry
land farming as also investment for augmenting
supply of vegetables, fruits, eggs, fish, meat and
milk are key to addressing the supply constraints in
agriculture which is necessary to tame inflation. As
per the approach paper for the 12th Five Year Plan,
achieving at least 4 per cent agricultural growth in
the coming years is crucial not only for sustaining
overall growth of the economy but also for a more
equitable growth. This would require a quantum
increase in productivity from the current levels. This,
in turn, requires technological breakthrough given
the limited supply of land, water and other structural
constraints such as low level of mechanisation,
shortage of irrigation facilities and power, and
inefficient communication and extension services.
II.1.27 Frontier technologies such as biotechnology,
information and communication technology (ICT),
renewable energy technologies, space applications
and nanotechnology; and organic farming along with
Low External Input Sustainable Agriculture (LEISA)
techniques, if promoted with Integrated Natural
Resource Management (INRM) and Integrated Pest
Management (IPM) techniques, can help improve
productivity in a sustainable manner without
ecological distress. Technology can also help ensure
sustainability of natural resources, enhance
efficiency of public investment, and diversify
agriculture towards higher value crops and livestock.
II.1.28 Success in bridging productivity gap in
terms of yield vis-à-vis world average and the gap
within states/regions in the country can contribute
significantly to higher production. An effort in this
direction which has yielded favourable result is
the assigning of mission mode status to the
objective of extending Green Revolution to the
eastern region. During 2011-12, West Bengal,
Bihar and Jharkhand registered significant
increase in yield, production and cultivated area
under rice with West Bengal emerging as the
highest producer of rice in the country. Initiatives
with respect to pulses and oilseeds are also
yielding favourable results.
II.1.29 Improving protein supplies requires spread
of appropriate technologies and larger investments
in poultry, fisheries and dairy farming. Though there
has been rapid growth in poultry output, demand
has grown faster. There is, therefore, a need for
encouraging rearing of hybrid birds and poultrylayer
farming, investment in improved feed
conversion, poultry vaccines and medicines,
veterinary services as also poultry equipment.
Specific pathogen free egg production needs to be
stepped up. Higher investment is also needed in
fisheries covering deep sea, coastal and inland
fisheries such as aquaculture in ponds, tanks and
reservoirs. Private investment should be enabled
in tuna processing and fish drying centres through
public policy support.
Industrial growth moderates amidst deteriorating
investment climate, softer demand
II.1.30 Industrial growth, as measured by the index
of industrial production (IIP), decelerated to 2.9 per
cent during 2011-12 from 8.2 per cent in the
previous year (Appendix Table 7). While the IIP
maintained a moderate growth of 5.1 per cent
during the first half of 2011-12, growth took a plunge
in the second half to 0.9 per cent. The slowdown
was on account of moderation in demand, both
domestic and external, hardening of interest rates,
slowdown in consumption expenditure, especially
in interest-rate sensitive commodities, subdued business confidence and global economic
uncertainty.
II.1.31 The slowdown in industrial growth was
exacerbated by the volatility in the production of
capital goods. Truncated IIP, constructed by the
Reserve Bank by excluding item groups (out of 399)
which fall in the top 2 per cent growing and bottom
2 per cent declining blocks and has a weight of 96.0
per cent in total IIP, grew 4.8 per cent in 2011-12
showing a better performance than the overall IIP.
Nevertheless, a significant moderation in growth is
evident even for truncated IIP in successive
quarters of 2011-12 (Chart II.5). In Q1 of 2012-13,
IIP declined by 0.1 per cent mainly due to a 20 per
cent decline in output of capital goods. Growth in
truncated IIP and IIP excluding capital goods was
better than in Q4 of 2011-12.
II.1.32 The slowdown in industrial production was
reflected across all sub-sectors in 2011-12, except
electricity. In the manufacturing sub-sector, while 6
industry groups showed a decline in production, 6
registered growth in excess of 10.0 per cent. The
mining sub-sector declined by 2.0 per cent during
2011-12. This was mainly due to regulatory and
environmental issues affecting coal mining and low output of natural gas from the Krishna-Godavari
basin. However, electricity sector performed better
during 2011-12 recording 8.2 per cent growth
supported by higher hydro power generation aided
by a normal south-west monsoon (Chart II.6 a).
|
II.1.33 Capital and intermediate goods growth
declined during the year reflecting dampening of
investment climate. In general, the import-intensity
of domestic capital goods is high, and empirical
tests confirm the integral link of imports as inputs
to capital goods production. In 2011-12, however,
even as production of capital goods declined,
imports remained high. This could be indicative of
gradual loss of comparative advantage in production
of capital goods. The growth of consumer durables
decelerated sharply due to interest rate sensitivity
(Chart II.6 b). Basic goods2 made the highest
contribution to industrial growth at 75 per cent
during 2011-12.
Global factors impinge on domestic industrial
growth
II.1.34 As noted earlier, the slowdown in overall
growth of the economy during 2011-12 is mainly
attributable to weak industrial performance. This,
in turn, can be ascribed to both international and
domestic factors. The current slowdown, that
started in early 2010-11 coincided with the fragile economic conditions in the US and European
countries. As during 2008-09, global factors are a
part of the reason for the industrial slowdown. These
include the financial crisis in the euro zone, sluggish
growth in other industrialised countries and elevated
crude oil prices. Among emerging market
economies, countries such as Malaysia, South
Korea and Brazil also witnessed weak industrial
performance during the period.
II.1.35 An empirical assessment of the impact of
monetary policy and global growth on industrial
output suggests that a percentage point increase
in real weighted average lending rate for industry
in the base period results in a decline in IIP growth,
on an average, by 0.6 percentage point over a one
year horizon. On the other hand, a one percentage
point increase in global GDP growth in the base
period stimulates domestic IIP growth, on an
average, by about 0.7 percentage point over the
same horizon. These estimates indicate that both
monetary policy actions and global growth
dynamics affect the growth of domestic industry.
Removing bottlenecks facing core industries crucial
to reviving industrial growth
II.1.36 Structural bottlenecks in critical sectors
such as coal and natural gas affected the overall
performance of industrial sector during 2011-12. Contraction in natural gas output and slowdown
in coal, fertiliser and crude oil output led to
deceleration in growth of core industries to 4.4 per
cent during 2011-12 compared with 6.6 per cent
in the previous year (Chart II.7). There was
contraction in fertilisers, natural gas and crude oil
and deceleration in steel, refinery products and
electricity during April-June 2012.
|
II.1.37 Manufacturing growth depends crucially on
the inputs provided by core industries, especially,
electricity which has a weight of 10.3 per cent in
the IIP. An empirical assessment of the dependence
of manufacturing growth, inter alia, on electricity
availability indicates that a one percentage point
increase in annual growth in electricity increases
the growth rate of manufacturing by 0.4 percentage
point. This has been reflected in the co-movement
of growth rates of manufacturing and electricity
indices (Chart II.8). However, there was a divergence
between the two since June 2010 because even
as there was significant deceleration in the growth
of manufacturing sector, the growth in electricity
continued to remain buoyant due to the substitution
of petroleum products, especially diesel, with
electricity in other sectors of the economy. This was
reflected in the deceleration in the growth of diesel consumption. The increased electricity generation
also partly helped in reducing the power deficit in
the country from 10.1 per cent in 2009-10 to 8.5
per cent in 2011-12 in spite of increased demand
from household segment.
|
|
II.1.38 The gap between domestic demand and
supply of core industrial inputs has widened in
recent years. For coal, the gap has increased from
around 50 million tonnes in 2007-08 to 114 million
tonnes in 2011-12. The projected gap by the
terminal year of the 12th Five Year Plan (2016-17)
is expected to be 185 million tonnes. The policy of
captive mining, which was introduced to augment
production, has not helped the sector to the desired
extent. However, measures taken by the government
recently to ensure adequate coal supply to power
plants has helped improve coal output with average
growth during November-March 2011-12 rising to
8.5 per cent as against (-) 5.6 per cent during April-
October 2011-12. The coal sector grew by 6.4 per
cent in April-June 2012. Measures such as import
of coal and acquisition of coal assets abroad are
expected to help reduce the demand-supply gap.
It is important to ensure smooth shipments, port
handling and transportation of the coal imports to quickly bridge any supply shortages for the power
plants.
II.1.39 The government has initiated several steps
to augment the production of core sector in the
recent period. Augmenting resources for exploration
and mining through private sector participation has
yielded favourable results. The union budget for
2012-13 gave full exemption from basic customs
duty to fuels such as natural gas, liquefied natural
gas, steam coal and uranium concentrate imported
for power generation. To facilitate the development
of necessary infrastructure, viability gap funding has been extended to capital investment in fertiliser
industry, oil and gas storage and pipeline facilities
for supporting the scheme of public private
partnership (PPP).
II.1.40 The industrial sector, in particular,
manufacturing, is an important driver of growth and
source of employment. Though there is no official
estimate of capacity utilisation for the sector, given
the modest share of the sector in GDP, it is likely that
if enabling business environment and the required
infrastructure are provided, capacity utilisation in
the sector can be improved significantly (Box II.3).
Box II.3
Capacity Utilisation: Concept and Measurement in India
Capacity utilisation (CU), if properly assessed, could provide
a reliable indication of incipient inflationary pressure in an
economy. A realistic assessment of CU encapsulates the
demand pressure in an economy such that if market demand
grows, CU tends to rise, and if demand weakens, CU tends
to slacken. Therefore, higher CU is associated with higher
inflation.
Concept and Measurement
CU can be defined as the percentage of total productive
potential that is actually being utilised in a given period. CU
serves as an important indicator, reflecting the business
cycles as well as policy changes. Measures of CU are
extensively relied upon to help explain the changes in the rate
of investment, labour productivity and inflation.
There is no unique method for measurement of CU. CU can
be measured for an economy, industry or firm through survey
methods or use of production data. One important method of
measuring CU is the Wharton Method wherein capacity is
defined as the peak output achieved in each business cycle.
An implicit assumption of this method is that all short run
peaks in output represent 100 per cent CU. An alternative
method of tracking CU is through economic surveys of
operating metrics. However, the surveys generally offer a
subjective measure as they do not specify any explicit
definition of capacity. An alternative method of measuring CU
is the production frontier approach where the maximum
possible output (i.e., capacity output) for given input levels is
estimated.
Measurement of CU in India: Current Practices
In India, there is no single official estimate of CU. At present,
the Central Statistics Office in its monthly ‘Capsule Report on
Infrastructure Sector Performance’ provides some estimates
of CU in the core industries. The Reserve Bank in its quarterly
‘Order Books, Inventories and Capacity Utilisation Survey’ (OBICUS) provides estimates of the level of CU in the Indian
manufacturing sector. The level of CU is derived from the data
provided by companies as per the selected methodology. The
survey is canvassed among 2,500 public and private limited
companies in the manufacturing sector with a good size/
industry representation. Trend analysis is done to study the
movements in CU based on a common set of companies in
each round to facilitate better comparability of data over the
reference quarters. The results of the 17th round of the survey,
done for Q4 of 2011-12, were disseminated to the public in
July 2012.
The Federation of Indian Chambers of Commerce and
Industry in its quarterly ‘Business Confidence Survey’ and
‘Survey on Indian Manufacturing Sector’ provides assessment
of CU in the industrial sector. The National Council of Applied
Economic Research in its quarterly ‘Business Expectation
Survey’ also provides information on CU in Indian industries.
Thus, most of the estimates of CU in the Indian context are
based on survey methods. This is in line with the practice
followed by other countries as well. However, an attempt has
been made to measure CU in Indian industry using the
Wharton Method. The Wharton Method offers certain
advantages over the other traditional time series methods
due to its success in tracking demand pressures in the
economy. High CU rates are indicative of higher demand
pressure in an economy, and consequently higher inflation
rates. The CU rate in the Indian manufacturing sector
measured by Wharton School method has generally acted
as a lead indicator of inflationary pressure, which is consistent
with the theoretical expectation. Inflation in manufactured
products has a significant positive correlation of 0.54 with one
period lagged value of CU (Chart 1). Also, the broad trend in
CU as estimated by the Wharton method and OBICUS is the
same (Chart 2).
|
|
In practice, survey methods are preferred over time series
methods for estimating CU as the latter suffers from a number
of limitations. These include differing estimates obtained from
alternative methods, assumptions implying that the entire
capital stock available to the industrial sector has been used
with highest allocative efficiency (which is generally not the
case), the selection of peak output over a relatively short time
horizon of one year, the end point specification problem and
difficulties in specifying the exact form of the production
function for each firm. Major disadvantage of the time series
method arises from the revision of the base year as also the
variability of provisional data. For example, with the change
in base year of IIP to 2004-05 from 1993-94, the growth in
IIP has changed by as much as +/- 11 per cent in the new series. Thus, any method used to estimate CU should be
based on the exploration of competing methods emphasising
on conceptual suitability of alternative measures of capacity/
potential output, assessment of existing data gaps, and
interpretation and usage of different measures.
References
Mukherjee, A. and Rekha Misra (2012), “Estimation
of Capacity Utilisation in Indian Industries: Issues and
Challenges”, Reserve Bank of India Working Papers, May
Donde, K. and Mridul Saggar (1999), “Potential Output and
Output Gap: A Review”, Reserve Bank of India Occasional
Papers, Vol. 20, No. 3, Winter.
II.1.41 In countries such as China and some East
Asian economies, the share of manufacturing sector
in GDP ranges between 30-40 per cent. In India,
the share of manufacturing, has been around 14-16
per cent during the post-reform period. In this
regard, the National Manufacturing Policy, which
aims to increase the share of manufacturing sector
to 25 per cent of GDP by enhancing value addition
and improving competitiveness along with the
creation of 100 million jobs in the sector by 2022 is
expected to provide a major impetus to the
manufacturing sector.
Some moderation evident in services sector growth
II.1.42 Much of India’s growth performance in the
recent years has been contributed by the services
sector which showed considerable resilience during
the global economic crisis. However, some
deceleration is apparent in services sector recently
with growth slowing down to 8.5 per cent during
2011-12 compared to 9.2 per cent in the previous year (Chart II.9). The slowdown was mainly on
account of deceleration in construction which grew
by 5.3 per cent compared with 8.0 per cent in the previous year. The deceleration in services sector
is on account of both weakening demand as well
as inter-linkages with the industrial sector.
|
II.1.43 Construction activity slowed down as
housing inventories rose with price rigidities
observed in the industry to protect high profit
margins. With record road tendering in 2011-12,
construction activity could receive support in the
coming years. However, newer constraints for road
projects have emerged lately, reflected in sharp
drop in tendering during Q1 of 2012-13 (Chart II.10).
II.1.44 In 2001-12, ‘trade, hotels, transport and
communication’ also slowed given its strong linkage
with industrial activity. Slowdown in transportation
is also mirrored in deceleration in production of
commercial motor vehicles. Telecom industry
slowed down along with moderation in the number
of new cell phone connections, reflecting in part
imposition of regulatory penalties and in part
plateauing of penetration levels after a period of
extra-ordinary growth.
II.1.45 The outlook for the services sector depends
to a large extent on the revival of industrial growth
given the dependence of sub-sectors such as trade
and transport on industrial production. Prospects
of the sector also depend on the developments in
the global economic situation (Box II.4). Continued
fragility in economic conditions in the advanced
economies may have adverse impact on Indian
services exports.
Structural shift in employment evident in recent
years
II.1.46 In general, as economies grow there is a
shift in employment pattern away from agriculture
into manufacturing and then into service sector. In
India, the pace of transformation in the structure of
employment has been slow. Agriculture employed
53.2 per cent of the total work force in 2009-10,
while contributing around 14.7 per cent of GDP. On
the other hand, industry and services sector
contributed 20.2 per cent and 65.1 per cent,
respectively of GDP while employing only 11.9 per
cent and 35.0 per cent, respectively, of the work
force.
II.1.47 In recent years, there has been a shift in
employment away from agriculture and
manufacturing in favour of construction, transport
and communication (Chart II.11). Employment in
the construction sector increased by 62 per cent
between 2004-05 and 2009-10, accounting for most
of the employment generated during the period. As
regards the nature of employment, casual labour
accounted for most of the increase in overall
employment during this period, suggesting that the
employment generated may not be permanent.
II.1.48 During the period 2004-05 to 2009-10,
decline in employment is observed with respect
to youth and women. Employment among young
males in the age group of 15-19 years declined
by 12 per cent during this period. This was mainly due to increased enrolment rate in educational
institutions. Males in the 15-19 age-group who
reported attending educational institutions as their
primary activity increased from 51 per cent in
2004-05 to 63 per cent during 2009-10. As regards
women, there was a withdrawal from the labour
force reflected in the decline in the work participation
rate (WPR) among women across all age groups.
As a consequence, the proportion of women
engaged in domestic duties increased from 31.6
per cent in 2004-05 to 37.8 per cent in 2009-10.
Box II.4
Impact of Monetary Policy and External Demand on Services Sector Growth
India’s growth since the late 1980s has been driven by
services sector. The growth rates of almost all components
of the services sector picked up during the late 1980s
and increased significantly during 2005-08 (Table). Within
services sector, the expansion has been particularly strong
for communication and banking and insurance. The growth
rates of most of the sub-sectors, notably ‘communications’
continued to remain high even after the onset of the global
financial crisis, reflecting the resilience of the services sector.
The composition of the services sector shows that while
‘trade’ continues to remain the predominant sub-sector with
a share of around 24 per cent, the shares of both ‘banking
and insurance’ and ‘communications’ have registered
sharp increases over the years. The shares of ‘real estate,
ownership of dwellings and business services’ that includes
IT services and ‘construction’ have also remained high even
though these have declined somewhat in the post-crisis
period.
Services sector growth benefitted not only from liberalisation
after the initiation of structural reforms and the sharp increase
in per capita incomes but also from the inherent linkages
with the industrial sector. The trade, telecommunications,
banking and business services (including IT services)
sectors have particularly gained in this regard. The fairly
robust growth of the construction and real estate sectors is
reflective of rapid urbanisation.
In order to distill the impact of different factors, a linear
regression of services sector growth was run based on
annual data for the period 1980-81 to 2010-11. Dummy
variables were incorporated to take cognisance of the
initiation of structural reforms in 1991-92 (DREF), apart from
a few outliers (DYRS). The explanatory variables were the
call rate (CR) {as a monetary policy stance indicator}, WPI
inflation (INF), industrial sector growth (IND) and world GDP growth (WG). The results of the estimation are set out below:
SER = 7.23 – 0.20 CR(-1) – 0.18 INF + 0.12 IND + 0.41
WG(-1) + 1.93 DREF + 2.29 DYRS
Adj R -square = 0.81 DW = 1.84
All the coefficients are statistically significant at 1 per cent,
except IND which is significant at 5 per cent. The coefficients
also have expected signs. The results show that a one
percentage point increase in the call rate reduces services
sector growth by around 0.2 percentage point one period
ahead, largely reflecting the impact of an increase in the
cost of funds. The impact of a percentage point increase in
the inflation rate on services sector growth is nearly similar,
though contemporaneous. Robust industrial sector growth
provides support to the services sector. On the other hand,
lagged world GDP growth is an important factor for services
sector growth with coefficient of 0.41.
References:
Banga, R. and Bishwanath Goldar (2004), “Contribution
of Services to Output Growth and Productivity in Indian
Manufacturing: Pre and Post Reforms” ICRIER Working
Paper, No.139, July.
Eichengreen, B. and Poonam Gupta (2011), “The Service
Sector as India’s Road to Economic Growth”, NBER Working
Paper, No. 16757, February.
Gordon, J. and Poonam Gupta (2004), “Understanding
India’s Services Revolution” IMF Working Paper, WP/04/171,
September.
Kaur, G., Sanjob Bordoloi and Raj Rajesh (2009), “An
Empirical Investigation of the Inter-Sectoral Linkages in
India”, Reserve Bank of India Occasional Paper, Vol. 30, No.
1, Summer.
Table: Services Sector Growth |
(Per cent) |
|
Growth Rates |
Shares in Services Sector |
1980-83 |
1988-91 |
2005-08 |
2008-11 |
1980-83 |
1988-91 |
2005-08 |
2008-11 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
Construction |
3.9 |
8.6 |
11.3 |
6.8 |
16.2 |
13.8 |
12.9 |
12.2 |
Trade |
5.6 |
6.4 |
10.7 |
8.0 |
24.4 |
23.5 |
24.2 |
23.3 |
Hotels and restaurants |
7.2 |
8.9 |
14.9 |
2.4 |
1.9 |
1.9 |
2.6 |
2.3 |
Railways |
4.6 |
2.5 |
9.5 |
8.0 |
3.0 |
2.5 |
1.6 |
1.5 |
Transport by other means |
6.7 |
6.2 |
9.0 |
7.0 |
8.6 |
8.7 |
9.1 |
8.5 |
Storage |
2.0 |
1.3 |
6.3 |
10.3 |
0.3 |
0.2 |
0.1 |
0.1 |
Communication |
6.5 |
6.1 |
24.0 |
28.0 |
0.8 |
0.7 |
3.4 |
5.3 |
Banking and insurance |
6.9 |
11.9 |
17.7 |
13.3 |
5.5 |
7.7 |
10.7 |
12.2 |
Real estate, ownership of dwellings and business services |
6.4 |
8.2 |
9.5 |
8.4 |
13.5 |
15.5 |
14.5 |
14.2 |
Public administration and defence |
4.9 |
5.2 |
4.6 |
13.1 |
12.3 |
13.1 |
8.6 |
9.2 |
Other services |
3.4 |
7.0 |
6.3 |
7.3 |
15.4 |
14.3 |
12.2 |
11.2 |
Services Sector |
5.3 |
7.2 |
10.5 |
9.5 |
45.4* |
49.0* |
62.1* |
64.9* |
*: Share of services sector in GDP. Source: Central Statistics Office. |
II.1.49 Along with the lower growth in employment,
increase in real wages has also been significant in
the recent period. Reduction in WPR has resulted
in labour market tightening which could have partly
contributed to rising real wages. Also, the introduction
of the MGNREGA which resulted in eight-fold
increase in public works since 2004-05 along with
increase in higher minimum wage for public works
could also have contributed to rising real wages.
However, the public works accounted for less than
2 per cent of total person-days of rural employment
in 2009-10. Moreover, increase in wages for public
works has been lower than increase in wages for
casual laboureres engaged in non-public sector
works as well as regular/salaried employees.
II.1.50 Overall, the sharp deceleration in growth in
2011-12 was on account of both cyclical and
structural factors. After a firm recovery in 2010-11,
a cyclical downturn set in, induced by global factors and high inflation. The slowdown was exacerbated
by the structural rigidities in the economy. As these
structural rigidities are yet to be addressed, growth
may stay low in the near term. The constraints are
particularly severe in the infrastructure, mining and
metal space. Investment demand could revive
gradually once these are addressed.
II.2 PRICE SITUATION
Inflation remained high for the second year in a row
II.2.1 The high inflation phase that started in the
last quarter of 2009-10 persisted and became
generalised over two consecutive years. Inflation
remained elevated at over 9 per cent in the first
eight months of 2011-12, before softening
moderately in December. It has since remained
sticky in the range of 6.9-7.7 per cent. Non-food
manufactured products inflation remained over 5
per cent for 23 consecutive months, but moderated
from a high of 8.4 per cent in November 2011 to
below 5 per cent by March 2012 with significant
moderation in investment demand and weaker
growth momentum. Sustained input cost pressures,
however, imparted downward rigidity to non-food
manufactured products inflation since then, even
though pricing power weakened, resulting in
pressures on corporate earnings. The weakening
pricing power on the back of slowing growth and
monetary tightening, along with favourable base
effects and transitory softening of food prices, especially vegetables, contributed to the moderation
in inflation.
II.2.2 Notwithstanding the moderation, inflation
remained high with headline WPI inflation remaining
at 6.9 per cent in July 2012 and retail price inflation
as per new Consumer Price Index (CPI) remaining
near double digits. Inflation prevailed above the
threshold level at which growth-inflation trade off
stops working and high inflation turns inimical to
growth and growth sustainability (see Box II.4 of
the Annual Report 2010-11).
II.2.3 The monetary policy response of the
Reserve Bank during the year was based on the
assessment of drivers of inflation, particularly the
changing role of aggregate demand relative to other
determinants of inflation and time-varying multiple
risk factors. Monetary policy was continuously
tightened up to October 2011 given the high and
persistent generalised inflation. Subsequently,
amplified risks to growth and some moderation in
inflation warranted a shift in the balance of weight
in the conduct, stance and guidance on monetary
policy (for details, see Chapter III).
Generalisation of price pressures persisted despite
softening of growth momentum
II.2.4 The persistent nature of inflation during
recent years can be gauged from the trends in the average rate of inflation during the past few years
along with trends in volatility (as measured by the
coefficient of variation of monthly inflation during
the year). While the average rate of inflation
increased significantly during 2010-11 and 2011-
12, inflation volatility declined considerably (Chart
II.12a). Lower volatility at a high level indicates the
persistence of generalised high inflation and at the
same time reflects the impact of tighter monetary
policy in containing it from spiralling up further. Also,
inflation across different commodity groups within
WPI indicate that its variability declined for most of
the period since the second half of 2009-10
indicating generalisation of price pressures (Chart
II.12b). The decline in overall inflation during
October 2011-January 2012 was marked by
increasing variability as only few items contributed
to the moderation in inflation. Since January 2012,
the variability has come down indicating that the
decline in inflation has spread to a number of
commodities.
II.2.5 Since 1970s, there have been seven
episodes of high and persistent inflation in India
where the headline WPI inflation was above 8 per
cent for more than six months on a sustained basis
(Table II.2). Most of these episodes resulted in high
inflation persisting for about 2-3 years. Even though
these high inflation periods had different drivers like
oil shocks, drought and currency devaluation, persistence of inflation seems to be a common
pattern when inflation turns high.
Table II.2: Episodes of High Inflation in India: 1971 to 2012 |
Period |
Average Inflation |
Number of Months |
WPI |
CPI-IW |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
July 1972 - Apr 1975 |
19.3 |
19.4 |
34 |
May 1979 - Dec 1981 |
15.7 |
11.1 |
32 |
Aug 1987 - Jul 1988 |
8.8 |
9.6 |
12 |
Feb 1990 - Dec 1992 |
11.3 |
11.7 |
35 |
Sep 1993 - Nov 1995 |
10.0 |
9.9 |
27 |
May 2008 - Nov 2008 |
10.2 |
9.1 |
7 |
Jan 2010 - Nov 2011 |
9.6 |
10.7 |
23 |
II.2.6 Nonetheless, the current high inflation
phase is one of the longest phases of high inflation
since the mid-1990s. Why inflation has been so
persistent even in the wake of a growth slowdown
has become an important issue for monetary policy.
It may be noted that all three major drivers of
inflation, viz., food, fuel and core have been
significantly contributing to the high and persistent
inflation. While food inflation has generally been
volatile with large swings in the prices of certain
food items like vegetables, the major driver of food
inflation has been protein-rich items whose prices
continue to grow at a faster pace. Both increased
demand on account of structural changes in dietary
patterns and rising input costs driven by increases
in wages have contributed to the increase in protein
inflation.
II.2.7 Even though fuel inflation remains
suppressed due to the administered price
mechanism, increases in fuel prices had kept fuel
inflation in double digits for more than two years
(Appendix Table 8). However, fuel inflation moderated
to 6.0 per cent in July 2012 as domestic prices of
administered fuel products have not been raised in
past one year. Pressure on core inflation was visible
from rising input costs- raw materials, fuel and staff
costs. So, apart from demand pressures, cost
pressures were also reflected in core inflation.
II.2.8 The WPI exhibited a sustained increase
during 2011-12, even though the pace of increase
somewhat slowed down during the latter half of the
year (Chart II.13). The increase in the WPI during
the initial months of the year was driven by a host
of factors that included an increase in food prices,
a revision in the administered prices of fuel as well
as an increase in manufactured product prices in
the wake of significant pressure from high input
costs as well as strong demand and pricing power.
The decline in growth during 2011-12 was expected
to ease the pressure on core inflation. However, the
extent of moderation was constrained by further
pressure from rupee depreciation and high global
commodity prices.
II.2.9 The phase of softening of inflation was
marked by a decline in the contribution of food,
which again increased from February 2012 as
prices increased sharply after the seasonal decline.
The contribution of non-food manufactured products remained strong despite the deceleration in growth
momentum (Chart II.14). The contribution of fuel
group to overall inflation remained high and
significant throughout the year despite suppressed
inflation from the administered prices of some
petro-products, coal and electricity.
Food inflation rebounded after declining during the
year
II.2.10 India had a normal south-west monsoon
during 2011, which had a moderating impact on
the prices of select food items, especially cereals
and pulses, for which the average inflation during
the year was moderate at 3.6 per cent. However,
food inflation driven by non-cereal items, whose
output is less responsive to monsoon in the shortrun,
remained high (Chart II.15). There is some
evidence that rising per-capita incomes and
changes in dietary patterns led to increase in demand for protein-rich items. Input cost pressures
have also been significant in recent years, with
significant increases in wages. Besides weak
supply responses, input cost pressures sustained
the food inflation at a high level, except for
occasional seasonal declines. Primary food articles
inflation declined sharply during November 2011–
January 2012, from above 10 per cent to negative
territory, largely reflecting a seasonal decline in the
prices of vegetables and a favourable base effect.
However, prices rebounded significantly
subsequently, resulting in food inflation reverting to
double-digit levels by April 2012. The prices of
protein-based food articles have remained
persistently high since October 2011.
II.2.11 Managing food inflation requires measures
to augment supply since demand management
through monetary policy to contain food inflation has its own limits and costs in terms of growth
sacrifice. Food inflation has not only exhibited
greater volatility at higher average levels, but there
is also increasing divergence between prices at the wholesale and retail levels. This points to the role
of rigidities in the supply chain. Effective policy
interventions in this regard need to take into
account several institutional factors (Box II.5).
Box II.5
Supply Chain Management in Agriculture: Farm Gate to Retail Market
In explaining large volatility in commodity prices, especially
of farm products, the concept of farm retail spread, developed
within the paradigm of supply chain management, is
traditionally employed to characterise marketing efficiency.
An efficient marketing system minimises the cost of marketing
services to ensure the largest possible share for the producer
in the consumer’s rupee. Various micro-level studies in India
have found that the producer’s share in final price of many
agricultural commodities (which undergo little value addition
from the point of leaving the farm gate) is not very high. As
these studies were conducted at different times and for
different commodities, the results cannot be generalised.
However, they provide a sufficiently clear picture of the
inefficiencies that existed or exist in the supply chain
management of various commodities. These inefficiencies
have been especially reflected in high food inflation led by
protein items. With income increases and demographic
transition, the supply chain is struggling to meet the demand
(Gokarn, 2011).
The marketing channels for various commodities are
distinguished from each other based on the market
functionaries involved in carrying the produce from the farmers
to the ultimate consumers. The length of the marketing
channel depends on the size of the market, the nature of the
commodity and the pattern of demand at the consumer level.
These channels as identified in micro level studies can be
classified into (i) Producer-Consumer, (ii) Producer-Retailer-
Consumer, (iii) Producer-Wholesaler-Retailer-Consumer,
(iv) Producer-Commission agent-Wholesaler-Retailer-
Consumer and (v) Producer-Village Merchant-Wholesaler-
Retailer-Consumer. As mentioned by Balappa and Hugar
(2003) while Channels (i) and (ii) are slowly emerging, other
channels are well established, with the farmers preferring
shorter supply chain channels among them. Gupta and
Sharma (2009) found that farmers are not solely guided by
the marketing efficiency of the channel (which secures the
maximum producer’s share in the consumer’s rupee), but also
seek to market their produce through channels that serve
retail markets with the capability to absorb larger supplies.
Finally, intermediaries in the value chain of several
commodities exist to tap the scale economies associated with
services like transportation (Saraswat, 2009).
The three major challenges in the supply chain environment
are: 1) improving the accessibility of regulated markets,
2) promoting greater competitiveness by suitable amendments
to Agricultural Produce Market Committee (APMC) Act and
3) facilitating the emergence of a nationwide common market.
Although the ideal density of regulated markets could be
15,000 to 18,000 ha of gross cropped area as mentioned in
the Report of the ‘Working Group on Agricultural Marketing Infrastructure and Policy Required for Internal and External
Trade for the Eleventh Five-Year Plan’, it varies between
13,580 ha in West Bengal to 37,050 ha in Madhya Pradesh.
Suggestions have also been made to reform the APMC Act
to address the perceived concerns regarding mandi
governance (Economic Survey, 2011-12) and monopolistic
tendencies (Inter-Ministerial Group on Inflation). The different
rates of entry tax/octroi tax and sales tax that vary across
states as well as across commodities prevent the emergence
of a nationwide common market for agricultural produce.
Moreover, restrictions on the movement of goods under the
Essential Commodities Act remain in place in various states.
The suggestions from various policy documents to strengthen
the supply chain can be classified as: 1) enhancing the
capabilities of farmers, 2) strengthening infrastructure, and
3) legislative interventions. By encouraging farmers to
organise themselves into groups – growers’ groups, cooperatives,
self-help groups and producer companies – supply
chains can be streamlined as well as made more egalitarian.
Also, investments across the entire agri-value chain spectrum,
such as creation of cold chains, rural godowns, new
agricultural marketing infrastructure, and modernisation of
existing markets could be promoted by providing them with
tax holidays and suitable exemptions. As suggested by the
Inter-Ministerial Group on Inflation, perishables could be taken
out of the ambit of the APMC Act to encourage arbitrage
activity by small traders and farmers by allowing them to freely
trade perishables through buying where it is cheap and selling
where it is expensive. Similarly from the long-term perspective
of inflation management, it is crucial to improve mandi
governance by holding regular elections of agricultural
produce market committees as well as to bring professionalism
into the functioning of the existing regulated markets through
public private partnership.
References
Balappa, S.R. and L. B. Hugar (2003), ‘An Economic
Evaluation of Onion Production and its Marketing System in
Karnataka’, Agricultural Marketing, Vol.XLVI (2), July-
September.
Gokarn, Subir (2011), “Striking a Balance between Growth
and Inflation in India” presentation at Brookings Institution
June 27, 2011.
Gupta, M. and K.D. Sharma (2009), ‘Production and Marketing
of Ginger in Himachal Pradesh’ Agricultural Situation in India,
Vol. LXVI(13), 681-686.
Saraswat, S.P. (2009), ‘Understanding the apple marketing
system of Himachal Pradesh with reference to Kiari village
of Shimla’ Agricultural Situation in India, Vol. LXVI(4), July,
187-190.
Suppressed fuel inflation through administered
pricing continued
II.2.12 Pressure from the sustained increase in
global oil prices continued during 2011-12. Global
crude oil prices (Indian Basket), which averaged
US$85 per barrel during 2010-11 increased by
about 31 per cent to US$112 per barrel during
2011-12. The increase in domestic mineral oil
prices, however, was much lower, by about 17 per
cent (Chart II.16). Freely priced product prices
moved in line with the changes in international
prices while administered fuel prices were revised
in June 2011. Despite the revision in administered
prices of fuel, the suppressed inflation in the energy
segment remains significant. This has resulted in
under-recoveries to the amount of `1.38 trillion
during 2011-12, with the bulk of under-recoveries
(about 59 per cent) coming from diesel. This would
entail higher subsidies to the oil marketing
companies with its attendant fiscal pressure on
inflation.
II.2.13 Among the other major items in the fuel
group, one major pressure on overall inflation has
been the changes in the prices of coal. In January
2012, the price of non-coking coal was increased
by 33 per cent, contributing thereby to an increase in the overall WPI by 0.34 per cent in terms of the
direct impact. Given that coal is an input for many
industries, including electricity generation, changes
in coal prices do transmit to generalised inflation.
Recent emerging trends in the coal sector indicate
the need to address basic issues in this sector
(Box II.6). Also, electricity price increases in the
past have been much lower than the increase in input costs, which has also severely impacted the
finances of state-run electricity boards.
Box II.6
Need for Revamping Coal Policy to Address Supply Shortages and Suppressed Inflation
Coal is one of the world’s most important sources of energy,
fuelling around 42 per cent of electricity generation worldwide
and also meeting about 30 per cent of global primary energy
needs. In India, two-third of the country’s electricity generation
is based on coal. India’s coal reserves have been assessed
at about 286 billion tonnes as on April 1, 2011, of which 114
billion tonnes (or 40 per cent of total reserves) are proven
reserves according to the Geological Survey of India (GSI).
At the current level of production of around 540 million tonnes
per annum in 2011-12, the coal reserves in the country are
expected to last for more than 100 years.
Despite being the third largest producer of coal in the world,
India is a significant net importer of coal as the country’s
domestic production is insufficient to meet the large and
growing needs of power companies, steel mills and cement
producers (Chart 1).
According to the Ministry of Coal, the gap in demand and
domestic supply of coal has increased to 161 million tonnes (MT) in 2011-12 from about 43.4 MT in 2006-07. According
to the revised estimates of the Ministry of Coal, the demand
is projected to increase to 980 million tonnes in the terminal year (2016-17) of the 12th Five-Year Plan, against which
indigenous availability is projected to be 795 million tonnes.
Therefore, the gap between demand and domestic availability
is projected to be 185 million tonnes which needs to be
bridged by importing coal.
|
The shortage of coal is affecting electricity generation in
different power plants. According to the Central Electricity
Authority, power generation utilities have already reported a
production loss of 8.7 billion units during 2011-12 (up to
February 2012) on top of an 8.4 billion unit loss in 2010-11
and a 14.5 billion unit loss in 2009-10 on account of coal
shortage. The Ministry of Coal pointed out that coal shortage
has resulted in a significant increase in coal imports, from
43.1 MT in 2006-07 to 98.9 MT in 2011-12. Higher import
dependence calls for parity between domestic and
international prices, given the known adverse implications of
administered pricing of petroleum products for domestic
imbalances. International coal prices have been higher than
domestic coal prices even when adjusted for quality and the
divergence has persisted for some time, despite the fact that
domestic coal prices were completely de-regulated in 2000.
Coal India Limited (CIL), that provides 80 per cent of the
domestic supplies, periodically fixes the price of coal in line
with market prices. Thus, a combination of higher import
dependence and elevated international prices of coal has the
potential to impact key macro indicators like inflation, growth,
fiscal deficit and current account deficit, as witnessed in the
case of oil imports, although the magnitude may differ.
A revision in the coal pricing formula was contemplated in
January 2012 to bring domestic coal prices in line with
international prices. However, the increase was rolled back
subsequently as the overall coal price increase on account
of the new pricing was substantial. This would have increased
the input costs for power generation and the steel and cement
industries which would have been inflationary. According to
the New Coal Distribution Policy (NCDP), coal supplies are
governed by legally enforceable agreements between the
seller (coal companies) and the consumer under specific
terms and conditions. Various model Fuel Supply Agreements
(FSAs) exist for different categories of consumers. The
Government recently decided that CIL would sign FSAs with
power plants that have entered into long-term Power Purchase
Agreements (PPAs) with distribution companies (DISCOMs)
and have been commissioned/would get commissioned on
or before March 31, 2015. In this context, CIL has proposed
a new FSA assuring coal supply at 80 per cent of the annual
contracted quantity with a penalty of 0.01 per cent in case of
shortfall in supply, operative after a period of three years after
signing of FSA. These terms are not acceptable to the power
sector. In this backdrop, a large part of the new capacities in
power sector are at risk due to coal shortages. These, in part,
would have to be met by imported coal at higher cost. As
such, pooled coal prices would need to go up. Even in case
of the FSAs, the domestic price of coal may see upward
revisions in the coming years as the FSAs assure coal
supplies at the notified prices, which are subject to revision
from time to time.
Inflationary pressures on core component eased
in the latter half of the year
II.2.14 Non-food manufactured products inflation,
which remained at or above 7 per cent during
February–December 2011, moderated significantly
to below 5 per cent by March 2012. The high inflation
in this segment during the initial part of the year
was on account of the sharp increase in input cost
pressures, which the firms could pass on in the
presence of buoyant demand. As growth decelerated,
the pricing power of firms weakened, which led to
a decline in the inflation momentum in this category
on a sustained basis in the second half of the year.
During Q1 of 2012-13, non-food manufactured
products inflation ruled at for 5.0 per cent before
rising to 5.4 per cent in July 2012 (Chart II.17).
Global commodity prices generally moderated, with
some hardening in the latter half of the year
II.2.15 Global commodity prices exhibited a
contrarian trend relative to domestic inflation during
2011-12. Commodity prices trended downwards for
the larger part of the year, factoring in deepening
euro area debt problems, risks to global growth,
easing of geo-political tensions in the Middle East
and improved supply prospects in key commodities,
including agricultural commodities (Chart II.18).
During the last quarter of 2011-12, however,
commodity prices, especially crude oil, increased
significantly, following geo-political tensions in Iran
and improved growth prospects for the US. Although
commodity prices moderated significantly since
March 2012, tight demand-supply conditions in key
commodities along with the presence of large
liquidity in the global market keep commodity prices
highly vulnerable to shocks. This is evident from the
recent reversal in energy prices as well as increase
in global food prices as drought in US and
unfavourable weather conditions in Europe and
other major producers impacted on supplies.
Exchange rate movements impacted the inflation
trajectory
II.2.16 Apart from trends in commodity prices,
exchange rate movements also impacted the overall
inflation path. The pass-through of depreciation of
the rupee since August 2011 has often either
amplified or dampened the impact of commodity prices, depending on the direction and magnitude
of commodity price changes. Empirical estimates
in the Indian case indicate that the pass-through
has declined over time (Box II.7). However, given
the magnitude of depreciation of the rupee since
August 2011, the exchange rate became a source
of pressure on inflation.
Widening fiscal gap poses threat to inflation
moderation
II.2.17 Although the government had envisaged a
path for fiscal consolidation during 2011-12, the
shortfall on achieving the target on key deficit
indicators emerged as a major issue in inflation
management. The shortfall in revenue partly on
account of the growth slowdown and the increase
in the subsidy burden, particularly in fuel and
fertilisers, contributed to the widening of the deficit
(for details, see Section II.5: Government Finances).
Though fiscal intervention in terms of administered
prices kept part of the inflation suppressed in the
near-term, overshooting of expenditure increases
aggregate demand and leads to medium-term risk
to price stability.
Wage pressures on inflation remained significant
II.2.18 High inflation, through its impact on inflation
expectations, could influence wage-setting
behaviour and thereby generate a wage-price spiral.
Available empirical evidence in the recent period
indicates that wages both in rural areas and in the
manufacturing sector, have been growing at a rate faster than inflation (Chart II.19). There is significant
divergence in wage-price relationship in rural areas
across different states which point towards the role of state specific factors in conditioning the
overall wage-inflation dynamics (Chart II.20).
Increases in real wages indicate that inflation is not always a tax on the working population,
particularly when the wage increase is in excess
of productivity growth. The pressure on inflation
from wages has become more visible in the post
Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment
Guarantee Scheme (MGNREGS) period, as
MGNREGS provides a floor to wages in rural
areas, which are also indexed to inflation
(Box II.8).
|
Box II.7
Rupee Depreciation Impact on Inflation
Exchange rate pass-through (ERPT) reflects the percentage
change in local currency import prices following a one per
cent change in the exchange rate between importing and
exporting countries. Pass-through of depreciation of
exchange rate to domestic consumer price inflation seems
to have declined across several countries over time, partly
reflecting the result of a switchover to inflation-focused
monetary policy frameworks and the success of monetary
policy in anchoring inflation expectations (Mishkin, 2008).
When commitment of monetary policy to inflation is strong
and credible and inflation expectations remain well-anchored,
the impact of shocks – whether from aggregate demand,
energy prices or the exchange rate – on inflation expectations
and trend inflation may be weaker.
Monetary policy performance in anchoring inflation
expectations, however, is only one among several determinants
of pass-through. Other determinants of pass-through include:
(a) inflation persistence, (b) pricing to market behaviour, (c)
price elasticity of demand in the importing country, (d) share
of local distribution and marketing costs in the final retail price,
(e) size of a country, (f) degree of openness, (g) exchange
rate volatility and persistence of exchange rate shocks, and
most importantly (h) domestic demand conditions at the time
of the depreciation of the exchange rate.
Pricing-to-market behaviour may indicate that exporters from
the rest of the world are partially absorbing the impact of the
depreciation in the importing country. If domestic manufactures
of import substitutes keep their prices unchanged, it also
weakens pass-through. Disaggregated commodity-wise
analysis could suggest that price elasticity of demand for
certain items – like gold and oil – may be low, which in turn
would imply higher pass-through in such items. At times,
however, because of suppressed inflation reflecting fiscal
policy interventions in the pricing of imported items, passthrough
may remain depressed. With rising openness, higher
import penetration may also increase pass-through. If
depreciation is perceived to be short-lived and not permanent,
pass-through may not be high. Misalignment of the exchange
rate, in terms of the behaviour of the Real Effective Exchange
Rate (REER), could often be a lead indicator of how the
market perceives depreciation. An important determinant of
pass-through could be domestic demand conditions, which
is an indicator of pricing power. In items that are price elastic,
weak domestic demand would significantly limit the pricing
power of firms. As a result, both exporting firms from the rest
of the world and the importing firm in the country of
depreciation may have to adjust their profit margins resulting
in lower pass-through.
In India, monetary policy over time has established greater
commitment to the inflation objective despite a multi-objective
and multi-indicator approach to policy. However, because of
successive supply shocks, in recent years inflation
persistence, often at elevated levels, has been experienced.
Large misalignments in exchange rate have been generally
non-existent, and the Reserve Bank’s emphasis on containing
volatility in the exchange rate has ensured stability. India’s
openness, in terms of share of imports in GDP, however, has
increased but suppressed inflation in petroleum products
continues, despite the importance of market-based pricing
to improve the fiscal position.
Empirical evidence on ERPT in India finds overwhelming
evidence for an incomplete pass-through even though there
is varied evidence on the quantum of pass-through.
Khundrakpam (2007) found that there was no clear-cut
evidence of a fall in exchange rate pass-through to domestic
prices after the 1991 reforms. Further, there was asymmetry
in pass-through between appreciation and depreciation, and
between sizes of the exchange rate change. Bhattacharya
et al. (2008) found that a one per cent change in the exchange
rate causes a 0.04–0.17 per cent change in the CPI level
and a 0.29 per cent change in the WPI level in the long run.
Mallick and Marques (2008) found that the pass-through
remained incomplete in the 1990s but exceeded the tariff
rate pass-through.
ERPT, in recent years, has been low, perhaps due to
significant suppressed inflation in petroleum products. It is
also possible that exporters from the rest of the world might
have absorbed part of the impact in order to retain their
market share in India, which in turn would have led to a
somewhat lower pass-through. Given the depressed global
demand conditions, pricing-to-market behaviour of exporters
from the rest of the world might have contributed to the
decline in the estimated pass-through impact on inflation.
Reference
Khundrakpam, Jeevan Kumar (2007), “Economic reforms
and exchange rate pass-through to domestic prices in India”,
BIS Working Paper No.225.
Bhattacharya, Rudrani, Ila Pattnaik and Ajay Shah (2008),
“Exchange rate pass-through in India”, available at
http://macrofinance.nipfp.org.in/PDF/BPS2008_erpt.pdf.
Mallick, Sushanta and Helena Marques (2008), “Passthrough
of exchange rate and tariffs into import prices of
India: currency depreciation versus import liberalisation”,
Review of International Economics, 16(4): 765-782.
New CPI suggests higher inflation in the ‘non-food
non-oil category’, with much of the pressures visible
in services.
II.2.19 While the Reserve Bank continued to
present its inflation outlook in terms of WPI inflation for the conduct of its monetary policy, inflation
assessment has always been based on both WPI
and different measures of CPI. The greater reliance
on WPI for monetary policy in contrast with a
reliance on CPI for most other countries reflected
better data quality arising from more frequent data
availability (until the weekly series was
discontinued), the shorter lags with which data is
available, a wider basket of commodities and a
more up-to-date base year. From January 2012,
inflation numbers based on the new CPI with a
more recent base (year 2010=100) became
available. The new series has, however, shown
significant divergence relative to WPI and other
CPI measures, both in terms of level and the overall trend (Chart II.21). While a certain degree of
divergence was expected because of the difference
in coverage, weights and price quotes of different
indices, a rising inflation path in an environment of
softening growth momentum has raised the
question of whether price rigidities are more at the
retail level as compared to the wholesale level.
Even when the volatile components are removed
to make an assessment of the behaviour of the
price situation relative to demand conditions, the
‘non-food non-oil’ CPI-All India inflation remains
above ‘non-food non-oil’ inflation in WPI (Table II.3).
The inclusion of services and rent as also the
collection of price quotes at the retail level explain part of the divergence. Higher CPI inflation
suggests that the cost of inflation from the
standpoint of consumer welfare has been much
higher than appears from trends in WPI. However,
until data on the new CPI over a longer time period
become available, it would be difficult to assess its
behaviour in relation to other key macroeconomic
variables. Till such time, it may be difficult to fully
assess the information content of the new CPI for
monetary policy purposes, but the new index is
viewed as supplementary evidence on price trends
at the retail level.
|
|
Table II.3: WPI and New-CPI (Combined) Inflation |
|
Food |
Fuel |
Excluding Food and Fuel |
Overall |
WPI |
New CPI |
WPI |
New CPI |
WPI |
New CPI |
WPI |
New CPI |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
Weight |
24.3 |
47.6 |
14.9 |
9.5 |
60.8 |
42.9 |
100 |
100 |
Jan-12 |
1.5 |
3.9 |
17.0 |
13.0 |
7.5 |
10.6 |
7.2 |
7.5 |
Feb-12 |
5.9 |
6.7 |
15.1 |
12.8 |
6.3 |
10.4 |
7.6 |
8.8 |
Mar-12 |
8.7 |
8.1 |
12.8 |
11.8 |
5.8 |
10.2 |
7.7 |
9.4 |
Apr-12 |
9.1 |
10.1 |
12.1 |
11.2 |
5.4 |
10.2 |
7.5 |
10.3 |
May-12 |
9.0 |
10.5 |
11.5 |
10.7 |
5.7 |
10.1 |
7.5 |
10.4 |
June-12 |
9.0 |
10.8 |
10.3 |
10.3 |
5.6 |
9.1 |
7.3 |
10.0 |
Box II.8
The Risk of Wage-Price Spiral: What the Empirical Evidence for India Suggests
Cost-push inflation caused by sustained wage pressures has
always been a dominant theoretical determinant of inflation,
even though over time the relevance of wage-push as an
independent determinant of inflation has been subjected to
rigorous empirical scrutiny. Wage-push inflation results when
nominal wage rate increases exceed growth in labour
productivity and firms, instead of taking the pressure on their
profit margins, pass on the higher wage costs in the form of
higher prices. As workers get higher wages, they sustain their
demand for goods and services when inflation rises, and,
with a lag, demand even higher wages. This leads to wageprice
spiral.
Conventional wisdom suggests that activity in labour markets
could be a lead indicator of inflation. A fall in the unemployment
rate relative to the natural rate could mean an overheating
of the economy and, hence, higher wage inflation and
headline inflation. Wage-price inflation, thus, has a common
determinant, i.e. labour market conditions. Wage inflation
and price inflation, therefore, may exhibit co-movement and
there could also be bi-directional causality; but a wage-price
spiral independent of positive output-gap and tight labour
market conditions could be difficult to sustain.
Empirical evidence, however, suggests that wages have
increased even with high unemployment, implying that wage
inflation is increasingly less responsive to unemployment
trends. There have been episodes of both unemployment
declining without much corresponding improvement in growth
(such as the recent Bernanke conundrum) and also high
growth accompanied by inadequate job creation (such as
the concern about job-less growth in India). Moreover,
alongside higher unemployment in advanced economies, the
announced job vacancy rate at times also increases,
suggesting an upward shift in the Beveridge curve (which
shows the relationship between unemployment rate and
vacancy rate). This often reflects the gap between skill needs
for open vacancies and the skill set possessed by the
unemployed. Thus, when there is a large premium for skills,
wages may increase even with high unemployment. Till the
skill gap persists, wages could keep rising. Another major
driver of wage-push inflation often could be wage indexation,
in which case wage-push may become an independent
determinant of inflation.
At times, instead of using hard options to contain inflation,
a country may opt for a soft option like wage indexation to
limit the costs of high inflation to the common man. In that
process, however, the economy gets exposed to other risks.
The first such risk is that “…indexation weakens policymakers’
will to fight inflation” (Ball and Cecchetti, 1989). As
underscored by Okun (1971), wage indexation “may be read
as evidence that the government has raised its tolerance
level of inflation …It is quite rational to expect that the more
effectively the government can minimise the social costs of
inflation (through indexation), the more inflation it will accept”.
Second, wage indexation will tighten the constraint of wage
rigidity and lead to misallocation of resources by preventing
necessary relative wage adjustments relative to productivity
trends in different sectors. In any disinflation policy strategy, nominal downward rigidity of wages is a major constraint,
which gets amplified with wage indexation. Keeping real
wage growth at a rate that does not exceed productivity
growth is important for both long-term growth and external
competitiveness. As noted by Mihaljek and Saxena (2010),
skilled labour shortages and public sector wage policies are
two factors that could lead to real wages exceeding
productivity in emerging economies.
Table 1: Causal Relationship between Wages and
Inflation in Rural India |
Sample: May 2001 to February 2012 |
Null Hypothesis: |
F-Statistic |
Prob. |
Wage Change does not Granger cause Price Change |
5.77 |
0.004 |
Price Change does not Granger cause Wage Change |
2.88 |
0.060 |
In India, in the post-MGNREGS period, wages in rural areas
have increased at a faster rate than inflation. Agricultural
growth in the Eleventh Plan period has remained below the
4 per cent target, but real wages have increased at a higher
rate. Even in urban areas, annual wage increases have
been strong, despite weaker output growth in the recent
years. The coverage of MGNREGS in terms of total mandays
employed, may not be significant enough to exert
pressure on inflation from demand pressures arising from
income transfers. However, the major inflationary risk
emerges from MGNREGS exerting pressure on the overall
wage structure, and also raising the wage level annually
because of wage indexation. The risk of an emerging wageprice
spiral in India can be studied empirically using the
limited available data on rural wages and industrial sector
wage data. Empirical estimates based on monthly wages
for rural unskilled labourers and CPI rural labourer’s inflation
(available from the Labour Bureau) indicate that there is a
bi-directional causality between wage inflation and price
inflation (Table 1) implying that there is evidence of a wageprice
spiral.
In the organised manufacturing sector, the average wage per
worker was growing at a moderate rate of 3.9 per cent per
annum during the period 2000-01 to 2005-06, which
accelerated to 9.3 per cent during 2006-07 to 2009-10.
Available evidence on the wage-price spiral partly explains
the stickiness of the inflation path and why cyclical moderation
in growth momentum does not lead to a corresponding
softening of inflation.
Reference
Ball, Laurence and Stephen G. Cecchetti (1989), “Wage
Indexation and Time-Consistent Monetary Policy,” NBER
Working Papers 2948, National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Mihaljek, Dubravko and Sweta Saxena (2010), “Wages,
productivity and “structural” inflation in emerging market
economies”, BIS Working Papers No.49, BIS.
Okun, Arthur M. (1971), “The Mirage of Steady Inflation.”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 2, 485-98.
Inflationary pressures likely to persist in 2012-13
II.2.20 Going forward, risks to inflation remain from
unsatisfactory monsoon and increases in MSP even
as growth slowdown eases demand pressures.
Monsoon till August 16, 2012 has been 16 per cent
below Long Period Average. Reserve Bank’s
production weighted index places the monsoon
deficiency at 21 per cent. Sowing picked up
considerably in the latter half of July but significant
shortfall remains in case of coarse cereals, pulses
and some oilseeds, especially groundnut. These
sowing shortfalls could emerge as price pressure
points. As global food prices are already on the rise
on the back of drought in parts of US, Eurasia and
Australia, the option to bridge demand-supply gaps
through imports would have its limits. The large
carryovers and buffers in domestic stocks of food
would come in handy at this juncture, though efforts
are necessary to ensure that its movement and use
is efficient.
II.2.21 With likely increase in food inflation,
containing spillovers and generalisation of price
pressures is important in the current context.
Though core inflationary pressures remained muted
during Q1 of 2012-13, risks remain. Continued rise
in real wages and food price shocks may spill over
to core inflation. The decline in global metals and
energy prices during Q1 of 2012-13 provided some
relief, but these gains have been partly offset by
rupee depreciation and recent rebound in global
energy and food prices. In this backdrop, persistence
of inflation, even as growth is slowing, has emerged
as a major challenge for monetary policy.
II.3 MONEY AND CREDIT
II.3.1 Monetary and credit conditions in the
year 2011-12 were marked by two distinct broad
phases. During the first half of the year, monetary
policy was tightened. Liquidity conditions
generally remained in line with the policy objective
of maintaining moderate deficit of 1 per cent of
NDTL, under which monetary policy transmission
was seen to be more effective. More liquidity
was judged to be inimical to the monetary policy
goal of containing inflation, as it could spill over
to prices via excess demand. In the second half,
the Reserve Bank paused its tightening cycle.
Liquidity deficit, however, worsened due to some
unforeseen factors. First, the Reserve Bank
sold dollars to contain the volatility in the rupee
exchange rate. Second, the frictional mismatch
caused by the sudden build-up of government cash
balances persisted for a longer duration. Third, the
gap between growth in credit and deposit, which
was narrowing during the first three quarters of
the year, widened again during the fourth quarter
on account of a sharp deceleration in aggregate
deposit growth and a pick-up in credit growth.
II.3.2 Headline inflation averaged about 9.5
per cent over two calendar years – 2010 and
2011, after remaining low during most of 2009.
In response, the Reserve Bank persisted with its
anti-inflationary monetary policy stance during
February 2010-October 2011, gradually raising
the operational policy repo rate by 525 basis points
and the CRR by 100 basis points. The tightening
was necessary as inflation risks outweighed risks
to growth and would have adversely impacted
growth. As domestic demand slowed, partly due
to monetary policy actions, headline inflation
moderated. Taking into account the forwardlooking
assessment that growth was slowing more
than what was foreseen earlier, the Reserve Bank
signalled a monetary policy pause in Q3 of 2011-
12. It also infused liquidity by undertaking open
market operations through outright purchases.
Subsequently, the Reserve Bank eased policy
rates in April 2012 factoring in the moderation
in growth. In August 2012, the Reserve Bank reduced SLR by 1 percentage point with a view to
providing liquidity to facilitate credit availability to
productive sectors.
Expansion in net domestic assets (NDA) offset by
decline in net foreign assets (NFA); reserve money
growth remained low during 2011-12
II.3.3 The movements in reserve money
during 2011-12 reflected the offsetting liquidity
management operations of the Reserve Bank
in response to the autonomous liquidity drivers
(Chart II.22 and Appendix Table 9). During the
year, the autonomous drivers, viz., government
cash balance, the Reserve Bank’s forex
operations and currency with the public, resulted
in the drain of liquidity from the banking system.
Large scale open market operations through
outright purchases of G-sec of `1.3 trillion and
daily liquidity adjustment facility (LAF) operations
by the Reserve Bank resulted in the expansion
of net domestic assets (NDA). However, reserve
money growth decelerated during the year as NFA
declined due to the Reserve Bank’s interventions
in foreign exchange market. The deceleration
in reserve money was further accentuated by a
reduction in the cash reserve ratio (CRR) during
the fourth quarter that in the first round reduced
the deposits maintained with the Reserve Bank by around `795 billion. Even after adjusting
for the change in CRR, reserve money growth
decelerated during 2011-12.
|
II.3.4 Currency in circulation, which is the largest
component of reserve money, decelerated in 2011-
12 mainly on account of moderation in economic
activity and inflation. The cumulative rise in the
deposit rates progressively raised the opportunity
cost of holding idle cash, which caused a switch in
household savings from cash holdings.
II.3.5 Liquidity deficit in the first half of 2011-12
remained within the comfort zone of the Reserve
Bank on account of increased government
spending. The government persistently resorted
to Ways and Means Advances (WMA) along with
occasional over draft (OD). Accordingly, the need
for injection of durable discretionary liquidity did
not arise during the first half.
II.3.6 The deceleration in the growth of reserve
money (adjusted for CRR), particularly since
November 2011, reflected offsetting movements in
the autonomous and policy drivers of liquidity. The
Reserve Bank responded to the structural drivers
of liquidity – forex sales and increased demand
for currency as compared to previous quarters
– by the injection of durable liquidity in the form
of OMO purchases and CRR cuts. The frictional
dimension of autonomous liquidity – a build-up
of government balance – was addressed by the
provision of overnight liquidity under LAF/MSF.
Following the seasonal easing of government
balances, the narrowing of the wedge between
the pace of growth of deposit and credit, and the
Reserve Bank’s active management of liquidity
through LAF and OMO, liquidity deficit under
LAF declined during 2012-13 so far. Chapter III
provides a detailed discussion on the Reserve
Bank’s liquidity management operations.
Behavioural and policy factors result in higher
money multiplier
II.3.7 The deceleration in reserve money in
2011-12 was led by a moderation in the demand
for currency. The value of the money multiplier
depends on two behavioural ratios – currency deposit ratio and reserves-deposit ratio. During
the first three quarters of 2011-12, the response
of banks and households to the hardening of
monetary conditions led to the rise in the value
of the money multiplier (Chart II.23). During 2011-
12, the money multiplier peaked on the fortnight
ended February 24, 2012, following the 50 basis
points cut in the CRR in January 2012, which
reduced the amount of required reserves to be
maintained. Following a second round of decline
in the CRR by 75 bps from the fortnight beginning
March 10, 2012, the money multiplier rose further
in recent period.
|
II.3.8 The rise in the money multiplier, however,
could not offset the sharp deceleration in the
reserve money, and money supply growth
decelerated to 13.1 per cent at end-March 2012
from 16.1 per cent a year ago (Chart II.24). Even
though the money supply growth marginally
recovered subsequently at 13.5 per cent as on
July 27, 2012 it still remains below the Reserve
Bank’s indicative trajectory of 15 per cent.
Broad money growth remains strong, but softens
in Q4 as deposit growth decelerates
II.3.9 Consistency among money, growth and
prices depends on the stability of the demand function for money. Empirically, the demand for
money in India is found to be stable over the
medium to longer term (Box II.9).
|
II.3.10 Broad money (M3) growth, which was above
the 15.5 per cent year-end trajectory by the third
quarter of 2011-12, declined sharply from mid-
January 2012, partly due to insufficient liquidity
creation to offset frictional and structural liquidity
deficits and partly due to slowing growth and
inflation. All components of broad money exhibited
a deceleration during 2011-12 (Appendix Table
10). Time deposits recorded strong growth during
the first three quarters mainly on account of the
rising opportunity cost of holding cash or demand
deposits as the interest rates on time deposits
responded to the anti-inflationary monetary policy
stance of the Reserve Bank. The substitution from other components of household financial savings,
such as small savings and mutual funds was also
mirrored in the strong growth in time deposits.
During the fourth quarter of 2011-12, however,
tight liquidity conditions slowed down time deposit
growth, which was further aggravated by the
base effect. Banks supplemented deposits with
alternate sources such as borrowings by way of
debt instruments and LAF.
Box II.9
Demand for Money
The importance of money as an information variable for
the conduct of monetary policy hinges on the stability of its
demand with respect to its determinants. Even though India
abandoned what was known as ‘monetary targeting with
feedback’ in 1998, where broad money (M3) served as the
intermediate target of monetary policy, monetary aggregates
in general and M3 in particular continue to play an important
role in the formulation of monetary policy.
Consistent with its projections on growth and inflation,
the Reserve Bank gives its projection for M3 growth for
the financial year at the beginning of each financial year.
Subsequent changes, if any, in the outturn of the evolving
growth-inflation dynamics results in a change in the
monetary projection. This presumes a stable demand for
money. Any deviation between the initial projection and
the final outturn of M3 depends not only on the accuracy
of the projection of growth and inflation – the proximate
determinant of money demand – but also on the stability of
the money demand function. Further, there are evidences
of bi-directional causal relation between money, prices and
income as was recognised in the ‘monetary targeting with
feedback’ approach.
What has now prompted a revisit of the stability of the money
demand function is whether the deceleration in money
growth during recent years is in line with the deceleration
in nominal GDP growth (Chart 1). Does it imply financial
disintermediation induced instability in the demand for
money that has prompted many formerly monetary targeting
countries to abandon it? Or is it a consequence of the
decelerating financial saving of households as households rebalance their portfolios in favour of assets that are
illiquid but yield a higher rate of return? These issues have
necessitated a re-examination of the demand for money in
India.
|
Theoretically, the demand for money depends primarily on
income and the opportunity cost of holding money. As real
income grows, the demand for money increases to finance a
higher volume of transactions. Further, the higher real rate of
return on alternative assets increases the opportunity cost
of holding money, thereby reducing the ‘speculative’ demand
for money.
Also, financial innovations that involve the introduction of
new financial instruments influence the demand for money. In addition, with full convertibility on the current account in
1994, the measures taken to liberalise the capital account,
exchange rate and foreign rate of interest are expected to
have a bearing on the demand for money.
The mainstream literature in the Indian context define the
demand for broad money (M3) as a function of either real
income and price level (e.g., Mohanty and Mitra (1999),
Ramachandran (2004)) or real income and a short term
nominal interest rate (e.g., Rao and Singh (2006)). The
empirical literature has debated considerably on the stability
of money demand and found mixed evidences depending on
the model specification and time period under consideration.
An empirical investigation of demand for money for the
period 1970-71 to 2011-12 reveals that there is a long run
cointegration relationship between money balances, real
income and the price level. Money demand is defined as the
average M3 for the year, real income is measured in terms of
GDP at constant market prices. The price level is captured
using the WPI. All these variables are in natural log forms.
Accordingly, the estimate for long-run money demand is as
under:
M3 = 9.62 + 1.30 GDP + 0.98 WPI……………(1)
(0.33405) (0.24515)
where the figures in parentheses indicate standard error of
the estimates.
The coefficients are significant at 5 per cent level. The
income elasticity of money demand is estimated to be 1.3,
while a one percentage increase in price level translates into
a nearly proportionate increase in the long run demand for
money. Standard tests indicate robustness of these results.
Other explanatory variables, for instance, proxies for financial
innovations, alternative sources of funding etc. didn’t exhibit
significant long term relation in the above specification.
On the whole, the empirical analysis indicates that the
demand for money (equation 1 above) in India remained
generally stable over the period under consideration.
References
Mohanty, D., and A. K. Mitra (1999), ‘Experience with
Monetary Targeting in India’, Economic and Political Weekly,
34: 16–23.
Ramachandran, M (2004), ‘Do Broad Money, Output, and
Prices Stand for a Stable Relationship in India?’ Journal of
Policy Modeling 26: 983–1001.
Rao, B. B. and Rup Singh (2006), ‘Demand for money in
India: 1953-2003,’ Applied Economics, 38(11), 1319-1326.
II.3.11 On the sources side, the deceleration in M3 was led by commercial credit growth. Besides, the
Reserve Bank’s foreign exchange operations also
caused a drag on M3 growth. The banking system
credit to the government, however, increased
significantly. For commercial banks, this reflected
their participation in the large market borrowing
programme.
Credit decelerates as growth slows
II.3.12 The Reserve Bank lowered its projection
for the growth of non-food credit from 19 per
cent in May 2011 to 18 per cent in July 2011 and
finally to 16 per cent in January 2012. This was done in recognition of the gradual deceleration in
credit growth below the Reserve Bank’s trajectory
even as M3 growth was above the Reserve Bank’s
indicative trajectory (Chart II.25). The deceleration
in credit reflected the combined effect of weakening growth and increasing risk aversion by banks. As
a result the SCBs’ investments in government
securities increased sharply. However, there is
significant evidence suggesting that in India,
the interest rate channels and credit channels
have been working effectively in recent years
(Box II.10).
Box II.10
Interest Rate and Credit Channels of Monetary Transmission
Monetary transmission explains the mechanisms by which
monetary policy changes achieve the ultimate objectives of
impacting inflation and growth. The interest rate and credit
channels have been particularly important in the Indian case.
The interest rate channel explains how changes in money
supply affect investment, aggregate demand, inflation and
output through changes in interest rates. A contractionary
monetary policy raises the real lending rate, thus raising the
cost of capital. This causes investment spending, and
therefore, aggregate demand to slow down and lead to growth
deceleration and the lowering of inflation.
The credit channel of monetary transmission occurs through
two broad channels – the balance sheet channel and the
bank lending channel. The balance sheet channel works by
affecting the external finance premium, i.e., the difference
between the costs of funds raised externally (equity and debt)
and internally (retained earnings). As imperfections and
information asymmetry prevails in the credit market, external
finance premium tends to rise when central banks raise shortterm
interest rates. This affects net cash flows and the impact
depends on financial ratios such as the net worth or the
coverage ratio of a firm. Cyclical movements in borrower’s
balance sheets can amplify and propagate business cycles
through “financial accelerators” (Bernanke, Gertler and
Gilchrist, 1996).
The bank lending channel works by monetary policy impacting
the supply of bank loans. As external finance premium rises,
bank finance decreases in the sources of funds. This is
because sources of finance are imperfect substitutes for one
another. Banks, which play an important role in reducing
informational problems, tend to lose their retail deposit base as the central bank contracts base money. Since banks cannot
fully substitute these through other sources such as CDs or
by raising capital, they are forced to contract bank loans.
There is significant new evidence of these channels operating
in India. Mohanty (2012) using a quarterly structural vector
autoregression model showed that policy rate increases in
India in recent years had a negative effect on output growth
with a lag of two quarters and a moderating effect on inflation
with a lag of three quarter. The overall impact persists for 8-10
quarters. Khundrakpam (2011) found that policy induced
expansion or contraction in money supply makes banks adjust
their credit portfolio. For the period after the introduction of
LAF, a 100 bps increase in policy rate was found to reduce
credit by 2.8 per cent in nominal terms and 2.2 per cent in
real terms. Monetary policy in India under the framework of
multiple indicator approach takes into account both interest
rate movements and developments in the credit market for
policy decision. The speed of transmission in India is often
impacted by banks’ having a large share of term deposits.
With such deposits locked, banks cost of funds do not change
fast enough for them to change their lending rates.
References
Bernanke, B., Mark Gertler and Simon Gilchrist (1996), “The
Financial Accelerator and the Flight to Quality”, Review of
Economics and Statistics, 78(1): 1-15.
Khundrakpam, J. K. (2011), “Credit Channel of Monetary
Transmission in India: How Effective and Long are the Lags”,
RBI Working Paper No.20/2011 November.
Mohanty, Deepak (2012), “Evidence of Interest Rate Channel
of Monetary Policy Transmission in India”, RBI Working Paper
No.6/2012, May.
II.3.13 The deceleration in credit coupled
with the upswing in deposit growth caused the
divergence between credit and deposit growth to
narrow during the first three quarters of 2011-12
(Chart II.26). The divergence even turned negative
in December 2011. The divergence increased
following the sharper deceleration of deposit
growth during Q4 of 2011-12 and the turnaround
in credit during March 2012. This trend of low
deposit growth and pick-up in credit continued in Q1 of 2012-13, thus maintaining the high wedge
between credit and deposit. As deposit growth
moderated, commercial banks increased their
recourse to non-deposit sources, viz., borrowings,
including through the LAF window. The reduction
in CRR in Q4 of 2011-12 also augmented the
lonable resources of banks. Reflecting these
trends, the outstanding credit-deposit ratio rose
from 74.5 per cent at end-March 2011 to 76.7 per
cent at end-March 2012. The incremental creditdeposit
ratio continued to remain at a high level
of 95.5 per cent during 2011-12 (97.5 per cent
during the previous year) as banks accessed LAF
borrowings for extending credit. In Q1 of 2012-13,
however both outstanding as well as incremental
credit deposit ratio declined.
|
Rising non-performing assets (NPAs) adversely
affect credit growth
II.3.14 Against the backdrop of growth
deceleration, the banks exhibited risk aversion in
extending credit. Credit growth decelerated across
bank groups during 2011-12 ranging between
16.3 per cent in the case of public sector banks
(PSBs) and 19.7 per cent for private sector banks.
The comparable figures for the previous year were
21.0 per cent and 24.7 per cent, respectively.
Since PSBs account for about 74 per cent of the
outstanding credit extended by commercial banks,
the credit growth of commercial banks decelerated
to 17.0 per cent from 21.5 per cent in the previous
year. In part, credit deceleration reflects banks’
risk aversion in face of rising NPAs and increased
leverage of corporate balance sheets.
II.3.15 The deceleration in non-food credit during
2011-12 was accounted for by all sectors, barring
agriculture (Appendix Table 11). The deceleration
was particularly sharp for the services sector and
personal loans and was modest for the priority
sector and industry. Within industry, however,
medium scale industries witnessed a sharp
decline in the flow of credit. During 2012-13 so
far, non-food credit growth at 16.9 per cent in mid-
August 2012, is in line with the indicative trajectory
of the Reserve Bank.
II.3.16 In the year 2012-13 so far, there has been
a significant easing of liquidity and monetary conditions reflecting lagged impact of 125 bps cut
in CRR in Q4 of 2011-12, 50 bps cut in policy rate
and liquidity infusion of over `800 billion through
outright OMOs and `100 billion through export
credit refinance, the limit for which was raised
from 15 per cent to 50 per cent of the outstanding
export credit. With continued liquidity infusion,
there has been a gradual pick-up in monetary
and credit aggregates. The 1 percentage point
SLR reduction effective August 2012, is expected
to further ease liquidity and encourage banks to
increase loans and advances.
II.4 FINANCIAL MARKETS
Euro area debt crisis keeps markets volatile
II.4.1 Uncertainties emanating from the ongoing
euro area sovereign debt crisis, the downgrade in
the outlook of several advanced economies (AEs),
and stability issues of euro area banks amid bank
recapitalisation concerns, among other factors, kept
the international financial markets volatile for most
of 2011-12. Cross-holding of sovereign debt,
especially by euro area banks, also translated the
sovereign debt crisis into banking sector stresses.
High debt levels and stretched fiscal space made it
difficult for euro area sovereigns to re-capitalise the
banks with public money. Concerns over economic
growth also came to the fore with many AEs,
particularly in the euro area, experiencing low or
negative rates of growth. Although some AEs took
policy measures to infuse more liquidity, the private
demand has remained low reflecting inter alia
deleveraging by households and tight bank lending.
II.4.2 Higher market volatility was witnessed
after the downgrade of the long term US sovereign
debt in August 2011. Equity markets witnessed a
sell-off, with investor preference shifting towards
perceived safe haven assets. The Federal
Reserve embarked on an “operation twist” to
support the US economy in the face of slow
growth and high unemployment. Developments in
the euro area warranted swift action by policy
makers to avoid a downward spiral in the financial
markets. The European Central Bank (ECB) responded by undertaking two Long Term
Refinancing Operations (LTRO) that pumped in
over €1 trillion. The European Financial Stability
Facility (EFSF) also increased its resources to
€780 billion. Against imminent default possibility, a bond swap was effected with large haircuts to
enable Greece to meet its obligation. The various
policy measures in the euro area in response to
the crisis had implications for global financial
markets (Box II.11).
Box II.11
Euro Area Crisis – An Assessment of Policy Action
The euro area is caught in a deep, structural and multifaceted
crisis characterised by large fiscal deficit, enormous public
debt, banking problems and consistently eroding competitive
position manifested in a gradually deteriorating current
account balance. Beginning with the peripheral euro area in
2009, the sovereign debt crisis has of late cascaded to engulf
core euro area economies, like France and Austria, which
were downgraded from their AAA rating status in January
2012. It has also brought Greece closer to a possible exit from
the euro and resulted in a spillover to a banking crisis in Spain
and Portugal. As countries in a currency union, the affected
economies are faced with a policy dilemma since they do not
have the liberty of using exchange rate and monetary policy
as stabilisation measures.
I. Policy Measures
The policy measures taken to alleviate the crisis were mainly
fourfold: (i) regional financial arrangements and euro-IMF joint
provision of resources, (ii) exceptional liquidity facility provided
by ECB, (iii) measures to recapitalise and strengthen
prudential norms in the European banking system and (iv)
structural measures to correct a distorted fiscal system.
Financial arrangements in the region were effected through
the establishment of new institutions, such as the European
Financial Stabilisation Mechanism (EFSM) in May 2010, the
European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) in August 2010
and the European Stabilisation Mechanism (ESM) that is
being operationalised but has not found favour for a banking
license as yet. While EFSM involves funds raised by the
European Commission backed by EU budget, institutions
such as EFSF were authorised to mobilise resources by
issuing bonds and other debt instruments in the market
backed by guarantees of 17 euro area member states. These
institutions, in alliance with the IMF, financed rescue packages
for Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Italy.
The ECB arranged to stabilise the sovereign debt markets
through security market programmes that involved sterilised
purchases of both public and private debt of the affected
countries. In December 2011, the ECB committed to supply
banks in the euro area with euro-denominated funding for
three years in two special long-term refinancing operations
(LTROs) that would enable banks to meet their potential
funding needs from maturing bonds over the next few years.
Since the large sovereign debt holdings of European banks
raised the probability of a spillover of the crisis to the financial sector, efforts were made to inspire confidence in the banking
system. Popular measures included encouraging stress tests
for the banks and their transparent dissemination and the
recapitalisation of 65 major banks by raising their core tier I
capital to risk-weighted assets ratio to 9.0 per cent by end-
June 2012.
In terms of medium-term policy measures, European leaders
often reiterated their commitment to implementing fiscal
austerity measures. At the Brussels Summit in December
2011, EU members agreed that general government budgets
should either be balanced or in surplus. Besides, institutions
outside the euro area have extended their support through
measures such as central banks’ provision of contingent swap
lines in 2010 and again in late 2011, and also announced
easy and unconventional monetary policy measures.
Besides, various structural measures are currently being
undertaken including the recent (June 2012) European
Council decision on “Compact for Growth and Jobs” which
aims to mobilise 120 billion euros for immediate investment
by unlocking domestic potential for growth, including through
opening up competition in network industries, promoting the
digital economy, exploiting the potential of a green economy,
removing unjustified restrictions on service providers and
making it easier to start a business.
There is also a line of thought that though not very likely, exit
of troubled nations like Greece from the union may allow more
policy flexibility to the affected countries in the medium-term.
Assessment
The policy measures taken by the euro area, viz., bailing out
affected economies and liquidity provision have not proved
to be effective in debt crisis resolution. Concerns over fiscal
sustainability and solvency of these economies still remain.
For example, in June 2012, Spain’s economic condition
worsened necessitating bail-out packages for its banks. These
appear to be aimed at staving off the crisis rather than
addressing its structural issues.
Since the economies in a currency union do not have the
option to adjust the exchange rate, the necessary adjustment
has to come through fiscal consolidation. However, the
ongoing fiscal austerity measures are likely to impact nearterm
recovery. The clear inter-temporal choice between fiscal
consolidation and near-term growth then necessitates
concrete collective effort to establish a fiscal union. Besides, efforts should be made to encourage domestic savings and
develop indigenous government bond markets to reduce the
reliance on foreign capital to finance public debt.
Second, regional arrangements have limited firepower, and
may require multilateral financial assistance to supplement
resources. But this would have direct implications for IMF
resource mobilisation, and since the ratification of the 2010
quota reforms is a protracted process, the IMF may have to
rely on borrowed resources that may deviate from the
equilibrium ratio between quota and borrowed resources, with
potential governance implications. This not only pre-empts
resources from low-income countries that have become more
vulnerable to global economic uncertainties but also puts
pressure on crisis by-standers that may be facing an uncertain
macroeconomic situation.
Third, increased liquidity provision in the region may add to
global liquidity, which, in turn, may feed into global inflation
and raise monetary policy challenges for EDEs. If increased
global liquidity is channelled into commodity markets, rising
commodity prices, particularly oil, will stretch current account
deficits in oil importing economies like India. Tightening the
prudential norms in the European banking systems may lead
to deleveraging, which may increase exchange rate volatility
in EDEs.
Against this backdrop, there has been a debate about whether
the crisis response in the euro area has been appropriate.
One argument is that the “troika” of the EU, the ECB and the
IMF has delayed in responding to the crisis. Douglas J. Elliott,
Fellow at Brookings Institution in his testimony argued that
the euro crisis could plunge Europe into a deep recession
and put the U.S. into at least a mild recession. There are those
who argue that the economics of austerity may fail in the euro
area. Others argue that the currency union is inherently
unsustainable and taxpayer money is being drained through
unworkable bailouts. The problem is whether others in the
periphery can be ring-fenced and how to thwart a likely strong
contagion. Broin (2012) warns that if loss-sharing cannot be agreed on, a messy default is likely to end in a forced exit
with far-reaching implications for the rest of the world.
Brutti and Saure (2011) find that exposure to Greek sovereign
debt and the debt of Greek banks constitute an important
transmission channel in the case of the euro area and, overall,
financial linkages explain up to two-third of the transmission
of sovereign debt in the euro crisis. Further, if Greece leaves
the Union, the apprehension about probable exit of other
countries from the euro area is likely to increase considerably
as their situation is equally fragile. Portugal and Ireland may
have to restructure their public debt regardless of whether
Greece defaults. Illiquid but solvent countries like Italy and
Spain will have to be rescued through lender of last resort
support to avoid default. It would have a cascading impact on
German and French bank balance sheets as they hold
majority of the Greek loans. Subbarao (2012) has pointed to
the trilemma being faced by the central banks, including the
ECB, in managing price stability, financial stability and
sovereign debt sustainability at the same time. This new
trilemma has emerged after the global crisis.
Reference
Broin, Peader O. (2012), “The Euro Crisis: Orderly Default or
Euro Exit”, The Institute of International and European Affairs,
Report No.8.
Brutti, Filippo and Phillip Saure (2011), “Transmission of
Sovereign Risk in a Euro Crisis”, December, Swiss National
Bank Study Centre, Gerzensee Working Paper No.12.01.
Subbarao, Duvvuri (forthcoming), “Price Stability, Financial
Stability, and Sovereign Debt Sustainability Policy Challenges
from the New Trilemma”, Macroeconomics and Finance in
Emerging Market Economies.
US Congress (2011), “What the euro crisis means for
Taxpayers and US economy”, Testimony of Douglas Elliott
before House sub-committee on Troubled Asset Reconstruction
Programme (TARP), Financial Services and Bailouts of Public
and Private Programs, December 15, 2011
II.4.3 In early 2012, global financial markets,
particularly equity markets, witnessed a firm trend
due to liquidity emanating from the LTRO and other
policy actions by AEs. However, concerns over the
euro area sovereign debt crisis have resurfaced in
anticipation that a change of leadership in Greece
and France may be inclined to re-negotiate the
austerity-based bailout plan, leading to stress in
financial markets (Chart II.27). During June –mid
August 2012, despite various measures taken by
the European Council to break the vicious circle
between banks and sovereigns, the bond yield of
Spain continued to be at elevated level. Further, recent developments like the LIBOR manipulation
has also added to the uncertainty by demonstrating
the fragilities in the banking and financial sector.
The discussion paper from the Financial Conduct
Authority of the UK government “The Wheatley
Review of LIBOR” released in August 2012, inter
alia lays out the necessary reforms for tighter
governance of LIBOR, soliciting feedback from
concerned parties.
II.4.4 The Indian financial markets (especially the
equity and currency markets) witnessed significant
spillover from the global turmoil in addition to the
domestic growth and inflation concerns, anti inflationary monetary policy and governance issues.
The financial markets quickly reflected the shocks
emanating from the global and domestic economy. A financial conditions index developed in-house
highlights the information content in the financial
variables (Box II.12).
Box II.12
Financial Conditions Index
There is a large body of literature on extracting signals about
the real economy from financial variables. Economists and
analysts have often used different financial prices as lead
indicators of the future course of the economy. Interest rates
and interest rate spreads are considered to be useful in
predicting the course of the economy (Bernanke, 1990). The
shape of the yield curve, i.e. the term structure of interest
rates, contains information about the expectations of market
participants about the state of the economy in the future. The
yield curve contains considerable information on the future
path of inflation for horizons of more than one year.
Similarly, the spread between three -month commercial paper
(CP) and three -month Treasury bill (T-bill) depicts the credit
default risk associated with corporates (if liquidity spread can
be ignored). Stock and Watson (1989) have found that the
spread between CP and T-bill rates, 10-year and 1-year
government bond, housing starts, manufacturer’s unfulfilled
orders in durable goods industries and growth of part -time
work are good predictors of business cycles.
Studying the movements in different financial assets in
isolation, however, may be of limited use as each price
contains information only about a certain aspect of the
economy and does not necessarily reveal much about other
aspects. This problem can be overcome by constructing an
index using the relevant financial variables. This kind of index
is usually called a Financial Conditions Index (FCI) and it
summarises information about the future state of the economy
contained in current financial variables (Hatzius et al., 2010).
In essence, the FCI analyses the synthesis of various,
sometimes contradictory, signals from financial markets.
Indices such as the Bank of Canada’s Monetary Conditions
Index, Macroeconomic Advisers Monetary and Financial Conditions Index (MFCI), Bloomberg Financial Conditions
Index (BBFCI), Goldman Sachs Financial Conditions Index
(GSFCI), Federal Reserve of Kansas City Financial Stress
Index (KCFSI), OECD FCI, and Monetary Conditions Index
for India (Kannan et al 2006) have been constructed at various
times. Drawing from the literature, a FCI for India has been
constructed in a principal components analysis framework
using monthly data between January 2004 and March 2012.
While indices have been computed for money market, bond
market, forex market and stock market, an aggregate financial
conditions index that covers all segments is also computed
(Table 1).
Table 1: Components of the Financial Conditions Index |
Call Spread (Call Rate - Effective Policy Rate)
CBLO Spread (Effective Policy Rate - CBLO Rate)
Market Repo Spread
(Effective Policy Rate - Market Repo Rate)
Short Spread (3m CP - 3m T-Bill) |
Money
Market
FCI |
Aggregate FCI |
10 yr G-Sec Yield
Long Spread (10 yr AAA Corp Bond - 10 yr G-Sec )
Medium Spread (5 yr AAA Corp Bond - 5 yr G-Sec ) |
Bond
Market
FCI |
Exchange Rate
3-month Implied
Volatility Forex CMAX |
Forex
Market
FCI |
S&P CNXNifty Annual Returns
PE Ratio of S&P CNX Nifty
S&P CNX Nifty Market capitalisation to GDP Ratio |
Stock
Market
FCI |
The index has been constructed so that high values depict
accommodative financial conditions, whereas low values
depict tight financial conditions. It may be seen from Chart 1 that the financial conditions index captures the stressed
financial conditions in the wake of the global financial crisis.
Evidently, the index shows highly stressed financial conditions
in October 2008, just after the collapse of Lehman Brothers.
The usefulness of the FCI should be appreciated in the context
of its ability to forecast or explain economic variables like GDP, IIP and inflation. The correlation of FCI with growth rates of
GDP and IIP are 0.43 and 0.60, respectively, which are
statistically significant. The recovery in financial conditions
has broadly been in line with recovery in the IIP and GDP
growth rates (Chart 2). However, more research is called for
to establish the link between the aggregate financial conditions
index and economic variables.
Reference
Bernanke, Ben S. (1990), “On the Predictive Power of Interest
Rates and Interest Rate Spreads.” New England Economic
Review, November/December, pp. 51-68.
Hatzius, J, P.Hooper, F.Mishkin, K. Schoenholtz and M. Watson
(2010), “Financial Conditions Index: A Fresh Look after the
Financial Crisis”, National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper No -16150, Cambridge, July.
Kannan, R, Siddhartha Sanyal and Binod Bihari Bhoi (2006),
“Monetary Conditions Index for India”, Reserve Bank of India
Occasional Papers Vol. 27, No. 3, Winter
Stock, J. and M. Watson (1989), “New Indexes of Coincident
and Leading Economic Indicators,” in O. Blanchard and S.
Fischer (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual (Cambridge,
MA: MIT), 352-94.
Monetary transmission strong in deficit liquidity
conditions for most of the year
II.4.5 The monetary policy stance of the Reserve
Bank saw a gradual shift from the primary focus of
containing inflation and anchoring inflation
expectations (during May-October 2011) to more
growth enabling, with due cognisance of the
inflationary pressures. In line with the policy stance,
2011-12 saw liquidity conditions remaining in a
deficit mode, with the later part of the year beginning
November 2011 experiencing liquidity deficit
beyond the stated comfort level of (+/–) one per cent of net demand and time liabilities (NDTL) of
banks (Chart II.28a).
Money market rates rose, reflecting monetary policy
and structural liquidity deficit
II.4.6 The call money rate generally hovered
around the repo rate during H1 of 2011-12, when
the liquidity deficit was contained mostly within the
comfort zone of the Reserve Bank. However, tighter
liquidity conditions in H2 kept the call rate mostly
above the repo rate (although below the MSF rate).
As an aberration of the trend, the year-end scramble
for funds by banks to shore up their balance-sheets (and front-loading of reserve) caused the call
money rate to move sharply above the MSF rate
on March 30, 2012. The rates in the collateralised
segments of the money market moved in tandem
with the call rate, but generally remained below it
during the year (Chart II.28b). The money market
rates have declined in 2012-13 so far, with the
easing of liquidity conditions, and reduction in the
policy rate announced in the Monetary Policy 2012-
13 Statement (April 17, 2012).
|
II.4.7 The speed of transmission of monetary
policy measures to the financial markets determines
the efficacy of the policy action. As noted by the
working group on Operating Procedure of Monetary
Policy (Chairman: Shri Deepak Mohanty), the
speed of monetary policy transmission across
financial markets was faster in a liquidity deficit
situation than otherwise. In-house empirical
analysis on the inter-linkages between financial
markets and monetary policy transmission reaffirm
the finding. Asymmetry in monetary policy
transmission to financial markets in India is
observed during 2005-11, with the transmission
being faster and more persistent when the liquidity
is in deficit mode than otherwise.
Higher bank deposit and lending rates also reflect
improved monetary policy transmission
II.4.8 During 2011-12, scheduled commercial
banks (SCBs) increased their modal deposit rate
by 82 basis points (bps) and modal base rate by 125 bps. The weighted average lending rates of five
major public sector banks increased from 10.98 per
cent in March 2011 to 12.80 per cent by September
2011 and remained around that level in April 2012
before declining to 12.58 per cent in June 2012,
suggesting that bank lending rates were broadly
following the policy rate signal.
Volumes in collateralised money market declined
II.4.9 Transaction volumes in the collateralised
borrowing and lending obligation (CBLO) and market
repo segments declined in 2011-12 compared to the
previous year (Chart II.29). Banks and primary
dealers were the major groups of borrowers in the
collateralised segments, whereas mutual funds
(MFs) and banks remained the major groups of
lenders in these segments.
II.4.10 The average fortnightly issuance of
certificates of deposit (CD) and commercial paper
(CP) increased during 2011-12. ‘Leasing and
Finance’ and ‘Manufacturing’ companies remained
the major issuers of CPs. The effective interest rate
for aggregate CD issuances increased to 11.13 per
cent at end-March 2012 compared with 9.96 per
cent at end-March 2011. The CD rates spiked
during March 2012 reflecting overall tight liquidity
conditions in the money markets and the reluctance
of MFs to rollover bank CDs after asset management
companies were made accountable for fair
valuations on a mark-to-market basis. The weighted
average discount rate (WADR) on CP also increased to 12.2 per cent as at end-March 2012
from 10.4 per cent as at end-March 2011. While
the average fortnightly issuance of CPs has
increased during 2012-13 so far (till mid-July 2012),
it has decreased for CDs. The WAEIR of aggregate
CDs and WADR of aggregate CPs declined to 9.1
and 9.3 per cent, respectively, in mid-July 2012.
|
G-sec yields remained range bound despite large
government market borrowing
II.4.11 The G-sec yields generally hardened during
the early part of H1 of 2011-12 on account of rise
in price of commodities, including crude oil,
concerns about inflation and government’s fiscal
deficit. The rise in yields also reflected transmission
of the hikes in policy rates by 50 basis points in May
2011. In the later part of H1, the G-sec yields
remained range bound amidst tight liquidity
conditions, persistent inflation concerns, hike in
policy rates by cumulative 100 bps in three stages
and growth concerns as reflected from weak IIP data and rush for safe haven assets after S&P
downgraded the credit rating of the US (Chart
II.29d).
II.4.12 During the initial part of H2 of 2011-12, the
yields continued to rise after the Reserve Bank
hiked the policy rate by 25 bps. The yields, however,
eased from mid-November 2011 on the back of
enhancement in FII investment limits in G-sec,
easing of food inflation and the pause in rate hikes
as announced in the Mid-Quarter Monetary Policy
Review (December 2011). OMO purchases by
Reserve Bank also helped in easing of G-Sec yields
(Box II.13). However, prevailing tight liquidity
conditions and concerns about increased
government’s borrowing program for 2012-13 as
announced in the Union Budget caused yields to
harden towards end of Q4 of 2011-12.
II.4.13 G-sec yields softened during April 2012 in
response to cut in policy rates, easing of inflation
and slowdown in industrial activity and exports. The yields, however, rose sharply after S&P downgraded
India’s long-term rating outlook to negative towards
end-April 2012. During 2012-13 (up to August 13),
the Reserve Bank injected durable liquidity to the
extent of `591 billion through OMO purchases in
auctions and another around `222 billion through
purchase of securities on the anonymous trading
platform. The G-sec yields hardened after the
Reserve Bank reduced the SLR by one per cent
from 24 per cent to 23 per cent in the First Quarter
Review of Monetary Policy 2012-13 (July 31, 2012).
Box II.13
Impact of OMO on G-sec Market Trading Activity
A combination of factors (both frictional and structural) led
to a net tight liquidity position in the later part of 2011-12.
As a measure to address the tight liquidity prevailing in the
system since Q3 of 2011-12, the Reserve Bank conducted
OMOs through both the auction and NDS-OM routes. Since
the commencement of OMOs in November 2011, the
Reserve Bank injected net durable liquidity of `1.35 trillion
into the system during 2011-12 (Chart 1). OMOs and CRR
cuts together helped ease the liquidity stress to a large
extent.
The objective of OMO purchases is liquidity management.
The Reserve Bank’s OMO purchases, however, adds to the
existing demand for G-secs, drives down yields and boosts
trading volumes, thereby imparting liquidity to the G-sec
market (Chart 2). The impact on yields, if any, is the result of the G-sec market demand -supply dynamics and may not
be construed as a signal for monetary policy purposes.
|
Since liquidity injection of durable nature is the goal in
conducting OMO auctions, the Reserve Bank has to identify
an optimal mix of liquid and semi-liquid/illiquid securities.
While the rationale for including semi-liquid/illiquid securities
is to enhance their secondary market liquidity, the liquid
securities are chosen to make the OMO successful. The
liquid securities are often those with the least price risk and
thus have a higher probability of success in the auctions.
The downside to this arrangement is that it may reduce the
availability of tradable stock of liquid securities and, if the
supply is not commensurate with the purchases through
OMOs, it may adversely impact the secondary market
liquidity.
|
II.4.14 The daily average volume in the G-sec
market, which stood at `105 billion during 2010-11,
rose to around `130 billion in the year 2011-12.
The daily average volume stood at `183 billion in
Q1 of 2012-13. The volume generally varied
inversely with the movement of the 10-year yield.
Equity market indices reflected FII flows and
macroeconomic developments
II.4.15 In line with global markets, Indian equity
prices continued their declining trend during most
of 2011-12. After remaining weak for three quarters,
the Indian equity market witnessed strong recovery
in Q4 on the back of renewed FII support,
moderation in inflation and firm trends in the global
equity market. Overall, the Indian equity markets
remained weak, owing to global developments,
weak macroeconomic indicators and depreciation
of rupee (Appendix Table No. 12). Two key Indian
equity indices – the BSE Sensex and the S&P CNX
Nifty - declined by 10.5 per cent and 9.2 per cent,
respectively, during 2011-12 (Chart II.30).
II.4.16 During 2012-13, the Indian equity market
started on a subdued note on FII outflows, concerns over the low domestic growth, weak revenue
outlook for major Indian IT companies and renewed
euro area uncertainties. Investment sentiment was
compounded by the downgrade of India’s long term
rating outlook to negative from stable, worries over
retrospective tax and general anti-avoidance rules
(GAAR) and the rupee slide. However, in the later
part of June 2012, following a pick-up in FII
investment in the equity market, clarifications by
the government on retrospective tax, GAAR and
the government decision to boost investments in
infrastructure, the market witnessed a turnaround.
Growth enabling policy actions by AEs and also the
European Council’s decision to support euro area
sovereigns and banks also aided the market
sentiments.
|
II.4.17 Nevertheless, during Q1 of 2012-13 both
the BSE Sensex and the S&P CNX Nifty declined
by 7.5 per cent and 6.5 per cent, respectively on
y-o-y basis with FIIs and MFs having sold shares
worth `6.6 billion and `6.4 billion, respectively in Q1 of 2012-13. However, in the Q2 of 2012-13 so
far (up to August 13, 2012), FIIs bought shares
worth `136.0 billion, while MFs sold shares worth
`28.9 billion. In tandem the BSE Sensex and the
S&P CNX Nifty recovered by 4.7 per cent and 5.4
per cent, respectively.
II.4.18 The turnover in the Indian equity derivatives
segment increased substantially over the year. Out
of total derivatives turnover, the index options
segment remained the highest contributor to the
total derivative turnover (Chart II.30d, Appendix
Table No. 13).
Dormant primary markets largely reflect subdued
sentiments
II.4.19 Resource mobilisation in the primary
segment of the domestic capital market was
significantly lower (65.8 per cent) during 2011-12
over the previous year. Dampened secondary
market conditions, and the poor performance of
IPOs after their listing affected investor and promoter sentiment. Firms abstained from
mobilising resources through public issues during
October–January 2012 when investor risk appetite
was low. There were no public issues in the primary
market. However, during February–June 2012 the
primary market witnessed a few issuances,
indicating slow recovery. Overall, primary market
sentiment remained subdued during the year so
far.
II.4.20 In any new project, equity capital is an
essential component of total capital. In sluggish
IPO market, it is very difficult to mobilise equity
capital from public. Further, in the absence of
equity capital, raising debt would be difficult for the
firms which are already leveraged significantly.
Hence, the sluggishness of IPO market could have
contributed to the overall investment slowdown.
II.4.21 During 2011-12, on the external front,
resources mobilised through Euro issues were also
sharply lower due to uncertain liquidity conditions
in the European banking system on the back of the
persistent euro area debt crisis.
Exchange rate remained volatile, reflecting
domestic and global concerns
II.4.22 The currency market was under pressure
during August–December 2011 due to a slowdown
in capital inflows that reflected global uncertainty.
However, conditions eased in Q4 of 2011-12,
reflecting a pickup in capital inflows as well as
the impact of policy measures undertaken to
improve the dollar supply and contain speculation
(Chart II.31). During 2011-12, the 6-, 30- and
36-currency trade weighted real effective exchange
rates (REER) depreciated in the range of 7-8 per
cent, primarily reflecting the nominal depreciation
of the rupee against the US dollar by about 13 per
cent (Appendix Table No. 14).
II.4.23 During H1 of 2011-12, the turnover for
currency futures showed a rising trend, but
remained range bound thereafter.
Housing prices remain firm
II.4.24 Despite the hardening of mortgage rates,
housing prices continue to remain firm at the aggregate national level. The Reserve Bank’s
House Price Index (HPI), based on residential
property prices for nine cities collected from the
registration authorities of the respective state
governments, increased during 2011-12 (average
of four quarters) at all-India level and also in all the
constituent cities, barring Chennai. Although House
Transactions Volume Index declined during 2011-
12 (average of four quarters) at all-India level,
significant acceleration is witnessed in case of
Lucknow, Kolkata, Chennai, Jaipur and Kanpur
(Chart II.32).
|
II.4.25 Over the last two years housing price
inflation has ranged between 16 - 25 per cent
during various quarters. Gold prices have increased
at an even faster rate of 14 - 40 per cent. These
two markets have not only provided effective
inflation hedges, but also enabled savers to earn
good real returns amidst high inflation. However,
with housing and gold prices running ahead of
inflation, there is a need for containing risks. In
April 2012, the Reserve Bank took prudential
measures on bank lending to NBFCS engaged in
lending against gold. While credit to housing and
commercial real estate has slowed down, a close
vigil is still necessary as housing price inflation has
not moderated. The Reserve Bank will continue to monitor the asset prices ahead from a macroprudential
angle.
II.5 GOVERNMENT FINANCES
Fiscal targets missed in 2011-12, with adverse
impact on the macroeconomy
II.5.1 The centre’s finances for 2011-12
experienced considerable slippage as key deficit
indicators turned out to be much higher than
budgeted due to shortfall in tax revenues and
overshooting of expenditure (Appendix Table 15).
This hampered return to the fiscal consolidation
path and impacted the economy adversely. Current
indications are that fiscal targets can again be
missed in 2012-13, unless immediate remedial
measures are undertaken.
II.5.2 A host of factors, both domestic and
external, contributed to the widening of deficit
indicators. The firming up of international crude oil
prices, the reduction in indirect taxes on petroleum
products, shortfall in revenue due to more than
anticipated slowdown in economic growth and lower
than budgeted disinvestment receipts contributed
to the fiscal slippage in 2011-12. Consequently, the
gross fiscal deficit (GFD)-GDP ratio moved up to
5.8 per cent in 2011-12 compared to the budgeted
ratio of 4.6 per cent, although some reduction in
plan expenditure muted the extent of fiscal
deterioration.
Budgetary stance for 2012-13 and the mediumterm
roadmap suggest fiscal consolidation ahead
but risks remain
II.5.3 The union budget for 2012-13 sets out a
roadmap for fiscal consolidation by budgeting a
significant reduction in the GFD-GDP ratio
beginning from 2012-13 and continuing the process
through further corrections in the revenue deficit
(RD)-GDP and GFD-GDP ratios under the rolling
targets for the next two years. The envisaged
correction of 0.9 per cent in the RD-GDP ratio and
0.7 per cent in the GFD-GDP ratio during 2012-13
(BE) would increase the space for private sector
credit in the economy. This is to be achieved through
revenue enhancing (especially indirect tax measures
and non-tax revenues through spectrum auction
receipts) and expenditure control measures, viz.,
restricting expenditure on subsidies to below 2 per
cent of GDP. The widening of the services tax base,
and a partial rollback of crisis-related reductions in
various indirect tax rates are expected to contribute
to the tax receipts of the central government. There
are risks to fiscal targets laid down for 2012-13,
particularly if the envisaged tax buoyancies are not
realised and the cap on subsidies is not adhered
to. The medium-term fiscal roadmap in the union
budget envisages a slower paced correction relative
to the path prescribed by the Thirteenth Finance
Commission (ThFC) (Chart II.33). During the first
quarter of 2012-13, the fiscal deficit of the central government was more than one third of the budget
estimate for the whole year.
|
II.5.4 The amendment of the FRBM Act 2003
which, inter alia, incorporates a “Medium-term
Expenditure Framework Statement” (MEFS) is a
significant initiative taken in 2012-13 towards fiscal
consolidation. Under the amended FRBM Act, the
government seeks to eliminate effective revenue
deficit (which excludes grants for creation of capital
assets from revenue expenditure) by 2014-15,
thereby targeting correction in respect of the
structural component of deficit in the revenue
account. The MEFS would set out three-year rolling
targets for expenditure indicators as part of the
strategy to improve the quality of public expenditure
management.
II.5.5 Despite the widening of the centre’s fiscal
imbalances during 2011-12, its debt-GDP ratio
continued to decline from 52.8 per cent in 2010-11
to 51.9 per cent in 2011-12 (RE) due to high
nominal growth rate of GDP. Excluding the amount
not used for financing central government deficit,
(viz., the component of the National Small Savings
Fund that is invested in state governments’
securities and liabilities raised under the market
stabilisation scheme), the outstanding liabilities- GDP ratio of the central government is budgeted
to decline marginally to 45.5 per cent of GDP
during 2012-13 from 45.7 per cent in 2011-12
(RE).
II.5.6 As per the projections under the rolling
targets, the outstanding liabilities-GDP ratio is
expected to be lower than the ThFC’s recommended
level of 44.8 per cent by 2014-15. However, a
comprehensive analysis using various approaches
is needed to assess the sustainability of central
government debt over a longer term (Box II.14).
Speedier implementation of tax reforms needed for
recovery in tax-GDP ratio to pre-crisis levels
II.5.7 During 2012-13, the government seeks to
increase the tax-GDP ratio by 0.5 percentage point
over 2011-12 (RE) to 10.6 per cent, through rollback
of standard excise duty rates from 10 per cent
to 12 per cent, widening of the service tax base and
rationalisation of customs duty rates. The budgeted
growth in gross tax revenues (19.5 per cent) is,
however, placed below the average growth (23.6
per cent) recorded during the pre-crisis fiscal
consolidation phase (2004-05 to 2007-08), thereby
recognising the ongoing economic downturn.
Although the budgeted growth in direct tax receipts,
viz., corporation tax and income tax, is conservative,
that for receipts from union excise and customs
duties is substantially higher than the pre-crisis
trend. This could be subject to downside risks
emanating from the continuation of slowdown in
industrial activity and international trade.
II.5.8 Service tax rate has also been raised from
10 per cent to 12 per cent. The widening of the
service tax base by including within its ambit all
services other than those in the negative list, is a
step in the right direction but it would necessitate
careful implementation. Measures have also been
taken to harmonise central excise and service taxes
through the introduction of a common simplified
registration form and a common return for both the
taxes. Steps are being taken to operationalise
Goods and Services Tax (GST) network to function
as a ‘National Information Utility’ for the implementation of GST, as and when it is introduced.
Despite these positive steps, there is a need to
expedite the implementation of DTC and GST to
enable the recovery of the tax-GDP ratio to precrisis
level. Notably, the general government
revenue-GDP ratio in India has been considerably
below that in both advanced economies and
emerging market economies and has been
declining since 2007 (Chart II.34).
Box II.14
Sustainability of Public Debt
Traditionally, fiscal sustainability is assessed in terms of
indicator analysis. The standard approach to evaluate debt
sustainability is by focusing on the ratio of the government
debt to GDP. The debt is considered sustainable if the debt-
GDP ratio is stable or declining over time while a continuous
increase in this ratio is considered unsustainable. The
assessment of the debt-GDP ratio depends on the real
interest rate on the debt, the real growth rate of the economy,
the ‘primary balance’ of the government budget (the surplus
or deficit excluding interest payments), and the debt ratio in
the previous period. Analysts also use this relationship to
identify the primary surplus required to stabilise or reduce
the debt in future.
Several studies have approached the issue of debt
sustainability by posing a specific question – “What is the
threshold for debt beyond which its burden significantly affects
capital accumulation and growth?” The debt sustainability
framework was first developed by Domar (1944) which
postulated the growth rate of income exceeding the interest
rate as a necessary condition for sustainability. Domar showed
that a constant overall deficit to GDP ratio ensured
convergence of both the debt-GDP ratio and the interest-GDP
ratio to finite values. The debate on sustainability took a new
twist in the 1980s in connection with the growth of the public
sector. In evaluating public finance sustainability it was no
longer sufficient to examine the tax rate implications of a
constant deficit à la Domar. It became necessary to estimate
the future deficit path implied by current policies. Blanchard
et al (1990) proposed two necessary conditions for
sustainability: (a) the ratio of debt to GNP eventually
converging back to its initial level (b) the present discounted
value of the ratio of primary deficits to GNP being equal to
the negative of the current level of debt to GNP.
All three conditions (Domar and Blanchard et al) have been
employed in empirical studies to assess the ‘sustainability’ of
public finances. The sustainable level of public debt varies
between countries depending on several economic and
political features. It is usually higher for industrialised
countries than for emerging market economies. The former
have historically shown the capability to generate sufficiently
large primary surpluses to ensure the sustainability of their
debt even in adverse circumstances whereas the latter have
generally not gained this credibility. This is due to, inter alia,
weak revenue bases (with lower yields and higher volatility)
and less effective expenditure control during economic
upswings (this is particularly the case in Latin America).
However, there are significant regional differences among
emerging market economies, with Asian countries generally
doing more to ensure debt sustainability than countries in
other regions.
The IMF has also developed a formal framework for
conducting public and external debt sustainability analyses
(DSAs) as a tool to better detect, prevent, and resolve
potential crises. This framework became operational in 2002.
The objective of the framework is three-fold: (i) assess the
current debt situation, its maturity structure, whether it has fixed or floating rates, whether it is indexed, and by whom it
is held; (ii) identify vulnerabilities in the debt structure or the
policy framework far enough in advance so that policy
corrections can be introduced before payment difficulties
arise; (iii) in cases where such difficulties have emerged, or
are about to emerge, examine the impact of alternative debtstabilising
policy paths. The framework consists of two
complementary components: the analysis of the sustainability
of total public debt and that of total external debt. Each
component includes a baseline scenario, based on a set of
macroeconomic projections that articulate the government’s
intended policies, with the main assumptions and parameters
clearly laid out; and a series of sensitivity tests applied to the
baseline scenario, providing a probabilistic upper bound for
the debt dynamics under various assumptions regarding
policy variables, macroeconomic developments, and financing
costs. The paths of debt indicators under the baseline
scenario and the stress tests allow an assessment regarding
the vulnerability of a country to a payments crisis
In the case of India, after a decade of large fiscal deficits, a
rule-based fiscal framework, namely, the Fiscal Responsibility
and Budget Management (FRBM) Act was enacted in 2003,
with the objective of ensuring inter-generational equity in fiscal
management and the fiscal sustainability necessary for longterm
macroeconomic stability. The implementation of the
FRBM Act coincided with a decline in the central government’s
fiscal deficit by about 1.8 per cent of GDP between 2004-05
and 2007-08. The amended FRBM Act incorporates a
Medium-term Expenditure Framework Statement to bring
about an improvement in the quality of the expenditure. The
FRBM Act, in its original as well as amended form, stipulates
debt targets under the rolling targets framework. All state
governments have passed their FRBM Acts, out of which 27
states have amended their FRBMs as recommended by the
ThFC. Accordingly, states have set out targets for gradual
reductions in their individual debt-GSDP ratio. In a recent
study, Topalova and Nyberg suggested that a debt ratio in the
range of 60-65 per cent of GDP by 2015-16 might be suitable/
sustainable for India. This is lower than the 67.8 per cent
suggested by the ThFC by 2014-15.
References:
Blanchard, O., Jean-Claude Chouraqui, Robert P. Hagemann
and Nicola Sartor (1990), “The Sustainability of Fiscal Policy:
New Answers to Old Questions”, OECD Economic Studies,
No. 15, Autumn.
Buiter, W.H. (1985), “A Guide to Public Sector Debt and
Deficits”, Economic Policy, Vol.1, No. 1, November.
Domar, E.D. (1944), “The Burden of the Debt and the National
Income”, American Economic Review, Vol. 34, No. 4,
December.
IMF (2003), “Public Debt in Emerging Markets”, World
Economic Outlook, September.
Topalova, P and Dan Nyberg (2010), “What Level of Public
Debt could India Target?”, IMF Working Paper, WP/10/7,
January.
II.5.9 Another downside risk on the revenue front
emanates from a possible shortfall in realising
budgeted proceeds from disinvestment for 2012-13
as was the case in 2011-12 and in the past
(Chart II.35). In view of the uncertainty in realisation
of disinvestment proceeds, there is a need to
assess the fiscal imbalances without reckoning
proceeds available from disinvestment. Therefore,
the ‘financing gap’, which excludes disinvestment
receipts from the calculation of GFD, as used by
the 2011-12 report of the Prime Minister’s Economic
Advisory Council (PMEAC), becomes an important
indicator for assessing the durable nature of
government’s fiscal correction process (Chart II.36).
This is also necessary, given the government’s
objective of returning, by 2014-15, to the earlier
policy of crediting disinvestment proceeds to the National Investment Fund rather than utilising them
to finance budgetary expenditure (Box II.15).
|
|
Shift in budgeted expenditure towards capital
outlays will materialise only through capping of
expenditure on subsidies
II.5.10 Revenue expenditure growth is budgeted
to decline in 2012-13, while capital expenditure (both plan and non-plan components) is expected
to increase sharply. However, for the government
to contain its non-plan expenditure within the
budget estimates for 2012-13, the commitment of
capping expenditure on subsidies within 2 per cent
of GDP should be adhered to. Credible fiscal consolidation accompanied by higher capital
outlays is key to reviving investor sentiments and
the economy. The budgeted shift in expenditure
composition with higher allocations for capital
expenditure augurs well for economic growth, given
higher capital outlay multipliers (Box II.16).
Box II.15
Divestment Policy in India
A natural evolutionary process of a developing economy has
generally involved sequential phasing out of the government
from direct capital formation in the economy followed by a
reduction in its stake in public sector undertakings (PSUs).
This essentially reflects the need to provide for greater private
sector participation for more efficient use of resources.
The underlying objective of the divestment policy in India,
which was part of the New Industrial Policy introduced in
1991, was to raise resources, encourage wider private
participation and promote greater accountability of the PSUs.
In the initial phase, select profit-making PSUs were to be
divested. The Rangarajan Committee (1993) had
recommended: (a) identifying select PSUs for disinvestment
up to any level except in defence and atomic energy;
(b) transparency in the disinvestment process with due
protection of the rights of the workers; and (c) setting up an
autonomous body for the smooth functioning and monitoring
of the divestment programme. Accordingly, the Disinvestment
Commission was constituted in 1996 to advise the government
on the extent, mode, timing and pricing of divestment. It
suggested four modes of divestment: (i) trade sale involving
100 per cent change of ownership through direct sale of
shares at a fixed price; (ii) strategic sale involving sale of a
substantial part of investment along with management control
to private enterprise or individuals; (iii) offer of shares, implying
sale of shares to individuals and companies and (iv) closure
or sale of assets and liquidation of the company. In practice,
the government has mostly resorted to the third mode of
disinvestment, selling its shares in PSUs to minority
shareholders.
Divestment in PSUs is the main source of receipts under the
head of non-debt capital receipts. The government has
partially divested its stake in PSUs in the telecom, oil, energy,
metals and minerals, automobiles and hospitality industries. During 2005-06 to 2008-09, the disinvestment proceeds were
not used for financing budgetary expenditure but were credited
to the National Investment Fund (NIF), constituted in 2005.
The returns on investments from the NIF were treated as
non-tax revenues to be used to finance expenditure on social
infrastructure and provide capital to viable PSUs. In 2009-10,
the government decided to use the divestment proceeds
received during the three-year period, viz., 2009-12 to finance
social sector programmes that create capital assets.
Accordingly, disinvestment receipts were being used to partly
meet expenditure on select flagship programmes related to
rural employment, irrigation infrastructure, and urban and
rural infrastructure. Also, the returns from the investments
made earlier through the NIF continued to be employed to
finance selected social sector schemes that promote
education, health and employment and to meet the capital
investment requirements of profitable and revivable PSUs.
The government decided to continue the existing arrangement
of using disinvestment proceeds to finance programme
expenditure for 2012-13 and 2013-14.
Notably, the realisation of projected disinvestment receipts is
subject to market uncertainties. The government has not been
able to achieve the budget estimates for disinvestment in 14
out of 21 years. Although the policy of reckoning disinvestment
proceeds as a non-debt capital receipt to finance budgetary
expenditure reduces fiscal deficit, it would be desirable that
the government returns to the policy of crediting disinvestment
proceeds to NIF, thereby making the process fiscal deficit
neutral.
References:
Verma, A (2009), “Disinvestment Process in India”, Shodh,
Samiksha aur Mulyankan, Vol. II, Issue-6 (Feb.09-April.09).
http://www.divest.nic.in/
Box II.16
Fiscal Multipliers in India
Large scale fiscal stimulus provided to stimulate economic
activity in various countries in the aftermath of the global
financial crisis during 2007-2009 has renewed interest in the
size of fiscal multipliers. Fiscal multipliers measure the
responsiveness of output to changes in government spending or taxation. Conventionally, Keynesian theory shows higher
multipliers for government spending relative to taxes since
spending has a more immediate and direct impact on
aggregate demand. Recent research, however, points to the possibility of higher size of tax multipliers as tax cuts can also
stimulate investment demand, whether directly through
investment tax credits or indirectly as a complement with
higher demand for labour, over and above the Keynesian
channel through increase in disposable income. In contrast,
the fiscal multiplier is zero under Ricardian equivalence
between taxes and debt in a dynamic framework. Ricardian
consumers are forward-looking and fully aware of the
government’s inter-temporal budget constraint.
Empirical studies put forth a wide range of estimates for the
fiscal multipliers for economies, ranging from negative to more
than one (IMF, 2008), thereby failing to provide a clear
guidance for the effectiveness of counter-cyclical fiscal policy.
The effectiveness of counter-cyclical fiscal policy depends
not only on the size of the stimulus but also its composition,
i.e., the relative importance of tax cuts versus government
spending. There is interplay of factors such as monetary
stance, health of the banking sector, interest rate constrained
by the zero lower bound problems, slack in labour market and
level of public debt. Various studies have shown that fiscal
multipliers are smaller for poorer economies, more open
economies, economies with flexible exchange rates and
economies with high public debt levels.
Given that there are not too many studies quantifying the size
of the fiscal multiplier for India, there is a need for one,
particularly in the context of the post-crisis stimulus provided
by the government which led to a considerable deviation of
fiscal indicators from the targets envisaged under fiscal rules.
An empirical exercise was undertaken for the period 1980-81
to 2010-11 to estimate the size of multipliers of various
expenditure aggregates of combined government finances
based on vector auto regression (VAR) frameworka. The VAR
is estimated in growth rates using lags suggested by the
Akaike Information Criteria.
Various components of combined government expenditure
(deflated by WPI), i.e., revenue expenditure, capital outlay,
development expenditure, total expenditure and tax revenue
have been used in alternative specifications to examine their
impact on real GDP growth. The variables are then converted
into growth rates so that the ratio of the impulse response of
GDP to shock variables can be interpreted as elasticity. The
short-term multiplier is then obtained by dividing the elasticity
by the ratio of real spending to GDP. The long-term multipliers
(in terms of GDP) are obtained by cumulating the impulse
responses and dividing the total by the ratio of spending to
GDP. Denoting GDP by Y and government expenditure by G,
the elasticity is α = (ΔY/Y)/(ΔG/G), and, therefore, the
multiplier is ΔY/ΔG = α / (G/Y). Among the endogenous
variables, expenditure, GDP and tax variables are included
while call money rate representing the monetary policy stance,
trade openness and global GDP growth are treated as
exogenous variables. The results are set out below:
Fiscal Multipliers in India – 1980-81 to 2010-11 |
Combined Government
(Centre + States) |
Impact Multipliers |
Long run Multipliers |
Revenue expenditure |
0.47 |
- |
Capital outlay |
0.11 |
2.41 |
Aggregate expenditure |
0.55 |
0.27 |
The results show that GDP responds positively to a positive
shock to combined government expenditure. In the case of
revenue expenditure, the impact is high in the first year but
fades out thereafter as expected. The capital outlay has a
large long-term multiplier, reflecting its greater productivity in
the long run compared with the short run, revealed by the low
impact multiplier.
The impact multiplier of aggregate expenditure is higher while
its long run multiplier is low but positive. The composition of
government expenditure which is tilted in favour of revenue
expenditure can be regarded as the reason for this outcome.
The above results show the criticality of re-orienting the
expenditure composition of the government in favour of capital
outlay to its pre-crisis average of 20.9 per cent (2003-08) to
improve growth prospects in the long run (Chart).
References:
Christiano, L., Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo (2011),
“When is the Government Spending Multiplier Large?” Journal
of Political Economy, Vol. 119, No. 1, February.
Ilzetzki, E, E.G. Mendoza and C.A.Végh (2011), “How Big
(Small?) are Fiscal Multipliers?”, IMF Working Paper,
WP/11/52, March.
Romer, C.D and D. Romer (2007), “The Macroeconomic Effects
of Tax Changes: Estimates based on a New Measure of Fiscal
Shocks”, University of California, Berkeley, March.
Spilimbergo, A. and others (2008), “Fiscal Policy for the Crisis,”
IMF Staff Position Note, SPN/08/01, December 29.
II.5.11 Undoubtedly, some subsidies for
development purposes are inevitable but subsides
which do not reach the intended beneficiaries or are
not in tune with the macroeconomic fundamentals
should be rationalised. The capping of subsidies
coupled with better targeting of beneficiaries is a
positive step. The achievement of this objective
would necessitate steps to allow the pass-through
of international crude oil and fertiliser prices to
domestic prices. The budgeted reduction in
expenditure on subsidies is mainly due to a decline
of over 36 per cent in the petroleum subsidy in 2012-
13 over 2011-12 (RE) (Chart II.37). The compensation
to oil marketing companies (OMCs) for underrecoveries
budgeted at `400 billion for 2012-13
would be inadequate, taking into account the
spillover of petroleum subsidy payments for the last
quarter of 2011-12 and the delay in the deregulation
of administered prices, particularly diesel.
Increasing dependence on market borrowing for
financing fiscal deficit necessitates appropriate
monetary management
II.5.12 The fiscal deficit financing pattern for 2012-
13 shows continued reliance on market borrowings
(96 per cent of GFD), though the recourse to shortterm financing through treasury bills is budgeted at
2 per cent, significantly lower than the 22 per cent
in 2011-12. The government expects inflows in
small savings during 2012-13 after the outflows
experienced in 2011-12. The envisaged market
borrowings by the government for 2012-13 will have
to be managed appropriately to avoid crowding out
of private investment. It may also be noted that
revenue receipts falling short of targets would entail
higher market borrowings which, in turn, could limit
the space for monetary policy to respond to the
slowdown in growth.
Higher than budgeted development expenditure by
the states augurs well for their economies
II.5.13 The consolidated position of state
governments shows that revenue surplus, at 0.1
per cent of GDP during 2011-12 (RE), was lower
than that budgeted for the year due to higher
revenue expenditure, which more than offset the
increase in revenue receipts. Within revenue
receipts, both tax revenues and current transfers
from the centre were higher than the budget
estimates, the latter on account of higher tax
devolution from the centre. Despite moderation in
economic growth, higher own tax revenues reflected
better than budgeted own tax buoyancies, aided in
large part by higher VAT/sales tax collections on
petroleum products. On the expenditure side, the
increase was on account of development
expenditure. Nevertheless, 20 states showed a
revenue surplus during 2011-12 (RE), with the
surpluses of nine states higher than that budgeted
for the year.
II.5.14 The consolidated GFD-GDP ratio for the
states during 2011-12 (RE) was higher than the
budget estimates mainly due to the decline in the
revenue surplus, even though the capital outlay-
GDP ratio was lower than its budgeted level
(Appendix Table 16). State-wise data indicates that
GFD-GSDP ratios were higher than the budget
estimates and the ThFC targets in sixteen and
seven states, respectively. Development expenditure
including social sector expenditure was higher than
the budgeted level.
States likely to remain in fiscal consolidation mode
in 2012-13, but development and social sector
expenditure as ratio to GDP budgeted to decline
II.5.15 Key deficit indicators of the states are
budgeted to show improvement during 2012-13.
The consolidated revenue surplus is budgeted to
increase due to an increase in revenue receipts
coupled with a reduction in revenue expenditure.
Both own revenues and current transfers from the
centre are budgeted to increase during 2012-13.
The revenue surplus is expected to not only provide
resources for increased capital outlay during 2012-
13 but would also enable a reduction in GFD-GDP
ratio. State-wise data shows that the ThFC target
for GFD-GSDP ratio is budgeted to be met by 26
of the 28 states. The envisaged expenditure pattern
of states shows that, while the committed
expenditure-GDP ratio (comprising interest
payments, administrative services and pensions)
is budgeted to increase, the development
expenditure and social sector expenditure as ratios
to GDP are budgeted to decline during 2012-13.
While pursuing the fiscal consolidation agenda
further, it would be important to take steps to reduce
committed expenditures to free more resources for
development, social and capital expenditures.
Pressures on state finances emerging from state
power distribution utilities
II.5.16 A growing area of concern for the states is
the significant increase in financial losses of state
power distribution utilities (SPDUs) which cast a
burden on the finances of state governments.
Accordingly, structural reforms are needed to
improve the efficiency and viability of these SPDUs,
which would have a bearing on the finances of the
states. While the revenue accounts of several state
governments continue to record surpluses, this
needs to be seen in the light of mounting losses in
the SPDUs. Besides budgetary support to the
SPDUs through subsidies, grants, loans and equity
investments, the states also extend guarantees for
loans taken by the power utilities from banks and
financial institutions. Although guarantees are in
the nature of contingent liabilities and may not have
a direct impact on the finances of the states,
defaults in the loans, if any, can invoke the state
guarantees. This would adversely impact the state
government finances (Box II.17). Rationalisation of
power tariffs and reduction in distribution losses
could be critical in bringing about stability in the
finances of SPDUs.
Box II.17
Fiscal Implications of Contingent Liabilities of the States
The fiscal position of the states in terms of key deficits and
debt as ratios to GDP has shown improvement in recent years.
This, however, may not be as encouraging as it appears if the
liabilities of the state public sector undertakings (SPSUs) and
contingent liabilities arising out of assistance to them are
taken into consideration. Studies have pointed out examples
of the financial position of the overall public sector changing
due to bailouts of financial and non-financial entities in both
the private and the public sector. Although contingent liabilities
do not form part of the states’ debt obligations, in the event
of default by borrowing entities, the states are required to
meet the debt service obligations of these defaulting entities.
Therefore, contingent liabilities assume importance in the
analysis of public finances of the state governments.
In 2001, the Reserve Bank constituted a working group to
assess the fiscal risk of state government guarantees.
Recognising that a major constraint in analysing the true fiscal
position of states was the absence of a consistent and
standard pattern of reporting data on guarantees in the state budgets, the group recommended a uniform format to
regularly publish data regarding guarantees in the budget. An
internal working group on “Information on state government
guaranteed advances and bonds” set up in the Reserve Bank
in 2003 emphasised that transparency in information
disclosure was crucial to enhance market discipline and
proper rating of projects guaranteed by the state governments.
With an increase in fiscal transparency at the state government
level, particularly after the enactment of the respective FRBM
Acts, 20 of the 28 states are providing information on
contingent liabilities such as outstanding guarantees in their
budget documents (statements under fiscal responsibility
legislation). However, only 14 states publish it in the prescribed
format, of which nine provide information on outstanding riskweighted
guarantees.
The consolidated outstanding guarantees by state
governments as a proportion of GDP increased from 6.1 per
cent in 1990-91 to 8.0 per cent in 2003-04 but declined thereafter to 2.8 per cent as at end-March 2010. As per latest
available information, outstanding guarantees for 14 states
amounted to `1.3 trillion as at end-March 2011. In view of the
fiscal implications of guarantees, many states have taken
initiatives to place ceilings (statutory or administrative) on
guarantees. To contain the fiscal risks associated with the
guarantees, Guarantee Redemption Funds have been set up
by 10 states.
Although there has been a decline in the total outstanding
guarantees extended by state governments, an increase in
the share of guarantees to financially ailing SPSUs is an area
of concern. Moreover, contingent liabilities of the state
governments could be much higher than is evident from their
budget documents/finance accounts, if the ‘letters of comfort’
extended to SPSUs, including power utilities, are included.
Another form of contingent liabilities relates to public private
partnership (PPP) at the state government level. The ThFC
noted that there are explicit and implicit obligations for the
public entity involved in PPP projects. While explicit contingent
liabilities in the form of stipulated annuity payments over a multi-year horizon may be spelt out, implicit contingent
liabilities are obligations to compensate the private sector
partners for contingencies such as changes in specifications,
breach of obligations and early termination of contracts, which
may be difficult to quantify. As recommended by the ThFC for
the central government, there is also a need for the states to
quantify expenditure obligations relating to PPP projects in
their medium-term fiscal policy statements, with an increasing
number of them adopting the PPP mode of project
implementation. The governments of Karnataka and Tamil
Nadu have included a statement on ‘Liabilities in Public Private
Partnership’ in their budget documents for 2012-13.
References
Cebotari, A. (2008), “Contingent Liabilities: Issues and
Practice”, IMF Working Paper, WP/08/245, October.
IMF (2007), “Manual on Fiscal Transparency”.
Reserve Bank of India (2002), “Report of the Working Group
to Assess the Fiscal Risk of State Government Guarantees”,
July.
II.5.17 The deviation in the deficit indicators of the
central government from the envisaged fiscal
consolidation path during 2011-12 was partly
contributed by the slowdown in economy which
impacted government revenues. The substantial
increase in subsidies during 2011-12 on account
of high crude oil prices further impacted the deficit
of the government. For a credible fiscal consolidation
strategy, steps need to be initiated to control
subsidies by de-regulating prices of administered
petroleum products and fertilisers, re-orienting
government expenditure in favour of capital
expenditure and speeding up tax reforms to improve
overall tax efficiency. Containing the fiscal deficit is
necessary for both external stability as well as
improving the efficacy of monetary policy.
II.6 EXTERNAL SECTOR
Deterioration in external sector during 2011-12
caused concern
II.6.1 The year 2011-12, especially the second
half, was characterised by a burgeoning current
account deficit (CAD), subdued equity inflows,
depletion of foreign exchange reserves, rising
external debt and deteriorating international
investment position. These indicators reflect the weakening external sector resilience and thus,
present a formidable challenge for policy makers.
II.6.2 After a marked deterioration in Q3 of
2011-12, India’s BoP witnessed further stress in
Q4, belying the seasonal pattern generally
observed in form of lower current account deficit
(CAD) in the last quarter . Sharper deceleration in
export growth than import growth led to higher trade
deficit. This coupled with deceleration in growth of
net services exports further widened the CAD-GDP
ratio to 4.5 per cent in Q4, taking the full year ratio
to an all time high of 4.2 per cent. This has been
much higher than the sustainable level of CAD
which is assessed to be around 2.5 per cent of GDP
with slower growth. This was also reflected in
drawdown of foreign exchange reserves during Q4
of 2011-12 as net inflows under capital and finance
account were less than adequate to finance CAD.
II.6.3 Going forward, the moderation in global oil
prices from the earlier highs and some softening in
gold imports if sustained, are likely to have a
favourable impact on CAD. Notwithstanding these
factors, CAD may still stay wide enough to put
strains, especially if capital inflows remain moderate.
Risks to India’s balance of payments remain from
weaker global growth prospects, including that in the US, euro area and China, slowdown in global
trade and renewed risk aversion arising from the
sovereign debt crisis.
II.6.4 The emergence of external sector weakness
during 2011-12 was caused by several factors, both
domestic and global. The US dollar appreciated
against all major currencies, except the yen.
Consequently the Indian rupee, as also many other
emerging market currencies, came under
considerable pressure. Global commodity prices,
especially those of oil and gold, rose. As India’s
demand for these commodities is relatively inelastic
in nature, the current account widened sharply. At
the same time, the rising fiscal deficit boosted
private consumption with a spill over to increased
import demand. While investment climate
deteriorated, so did saving, keeping the CAD wide.
As a combined impact of these factors, financing
of wider CAD became more difficult. This also
brought rupee exchange rate under pressure.
Furthermore, high domestic inflation led to inflation
differential that also contributed to a weaker
currency.
II.6.5 Weakening global economic and financial
conditions had adverse spillover impact on India’s
external sector in 2011-12. Moderate growth in
merchandise exports, coupled with robust import
growth, widened the trade deficit by 3 percentage
points of GDP to an all-time high of 10.0 per cent
of GDP in 2011-12. This alongwith sluggish growth
in invisibles caused CAD to rise above 4 per cent
of GDP. This level of CAD was markedly higher than
the CAD/GDP ratio of 3.1 per cent during 1966-67
and 3.0 per cent in 1990-91; the two occasions
when the country confronted balance of payments
crisis. This time around, the economy weathered
the external sector shock without any payments
crisis due to better access to international capital
markets and exchange rate flexibility. High level of
reserves acted as insurance against speculative
attacks and possible capital flights and the reserves
loss was contained by exchange rate adjustment.
II.6.6 The global financial uncertainty resulted in
reduced risk appetite and led to volatile and reduced capital flows to Emerging and Developing
Economies (EDEs) beginning third quarter of
2011-12. With moderation in the capital flows, CAD
was financed partly by drawing down the foreign
exchange reserves. Increase in external debt,
contributed by a marked increase in commercial
borrowings, export credits and short-term debt
further led to a deterioration of external sector
vulnerability indicators during 2011-12.
India’s trade performance was subdued due to
slowdown in exports and imports remaining sticky
II.6.7 Subdued growth conditions in advanced
economies began to weaken external demand for
exports from emerging market economies in the
latter half of 2011-12. India’s export growth also
showed concomitant moderation (Chart II.38,
Appendix Table 17). Trade diversification benefits
were also restricted by spillovers that shrunk EME’s
trade. After recording an average monthly growth
rate of 41.0 per cent in the first half of the year,
export growth lost its momentum and grew by about
7.6 per cent in the second half of 2011-12. The
overall export growth at 21.3 per cent in 2011-12
was nearly of half of that recorded in 2010-11. In
contrast, import growth was higher in 2011-12
mainly on account of import of POL and gold &
silver.
|
II.6.8 Despite sharp increases in the international
prices of crude oil and gold & silver, their import grew significantly in 2011-12, accounting for 43.1
per cent of merchandise imports (Box II.18). The increasing oil intensity of the economy (7.0 per cent
of GDP during 2008-12 compared with 4.7 per cent
during 2003-07) is reflected in the 35 per cent
growth in quantum of net POL imports during
2008-12 over 2003-07. The moderation in non-oil
non-gold import growth in 2011-12 may be due to
the economic slowdown and the impact of rupee
depreciation in the second half of 2011-12. Subdued
global growth prospects also impacted the imports
of export related items since the beginning of 2011-
12. Growth in import of export related items was
mainly affected due to contraction in imports of
pearl and precious/semi precious stones and
decelerated growth in imports of chemicals.
However, the import growth in bulk items and capital
goods imports increased in 2011-12. Capital goods
imports seem to be substituting domestic production
of capital goods, which showed a decline of 4.0 per
cent in 2011-12.
Box II.18
Determinant of Gold Demand in India
According to the latest World Gold Council release, inspite
of a 17 per cent year-on-year fall in gold consumption, India
remained the largest consumer of gold in the world, followed
by China. Based on the DGCI&S data, India’s gold import
is estimated to have grown by 39 per cent during 2011-12.
According to the World Gold Council, India’s quantum of
gold imports accounted for a quarter of the world demand
in 2011-12. Over the past decade India witnessed, on an
average, an annual growth of 29 per cent and 18 per cent
in gold consumption and gold price respectively, outpacing
country’s real GDP growth and inflation. During 2008-09 to
2011-12, on average, the quantum of gold imports grew by
12 per cent as compared to a decline of 5 per cent during
2005-06 to 2007-08.
Large gold imports reduce the availability of foreign
exchange reserves for other imports (including raw material,
intermediates and capital equipment) that may have better
productivity usage (Vaidyanathan, 1999).
During the recent period gold imports in terms of value
as well as in quantity witnessed a sharp rise despite the
increase in gold prices (Chart a). India’s import of gold is
on account of domestic consumption/ investment as well as
gold re-exports in the form of jewellery. Based on past trends
of gold import content in total gems and jewellery exports,
it is estimated that gold re-export was around US$ 7 billion
in 2011-12.
Increase in domestic demand for gold in India has stayed
strong in view of its characteristic as a safe investment asset
that has given good returns, while at the same time serving
as a consumption asset that meets the demand for jewellery.
Higher real rate of return on gold investment vis-à-vis
alternative modes of investments, viz., bank deposits and
the stock market seems to have boosted gold investment
by domestic residents. Further, various schemes mooted
by banks to promote gold as an investment asset among individuals is adding to the demand for gold. In the past 11
years, gold has given a compounded annual return of 18.5
per cent per annum.
|
NBFCs have also promoted gold investments in several
ways. Gold demand picked up because of easy availability
of gold loans by NBFCs. To examine the trends in demand
for gold loans and its impact on gold imports, the Reserve
Bank set up a Working Group on Gold Loans by NBFCs in
April 2012. The high level of gold import observed during
the recent past has become an acute problem in recent
times especially against the backdrop of deterioration in the
overall external situation. The price inelastic nature exhibited
by gold imports in the recent period has put considerable
strain on the trade balance and CAD. If the trade balance
is adjusted by excluding oil and gold imports, trade deficit
would be significantly lower for the last four years (Chart
b). Further, the diversion of household financial saving to
investment in gold may have impacted the growth of term
deposits in recent years (16.7 per cent in 2009-10 to 2011-12
as against 23.1 per cent in 2006-07 to 2008-09). Since such
investments in gold do not contribute to capital formation,
they are likely to have implications for overall investment and
economic growth.
There are very few systematic studies on the sensitivity
of demand for gold. Sarma et al. (1992) identified gold
price, rural surplus, rural income distribution, unaccounted
income/ wealth generated mainly in the service sector, rate
of return on alternative financing assets and the general
price level affecting gold demand in India. Vaidyanathan
(1999) found that the price of gold relative to share prices
and international gold prices was an important determinant
of gold imports.
An empirical analysis using annual data for the period
1998-2012 indicates that real per capita income growth and
inflation are the major determinants of gold import in India.
The positive and statistically significant coefficient of WPIinflation possibly indicates that gold may also have been
used as a hedge against inflation in India. The regression
results do not find support for the negative price-quantity
demand relationship, as the coefficient of gold prices was
found to be statistically insignificant at the conventional
levels. This result is, however, in line with the trend suggested
by Chart-a. It is possible that despite high prices, the
demand for gold picked up after 2007-08 as a response to
macroeconomic uncertainties, especially as retail investors
tend to view investments in gold as a safe haven.
|
Several policy measures have been taken recently to curb
gold imports. The government increased the basic customs
duty on standard gold imports from 2 per cent to 4 per
cent and on non-standard gold from 5 per cent to 10 per
cent. Similarly, recognising the rapid increase in exposure of NBFC’s to gold loans, the Reserve Bank introduced
prudential measures that prescribe NBFCs to maintain
a loan-to-value ratio not exceeding 60 per cent for loans
granted against the collateral of gold jewellery and disclose
in their balance sheet the percentage of such loans to their
total assets.
References:
Sarma, A, A. Vasudevan, K. Sabhapathy and Mohua Roy
(1992), “Gold Mobilisation as an Instrument of External
Adjustment”, DRG Study No.3, Reserve Bank of India, April.
Vaidyanathan, A. (1999), “Consumption of Gold in India”,
Economic and Political Weekly, February.
World Gold Council (2011), Quarterly Gold Demand Trends
(available on http:www.gold.org).
II.6.9 The exports recorded a decline of 5.1 per
cent to US$ 97.6 billion during 2012-13 so far (April-
July) as compared with US$ 102.8 billion in the
corresponding period of the preceding year largely
reflecting the prolonged slowdown in euro area, as
also lower growth in US and other emerging market
economies. The labour intensive sectors like
handicrafts, textiles and gems and jewellery were
assessed to be affected severely by the slowdown.
Imports also declined by 6.5 per cent to US$ 153.2
billion during the same period from US$ 163.8 billion in the comparable period of previous year mainly
reflecting lower domestic demand coupled with
subdued exports as some imports are used as
inputs in the exports related industries. Going
forward, the measures announced by the government
in June 2012 in terms of interest subvention and
other sector-specific incentives will have an impact
on the export performance with a lag.
India’s trade exposure to euro area is limited
II.6.10 The five troubled euro area countries –
Greece, Portugal, Spain, Ireland and Italy –
together account for less than 3.5 per cent of India’s
exports and 1.7 per cent of India’s imports.
However, global developments during the third
quarter of 2011-12 renewed fears that the euro
area crisis would escalate. The impact was evident
in EDEs including India, though the pattern of
spillovers varied across economies depending on
the strength of trade and financial linkages, and
euro area bank exposures. Reflecting the export
diversification policy efforts by the government, the
share of developing economies in India’s total
exports has shown a gradual increase in recent
years. However, as the sluggish economic
conditions in advanced economies gradually
spilled over to other EDEs, export diversification
efforts did not yield results similar to those seen in
previous years. Destination-wise, moderation in
India’s export growth during 2011-12 was significant in the case of OPEC economies, European Union
and other developing economies, particularly the
newly emerging destinations of African and Latin
American economies. Global Trade Alert data
suggest that protectionist actions announced
across advanced and emerging market economies
in the third quarter of 2011 were as high as in the
worst period of 2009. Recognising the concerns
relating to moderation in export growth, the
government announced various export boosting
measures in June 2012 that inter alia include
extension of interest subvention and Zero Duty
Export Promotion Capital Goods (EPCGs) scheme
up to March 2013 and increased coverage under
the Focus Market Scheme (FMS), Special FMS
Scheme and Focus Product Scheme.
Financing of CAD posed concerns in the second
half of 2011-12
II.6.11 The increase in India’s CAD in 2011-12
has been largely on account of the worsening trade
balance (Appendix Table 18). The merchandise
trade deficit was at a historic high of 10.0 per cent
of GDP in 2011-12. The trade deficit-led CAD was
comfortably financed in the first half, as capital
inflows exhibited an uptrend, mainly on account of
robust FDI inflows and a rise in external commercial
borrowings (ECBs) and trade credit (Appendix
Table 19). In the third quarter of 2011-12, however,
not only was the CAD significantly higher but
capital inflows also moderated as growing global
uncertainties impacted the risk appetite of global
investors. During 2011-12, CAD was 70.1 per cent
higher than the level during 2010-11 (Chart II.39).
II.6.12 On a cumulative basis, CAD stood at 4.2
per cent of GDP during 2011-12. Growth in net
services exports was too moderate to fully offset
the adverse impact of the high trade deficit on CAD
during 2011-12. Growth in exports of services
moderated at 7.1 per cent during 2011-12 as
against 34.4 per cent during 2010-11 while imports
of services declined by 7.3 per cent as against an
increase of 39.4 per cent during 2010-11. Despite
the slowdown in major export markets, software
services receipts, accounting for around 44 per cent of total services exports, continued to show higher
growth (Chart II.40).
Capital inflows moderated in Q2 and Q3 but
recovered in Q4
II.6.13 The pattern of capital inflows showed a
significant variation during 2011-12 (Chart II.41).
Net inflows under the capital and financial account
(bifurcation of the erstwhile capital account of Balance of Payments under IMF’s sixth edition of
Balance of Payment Manual) were buoyant in Q1.
Even though moderation in capital inflows began
in Q2, it became more pronounced in Q3, mainly
led by lower portfolio inflows and net repayments
under trade credit. Increased repatriation of inward
FDI and higher repayments of overseas borrowings
also led to greater outflows. Moderation in capital
inflows necessitated the drawdown of foreign
exchange reserves to meet the financing needs of
CAD in Q3 (Appendix Table 20). Due to a significant
drawdown in Q3, the level of foreign exchange
reserves (including valuation) declined from US$
304.8 billion at end-March 2011 to US$ 294.4
billion at end-March 2012.
|
|
Deteriorating international investment position and
rising short-term debt remain a policy concern
II.6.14 Various policy measures that were
undertaken against the backdrop of deteriorating
global financial conditions and India’s external
situation during the course of the year stimulated
debt creating flows in the form of investments by
FIIs in debt instruments, NRI deposits and external
commercial borrowings. Even though such flows
augured well for financing of CAD, their implications
were evident in the form of India’s rising external debt. External commercial borrowings, NRI deposits
and trade credit together accounted for 77 per cent
of the rise in total external debt at end-March 2012
over the level of end-March 2011 (Appendix Table
21).
II.6.15 With increasing recourse to debt flows and
drawdown of reserves to finance CAD, various
external sector vulnerability indicators showed
considerable deterioration during 2011-12. The
reserve cover of imports, the ratio of short-term
debt to total external debt, the ratio of foreign
exchange reserves to total debt, and the debt
service ratio deteriorated during the year (Chart
II.42). India’s net international investment position
also weakened during 2011-12.
Need to augment non-debt creating flows
II.6.16 In view of the higher dependence on debt
flows to finance the CAD during 2011-12, there is
a need for policy initiatives to augment non-debt
creating flows to keep composition of India’s
external liabilities at a comfortable level. In this
context, apart from insurance, reforms in the
pension sectors are necessary. There is a need to
further improve FDI inflows in sectors such as
insurance, retail, aviation and urban infrastructure.
|
II.6.17 In this context, the proposal relating to
further liberalisation of the Indian organised retail
sector by allowing up to 51 per cent of FDI in multibrand
retail and no limits for FDI in single-brand
retail was intensively debated during 2011-12.
Though the proposal in respect of multi-brand retail
has been kept in abeyance following lack of
consensus amongst various stakeholders, the
government in January 2012 raised the FDI limit
in single-brand retailing under the government
approval route from 51 per cent to 100 per cent.
Apprehensions in case of FDI in multi-brand
retailing mainly stem from possible predatory
pricing or below-the-cost pricing that can be
afforded by large retail chains. Such pricing
behaviour can drive out existing small kirana stores
and end up with creation of monopolistic power in
the absence of these small stores. These
apprehensions contrast with the international
experience that on the whole suggests that
allowing FDI in retailing space leads to increased
competition. Empirical evidence also suggests that
increased competition in retail space results in
lower prices which improves consumer welfare,
benefitting low income households the most. The
FDI in retail may be particularly helpful in improving
supply chain management through greater
investment in backend infrastructure, including cold
storage for farm and poultry products. Several
countries in east Asia have benefitted from FDI in
retailing over past two decades. Retailing and
wholesaling has also emerged as a major sector
of FDI inflows in China.
II.6.18 In recent years, outward FDI has increased
significantly in line with the trend observed in many
other emerging markets. The stock of outward FDI
from India reached US$ 112 billion at the end of
2011-12. While, these investments generate
benefits in terms of enhanced competitiveness and
market access, there is a need to balance the
domestic investment interests in the overall FDI
policy. Moreover, exponential rise in issuance of
guarantees by the Indian companies towards their
joint ventures/wholly owned subsidiaries abroad
could be a potential concern for banks and for the companies themselves. This needs to be closely
monitored.
Rupee depreciation driven by global currency
movements, domestic macroeconomic weakness
II.6.19 After being largely range bound in the first
four months of the financial year 2011-12, rupee
depreciated by about 17 per cent during August to
mid-December of 2011 reflecting global
uncertainties and domestic macro-economic
weakness. The S&P’s sovereign rating downgrade
of the US economy, deepening euro area crisis
and lack of credible resolution mechanisms led to
reduced risk appetite in global financial markets
and a flight to US dollar considered as a safe asset
by investors. With US dollar appreciating as a
result, most currencies with a notable exception of
yen came under pressure (Chart II.43). In general,
current account deficit countries witnessed sharper
depreciation as compared to current account
surplus countries, with the exception of Russia.
II.6.20 Considering the excessive pressures in the
currency markets, the Reserve Bank intervened in
the foreign exchange market through dollar sale. It
also took several capital account measures to
stabilise rupee that included deregulation of interest rates on rupee denominated NRI deposits and
enhancing the all-in-cost ceiling for ECBs with
average maturity of 3-5 years. The lock-in period of
long-term infrastructure bonds for FIIs (up to US$
5 billion within the overall ceiling of US$ 25 billion)
was reduced to one year, and ceilings for FIIs in
government securities and corporate bonds were
raised by US$ 5 billion each to US$ 20 billion and
US$ 45 billion respectively.
II.6.21 Consequent upon the series of measures
undertaken to improve dollar supply in the foreign
exchange market as also to curb speculation, the
rupee appreciated by 11 per cent by early February
2012, before weakening again by over 13 per cent
by end-May 2012.
II.6.22 The renewed pressure on rupee was mainly
due to widening trade deficit, drying up of capital
flows, particularly FII flows and apprehension about
the exit of Greece from the euro (Chart II.44). In
order to improve the inflows as also to reduce the
volatility in the rupee, the Reserve Bank took
additional measures in May and June 2012. The
measures in May 2012 included increase in interest
rate ceiling on FCNR(B) deposits, deregulation of
ceiling on interest rate for export credit in foreign
currency, and requirement to convert 50 per cent of the balances in the EEFC accounts to rupee
balances.
|
II.6.23 In June 2012, additional measures were
taken in consultation with the government which
included, inter alia, allowing ECB for Indian
companies for repayment of outstanding rupee
loans towards capital expenditure under the
approval route, enhancing the limit for FII investment
in G-secs by US$ 5 billion to US$ 20 billion,
allowing Qualified Foreign Investors (QFIs) to
invest in mutual funds that hold at least 25 per cent
of their assets in infrastructure under the sub-limit
for investment in such mutual funds and broadening
the investor base for G-Secs to include certain long
term investor classes that include Sovereign
Wealth Funds, insurance funds and pension funds.
Notwithstanding these measures, during 2012-13
so far (August 14, 2012) rupee depreciated by
8.1 per cent. The REER based on 6-, 30-, and
36- currency baskets also depreciated (Appendix
Table 13).
India’s foreign exchange reserves contract
II.6.24 The level of reserves moderated during
2011-12 as there was heavy drawdown in the
second half of 2011-12. The ratio of foreign
exchange reserves to debt also declined.
Nonetheless, in terms of adequacy of reserves,
India continues to be in comfort zone going by the
various alternative norms. In terms of traditional
indicators, reserve cover for imports at 7.1 months
against the rule of thumb of 3 month imports is
comfortable. Likewise, the level of reserves to
short-term debt at 377 per cent is much more than
the level of 100 per cent as prescribed under the
Greenspan-Guidotti rule. In its April 2012 Staff
Report, the IMF noted that India’s reserve coverage
is adequate (1.8 times of the 2011 gross external
financing requirement) and external debt, which
has remained at about 20 per cent of GDP and
compares well with other major emerging markets.
II.6.25 Going forward, the weaker rupee,
supplemented by other necessary policy responses
can help contain the current account deficit. The external sector scenario, however, needs
continuous monitoring so that growth in imports of
price insensitive items such as oil and gold, does
not impinge upon the trade deficit and CAD stays
within the sustainable range and does not act as
a drag on India’s forex reserves. There is a need
for more prudent macroeconomic and external
sector policies to keep external sector risks at bay
in the near term. This is especially so because debt creating flows have increased over the years,
making the economy more vulnerable to external
shocks. Since global economic and financial
conditions remain highly uncertain, there is no
room for complacency. Policymakers need to
address vulnerabilities emerging from rising
imbalances in India’s trade and current account
and also create a policy and business environment
that boost confidence among foreign investors.
|