Key
to the efficient conduct of monetary policy is the condition that it must exert
a systematic influence on the economy in a forward-looking sense. A priori
economic theory backed by some empirical evidence has identified the main channels
through which monetary policy impacts its final targets, viz., output,
employment and inflation. Broadly, the vehicles of monetary transmission can be
classified into financial market prices (e.g., interest rates, exchange
rates, yields, asset prices, equity prices) or financial market quantities (money
supply, credit aggregates, supply of government bonds and foreign denominated
assets). It is recognized that, whereas these channels are not mutually exclusive,
the relative importance of each channel may differ from one economy to another
depending on a number of factors including the underlying structural characteristics,
state of development of financial markets, the instruments available to monetary
policy, the fiscal stance and the degree of openness. Traditionally,
four key channels of monetary policy transmission are identified, viz., interest
rate, credit aggregates, asset prices and exchange rate channels. The interest
rate channel emerges as the dominant transmission mechanism of monetary policy.
An expansionary monetary policy, for instance, is expected to lead to a lowering
of the cost of loanable funds, which, in turn, raises investment and consumption
demand and should eventually get reflected in aggregate output and prices. Monetary
policy also operates on aggregate demand through changes in the availability of
loanable funds, i.e., the credit channel. It is, however, relevant to
note that the 'credit channel' is not a distinct, free-standing alternative to
the traditional transmission mechanism but should rather be seen as a channel
that can amplify and propagate conventional interest rate effects (Bernanke and
Gertler, 1995). Nevertheless, it is fair to regard the credit channel as running
alongside the interest rate channel to produce monetary effects on real activity
(RBI, 2002). Changes in interest rates by the monetary authorities also induce
movements in asset prices to generate wealth effects in terms of market valuations
of financial assets and liabilities. Higher interest rates can induce an appreciation
of the domestic currency, which in turn, leads to a reduction in net exports and,
hence, in aggregate demand and output. In the recent period, a fifth
channel – expectations – has assumed prominence in the conduct of
forward-looking monetary policy in view of its influence on the traditional four
channels. For example, the link between short- and long-term real rates is widely
believed to follow from the expectational hypothesis of the term structure of
interest rates. In a generalized context, the expectations channel of monetary
policy postulates that the beliefs of economic agents about future shocks to the
economy as also the central bank’s reactions can affect the variables that
are determined in a forward-looking manner. Thus, "open-mouth operation"
by the central bank, i.e., an announcement of future central bank policy influences
expectations in financial markets and leads to changes in output and inflation.
Clearly, the credibility of the monetary authority drives the expectations channel.
The rest of the paper focuses on the Indian experience with monetary
policy transmission. Section I delineates the objectives of monetary policy in
India. Section II presents the framework and instruments of monetary policy alongside
the evolution of institutional developments which were to have a fundamental bearing
on the monetary policy transmission. Section III discusses the monetary policy
transmission channels: operating procedures, channel of bank lending and rates,
debt market channel, exchange rate channel, and communication and expectations
channel. Section IV makes an assessment of monetary transmission in terms of the
ultimate objectives of monetary policy: price stability and growth. Section V
discusses what is needed to improve monetary transmission. In conclusion, section
VI sums up the challenges and dilemmas of monetary policy.
I. Objectives of Monetary Policy The short
title to the Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934 sets out the objectives of the Bank:
“to regulate the issue of Bank notes and the keeping of reserves with a
view to securing monetary stability in India and generally to operate the currency
and credit system of the country to its advantage”. Although there has not
been any explicit legislation for price stability, the twin objectives of monetary
policy in India are widely regarded as (i) price stability and (ii) provision
of adequate credit to productive sectors of the economy so as to support aggregate
demand and ensure high and sustained growth. With the increasing openness of the
Indian economy, greater emphasis has been laid in recent years on strengthening
the institutional capacity in the country to support growth consistent with stability
in the medium term. Given the overarching consideration for sustained growth in
the context of high levels of poverty and inequality, price stability has evolved
as the dominant objective of monetary policy. The underlying philosophy is that
it is only in a low and stable inflation environment that economic growth can
be sustained. In recent years, financial stability has assumed priority
in the conduct of monetary policy in view of the increasing openness of the Indian
economy, financial integration and possibility of cross border contagion. Strong
synergies and complementarities are observed between price stability and financial
stability in India. Accordingly, regulation, supervision and development of the
financial system remain in India within the legitimate ambit of monetary policy,
broadly interpreted. II. Framework and Instruments
Prior to the mid-1980s, there was no formal enunciation of monetary policy
objectives, instruments and transmission channels in India other than that of
administering the supply/ allocation of and demand for credit in alignment with
the needs of a planned economy. Over the period from 1985 to 1997, India followed
a monetary policy framework that could broadly be characterised as one of loose
and flexible monetary targeting with feedback (Annex I).
Under this approach, growth in broad money supply (M3) was projected in a manner
consistent with expected GDP growth and a tolerable level of inflation. The M3
growth thus worked out was considered a nominal anchor for policy. Reserve money
(RM) was used as the operating target and bank reserves as the operating instrument.
As deregulation increased the role of market forces in the determination of interest
rates and the exchange rate, monetary targeting, even in its flexible mode, came
under stress. Capital flows increased liquidity exogenously, put upward pressure
on the money supply, prices and the exchange rates, the latter having gained importance
vis à vis quantity variables. While most studies in India showed
that money demand functions had been fairly stable, it was increasingly felt that
financial innovations and technology had systematically eroded the predictive
potential of money demand estimations relative to the past. Interest rates gained
relative influence on the decision to hold money. Accordingly, the monetary policy
framework was reviewed towards the late 1990s, and the Reserve Bank switched over
to a more broad-based multiple indicator approach from 1998-99. In this approach,
policy perspectives are obtained by juxtaposing interest rates and other rates
of return in different markets (money, capital and government securities markets),
which are available at high frequency with medium and low frequency variables
such as currency, credit extended by banks and financial institutions, the fiscal
position, trade and capital flows, inflation rate, exchange rate, refinancing
and transactions in foreign exchange and output. For simplicity and to facilitate
greater understanding, the quarterly policy statements of the Reserve Bank continue
to be set in a framework in terms of money, output and prices. Since
the late 1980s, there has been an enhanced emphasis by many central banks on securing
operational freedom for monetary policy and investing it with a single goal, best
embodied in the growing independence of central banks and inflation targeting
as an operational framework for monetary policy, which has important implications
for transmission channels. In this context, the specific features of the Indian
economy have led to the emergence of a somewhat contrarian view: ‘‘In
India, we have not favoured the adoption of inflation targeting, while keeping
the attainment of low inflation as a central objective of monetary policy, along
with that of high and sustained growth that is so important for a developing economy.
Apart from the legitimate concern regarding growth as a key objective, there are
other factors that suggest that inflation targeting may not be appropriate for
India. First, unlike many other developing countries we have had a record of moderate
inflation, with double digit inflation being the exception, and largely socially
unacceptable. Second, adoption of inflation targeting requires the existence
of an efficient monetary transmission mechanism through the operation of efficient
financial markets and absence of interest rate distortions. In India, although
the money market, government debt and forex markets have indeed developed in recent
years, they still have some way to go, whereas the corporate debt market is still
to develop. Though interest rate deregulation has largely been accomplished, some
administered interest rates still persist. Third, inflationary pressures still
often emanate from significant supply shocks related to the effect of the monsoon
on agriculture, where monetary policy action may have little role. Finally, in
an economy as large as that of India, with various regional differences, and continued
existence of market imperfections in factor and product markets between regions,
the choice of a universally acceptable measure of inflation is also difficult’’
(Mohan, 2006b). The success of a framework that relies on indirect
instruments of monetary management such as interest rates is contingent upon the
extent and speed with which changes in the central bank's policy rate are transmitted
to the spectrum of market interest rates and exchange rate in the economy and
onward to the real sector. Clearly, monetary transmission cannot take place without
efficient price discovery, particularly, with respect to interest rates and exchange
rates. Therefore, in the efficient functioning of financial markets, the corresponding
development of the full financial market spectrum becomes necessary. In addition,
the growing integration of the Indian economy with the rest of the world has to
be recognized and provided for. Accordingly, reforms focused on improving operational
effectiveness of monetary policy have been put in process, while simultaneously
strengthening the regulatory role of the Reserve Bank, tightening the prudential
and supervisory norms, improving the credit delivery system and developing the
technological and institutional framework of the financial sector. Market
Development Given the pivotal role of the money market in transmission,
efforts initiated in the late 1980s were intensified over the full spectrum. Following
the withdrawal of the ceiling on inter-bank money market rates in 1989, several
financial innovations in terms of money market instruments such as certificate
of deposits, commercial paper and money market mutual funds were introduced in
phases. Barriers to entry were gradually eased by increasing the number of players
and relaxing the issuance and subscription norms in respect of money market instruments,
thus fostering better price discovery. Participation in the call money market
was widened to cover primary and satellite dealers and corporates (through primary
dealers), besides other participants. In order to improve monetary transmission
as also on prudential considerations, steps were initiated in 1999 to turn the
call money market into a pure inter-bank market and, simultaneously, to develop
a repo market outside the official window for providing a stable collateralised
funding alternative, particularly to non-banks who were phased out of the call
segment, and banks. The Collateralised Borrowing and Lending Obligation (CBLO),
a repo instrument developed by the Clearing Corporation of India Limited (CCIL)
for its members, with the CCIL acting as a central counter-party for borrowers
and lenders, was permitted as a money market instrument in 2002. With the development
of market repo and CBLO segments, the call money market has been transformed into
a pure inter-bank market, including primary dealers, from August 2005. A recent
noteworthy development is the substantial migration of money market activity from
the uncollateralised call money segment to the collateralised market repo and
CBLO markets (Annex II). Thus, uncollateralized overnight
transactions are now limited to banks and primary dealers in the interest of financial
stability (Table 1).
Table
1: Activity in Money Market Segments | (Rupees
billion) | Year/Month | Average
Daily Turnover (One leg) | Commercial
Paper (Outstanding) | Certificates
of Deposit (Outstanding) | Call
Money Market | Market
Repo | CBLO | Term
Money Market | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 |
2003-04^ | 86 | 26 | 3 | 3 | 78 | 32 |
2004-05 ^ | 71 | 43 | 34 | 3 | 117 | 61 |
2005-06 ^ | 90 | 53 | 100 | 4 | 173 | 273 |
2006-07 | | | | | | |
April | 85 | 55 | 163 | 5 | 165 | 441 |
May | 90 | 90 | 172 | 5 | 169 | 502 |
June | 87 | 106 | 138 | 6 | 197 | 564 |
July | 91 | 97 | 157 | 4 | 211 | 592 |
August | 107 | 78 | 156 | 5 | 229 | 656 |
September | 118 | 92 | 148 | 6 | 244 | 653 |
October | 132 | 97 | 170 | 5 | 232 | 658 |
November | 128 | 94 | 161 | 4 | 242 | 689 |
December | 121 | 72 | 155 | 5 | 233 | 686 |
CBLO: Collateralised Borrowing
and Lending Obligation. ^ : The average daily turnover (one leg) for a year
is arrived at by adding daily turnovers (one leg) and then dividing the sum by
the number of days in the year. Source: Macroeconomic
and Monetary Developments, various issues, RBI. | The
Government securities market is important for the entire debt market as it serves
as a benchmark for pricing other debt market instruments, thereby aiding the monetary
transmission across the yield curve. The key policy development that has enabled
a more independent monetary policy environment as well as the development of Government
securities market was the discontinuation of automatic monetisation of the government's
fiscal deficit since April 1997 through an agreement between the Government and
the Reserve Bank of India in September 1994 (Annex III).
Subsequently, enactment of the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management Act,
2003 has strengthened the institutional mechanism further: from April 2006 onwards,
the Reserve Bank is no longer permitted to subscribe to government securities
in the primary market. This step completes the transition to a fully market based
system for Government securities. Looking ahead, consequent to the recommendations
of the Twelfth Finance Commission, the Central Government would cease to raise
resources on behalf of State Governments, which, henceforth, will have to access
the market directly. Thus, State Governments' capability in raising resources
will be market determined and based on their own financial health. For ensuring
a smooth transition, institutional processes are being revamped towards greater
integration in monetary operations. As regards the foreign exchange
market, reforms have been focused on market development incorporating prudential
safeguards so that the market would not be destabilised in the process. The move
towards a market-based exchange rate regime in 1993, the subsequent adoption of
current account convertibility and de-facto capital account convertibility
for select categories of non-residents were the key enabling factors in reforming
the Indian foreign exchange market prior to now. India’s approach to financial
integration has so far been gradual and cautious guided by signposts/concomitants
in terms of improvement in fiscal, inflation and financial sector indicators,
inter alia. Efforts are currently underway to move towards fuller capital
account convertibility even for residents. In the period 2000-06, a number of
measures were initiated to integrate the Indian forex market with the global financial
system, with increasing freedom given to banks to borrow abroad and fix their
own position and gap limits (Annex IV). The
development of the monetary policy framework has also involved a great deal of
institutional initiatives in the area of trading, payments and settlement systems
along with the provision of technological infrastructure. The interaction of technology
with deregulation has also contributed to the emergence of a more open, competitive
and globalised financial market. While the policy measures in the pre-1990s period
were essentially devoted to financial deepening, the focus of reforms in the last
decade and a half has been engendering greater efficiency and productivity in
the banking system (Annex V). Legislative amendments have
also been carried out to strengthen RBI's regulatory jurisdiction over financial
markets, providing greater instrument independence and hence, ensuring monetary
transmission. The relative weights assigned to various channels of
transmission of monetary policy also reflect a conscious effort to move from direct
instruments of monetary control to indirect instruments. Illustratively, the CRR
which had been brought down from a peak of 15 per cent in 1994-95 to 4.5 per cent
by June 2003, before the onset of withdrawal of monetary accommodation since October
2004 is now 6.0 per cent (Chart 1). The recent amendment to the RBI Act in 2006
will further strengthen monetary maneuverability since it allows for the removal
of the floor of 3 per cent and ceiling of 15 per cent on CRR. Monetary control
is also exercised through the prescription of a statutory liquidity ratio (SLR),
which is a variant of the secondary reserve requirement in several countries.
It is maintained in the form of specified assets such as cash, gold and ‘approved’
and unencumbered securities – the latter being explicitly prescribed –
as a proportion to net demand and time liabilities (NDTL) of banks. Accordingly,
the SLR is also important for prudential purposes, i.e., to assure the soundness
of the banking system.The pre-emption under the SLR, which had increased to about
38.5 per cent of NDTL in the beginning of the 1990s, was brought to its statutory
minimum of 25 per cent by October 1997. Banks, however, continue to hold more
government securities than the statutory minimum SLR, reflecting risk perception
and portfolio choice. The statutory minimum SLR of 25 per cent has been removed
now (January 2007) to provide for greater flexibility in the RBI’s monetary
policy operations. The reform of the monetary and financial sectors has, thus,
enabled the Reserve Bank to expand the array of instruments at its command and
enhanced its ability to respond to evolving circumstances.
III. Operating Procedure for Monetary Policy Short-term
interest rates have emerged as the key indicators of the monetary policy stance
all over the world. It is also recognised that stability in financial markets
is critical for efficient price discovery and meaningful signaling. Since the
interest rate and exchange rate are key prices reflecting the cost of money, it
is particularly important for efficient functioning of the economy that they be
market determined and easily observed. Central banks follow a variety
of operating frameworks and procedures for signaling and implementing the monetary
policy stance on a day-to-day basis, with a view to achieving the ultimate objectives
– price stability and growth. The choice of policy framework in any economy
is always a difficult one and depends on the stage of macro-economic and financial
sector development and is somewhat of an evolutionary process (Mohan, 2006a).
In a market-oriented financial system, central banks typically use instruments
that are directly under their control: required reserve ratios, interest charged
on borrowed reserves (discount window) provided directly or through rediscounting
of financial assets held by depository institutions, open market operations (OMOs)
and selective credit controls. These instruments are usually directed at attaining
a prescribed value of the operating target, typically bank reserves and/ or a
very short-term interest rate (usually the overnight interbank rate). The optimal
choice between price and quantity targets would depend on the sources of disturbances
in the goods and money markets (Poole, 1970). If money demand is viewed as highly
unstable, greater output stability can be attained by stabilizing interest rates.
If, however, the main source of short-run instability arises from aggregate spending
or unsterilized capital inflows, a policy that stabilizes monetary aggregates
could be desirable. In reality, it often becomes difficult to trace out the sources
of instability. Instead, monetary policy is implemented by fixing, at least over
the short time horizon, the value of an operating target or policy instrument.
As additional information about the economy is obtained, the appropriate level
at which to fix the policy instrument/ target changes.
The operating procedures of monetary policy of most central banks have largely
converged to one of the following three variants: (i) a number of central banks,
including the US Federal Reserve, estimate the demand for bank reserves and then
carry out open market operations to target short-term interest rates; (ii) another
set of central banks, of which the Bank of Japan used to be a part until recently,
estimate market liquidity and carry out open market operations to target bank
reserves, while allowing interest rates to adjust; and (iii) a growing number
of central banks, including the European Central Bank and the Bank of England,
modulate monetary conditions in terms of both quantum and price of liquidity,
through a mix of OMOs, standing facilities and minimum reserve requirement and
changes in the policy rate. The operating procedure, followed in India, however,
presents a fourth variant. III.1 Money Markets and the Liquidity
Adjustment Facility In the Indian context, reforms in the
monetary policy operating framework, which were initiated in the late 1980s crystallised
into the Liquidity Adjustment Facility (LAF) in 2000 (Annex
VI). Under the LAF, the Reserve Bank sets its policy rates, i.e., repo and
reverse repo rates and carries out repo/reverse repo operations, thereby providing
a corridor for overnight money market rates (Chart 2). The LAF avoids targeting
a particular level of overnight money market rate in view of exogenous influences
impacting liquidity at the shorter end, viz., volatile government cash balances
and unpredictable foreign exchange flows. Although repo auctions can
be conducted at variable or fixed rates on overnight or longer-term, given market
preference and the need to transmit interest rate signals quickly, the LAF has
settled into a fixed rate overnight auction mode since April 2004. With the introduction
of Second LAF (SLAF) from November 28, 2005 market participants now have a second
window during the day to fine-tune their liquidity management (Chart 3). LAF operations
continue to be supplemented by access to the Reserve Bank’s standing facilities
linked to repo rate: export credit refinance to banks and standing liquidity facility
to the primary dealers.
The introduction of LAF has had several advantages. First and foremost, it made
possible the transition from direct instruments of monetary control to indirect
instruments. Since LAF operations enabled reduction in CRR without loss of monetary
control, certain dead weight loss for the system was saved. Second, LAF has provided
monetary authorities with greater flexibility in determining both the quantum
of adjustment as well as the rates by responding to the needs of the system on
a daily basis. Third and most importantly, though there is no formal targeting
of a point overnight interest rate, LAF helped to stabilise overnight call rates
within a specified corridor, the difference between the fixed repo and reverse
repo rates currently being 150 basis points. It has thus enabled the central bank
to affect demand for funds through policy rate changes. In this sense, LAF rates
perform the role of nominal anchor effectively. Although call money rates edged
above the repo rate during January-February 2006, the rates in the collateralised
segment of the money market – market repos and Collateralised Borrowing
and Lending Obligations (CBLO), which account for nearly 80 per cent of the market
turnover – remained below the repo rate. III.2
Market Stabilisation Scheme In the context of increasing openness
of the economy, a market-determined exchange rate and large capital inflows, monetary
management may warrant sterilizing foreign exchange market intervention, partly
or wholly, so as to retain the intent of monetary policy. Initially, the Reserve
Bank sterilized capital inflows by way of OMOs. Such sterilization, however, involves
cost in terms of lower returns on international assets vis-à-vis domestic
assets (Chart 4). The finite stock of government securities with the Reserve Bank
also limited its ability to sterilize. The LAF operations, which are essentially
designed to take care of frictional daily liquidity began to bear the burden of
stabilisation disproportionately. The
Reserve Bank, therefore, signed in March 2004 a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU)
with the Government of India for issuance of Treasury Bills and dated Government
Securities under the Market Stabilisation Scheme (MSS), in addition to normal
Government borrowings (Annex VII). The new instrument
empowered the Reserve Bank to absorb liquidity on a more enduring but still temporary
basis while leaving LAF for daily liquidity management and using conventional
OMO on more enduring basis (Chart 5). The MSS has provided the Reserve Bank flexibility
not only to absorb but also inject liquidity in times of need by way of unwinding.
Therefore, short-term instruments are generally preferred for MSS operations. The
various tools of liquidity management have thus enabled the Reserve Bank to maintain
liquidity conditions, orderly movement in both exchange rates and interest rates
and conduct monetary policy in accordance with its stated objectives (Annex
VIII and Table 2).
Table
2: Phases of Reserve Bank's Liquidity Management Operations |
(Rupees billion) |
| | Variation
during | Item | 2003-04 | 2004-05 | 2005-06 | 2006-07
Q1 | 2006-07 Q2 |
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 |
A. | Drivers
of Liquidity (1+2+3+4) | 721 | 581 | -317 | 355 | -158 |
1. | RBI’s Foreign Currency
Assets (adjusted for revaluation) | 1414 | 1150 | 688 | 285 | 105 |
2. | Currency with the Public | -434 | -409 | -573 | -215 | -1 |
3. | Surplus Cash balances
of the Centre with the Reserve Bank | -177 | 5 | -227 | 402 | -262 |
4. | Others (residual) | -83 | -165 | -205 | -118 | -1 |
B. | Management
of Liquidity (5+6+7+8) | -464 | -567 | 580 | -390 | 320 |
5. | Liquidity impact of LAF
Repos | -322 | 153 | 121 | -353 | 407 |
6. | Liquidity impact of OMO
(Net) * | -176 | 12 | 107 | 5 | 1 |
7. | Liquidity impact of MSS | 0 | -642 | 351 | -42 | -88 |
8. | First round liquidity
impact due to CRR change | 35 | -90 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
C. | Bank
Reserves (A+B) # | 257 | 14 | 263 | -35 | 162 |
(+) : Indicates injection of liquidity into
the banking system. (-) : Indicates absorption of liquidity from the banking
system. # : Includes vault cash with banks and adjusted for first round
liquidity impact due to CRR change. * : Adjusted for Consolidated Sinking
Funds (CSF) and Other Investments and including private placement. Note:
Data pertain to March 31 and last Friday for all other months. Source:
Annual Report and Macroeconomic and Monetary Developments, various
issues, RBI. | Government cash balances with the Reserve
Bank often display sizeable volatility. First, due to operational requirements
which are difficult to predict (except for salary payments, coupon/interest payments,
redemption of loans and the like), Government needs to maintain a substantial
cash position with the Reserve Bank. Second, there is the need for maintaining
or building up cash balances gradually over many weeks ahead of large, known disbursements
such as lumpy redemption of bonds contracted for financing high fiscal deficit
and, particularly, benchmark bonds, if markets are not to be disrupted. Third,
while a major part of outflows from government cash balances is regular, inflows
by way of direct tax revenues and other sources are lumpy and irregular in nature.
Accumulating Government cash balances with the central bank act, in
effect, as withdrawal of liquidity from the system and have the same effect as
that of monetary tightening, albeit without any intention to do so by
the monetary authority. Similarly, there would be injection of liquidity into
the system if Government cash balances maintained with the central bank decline,
despite a situation in which, for instance, monetary policy is biased towards
tightening liquidity. Thus, volatile Government cash balances could cause unanticipated
expansion or contraction of the monetary base, and consequently, money supply
and liquidity, which may not necessarily be consistent with the prevailing stance
of the monetary policy. In the presence of fluctuating Government cash balances,
the task of monetary management becomes complicated, often warranting offsetting
measures, partly or wholly, so as to retain the intent of monetary policy. III.3
Bank Credit and Lending Rate Channels There is some evidence
of the bank lending channel working in addition to the conventional interest rate
channel. In view of the asymmetry in the resource base, access to non-deposit
sources, asset allocation and liquidity, big and small banks are found to respond
in significantly different ways. In particular, small banks are more acutely affected
by contractionary monetary policy shocks as compared to big banks, i.e., smaller
banks curtail their lending more sharply vis-à-vis large banks (Pandit
et al, 2006). Available empirical evidence also indicates that prudential
norms, as proxied by banks' capital adequacy ratios, exert a significant influence
on bank lending (Annex IX, Nag and Das, 2002; Pandit et
al, 2006). The monetary policy stance of the Bank is often articulated
as a commitment to ensure that all genuine requirements for bank credit are adequately
met in order to support investment and export demand consistent with price stability
(Annex X). Liquidity operations are conducted with
a view to ensuring that the demand for reserves is satisfied and credit projections
consistent with macro economic objectives are achieved. Simultaneously, improvements
in the delivery of bank credit are pursued in recognition of the possibility of
market failure in efficiently auctioning credit. An integral element of
the conduct of monetary policy has, therefore, been the direction of bank credit
to certain sectors of priority such as agriculture, exports, small scale industry,
infrastructure, housing, micro-credit institutions and self help groups. An on
going policy endeavour is enhancing and simplifying the access to credit with
a view to securing the widest inclusion of society in the credit market (Table
3).
Table
3: Sectoral Shares in Non-food Bank Credit |
(Per cent) | Sector/Industry
| Outstanding on
October 27, 2006 | March
2006 | March 2005 | March
2004 | Non-food Gross
Bank Credit | 100 | 100 | 100 | 100 |
1. Agriculture and Allied Activities | 12 | 12 | 13 | 12 |
2. Industry (Small, Medium and Large) | 39 | 39 | 43 | 43 |
2.1 Small Scale Industries | 6 | 6 | 8 | 9 |
3.Services | 2 | 3 | 3 | … |
3.1 Transport Operators | 1 | 1 | 1 | … |
3.2 Professional and Others | 1 | 1 | 1 | … |
4. Personal Loans | 26 | 25 | 25 | … |
4.1 Housing | 14 | 13 | 13 | … |
4.2 Advances against
Fixed Deposits | 2 | 3 | 3 | 4 |
4.3 Credit Cards | 1 | 1 | 1 | … |
4.4 Education | 1 | 1 | 1 | … |
4.5 Consumer Durables | 1 | 1 | 1 | 1 |
5. Trade | 6 | 6 | 6 | 3 |
6. Others | 9 | 14 | 11 | 41 |
6.1 Real Estate Loans | 2 | 2 | 1 | 1 |
6.2 Non-Banking
Financial Companies | 2 | 2 | 2 | 2 |
Memo Item | Bank
Credit-GDP ratio | 40.3* | 42.2 | 35.2 | 30.4 |
Note: Sectoral shares may not add up to 100
due to rounding off; *: approximately. Source: Annual
Report 2005-06, RBI. | Available empirical
evidence covering the period September 1998 - March 2004 suggests that the interest
rate pass-through from changes in the policy rate was 0.61 and 0.42 for lending
and deposit rates, respectively, i.e., a reduction/increase of 100 basis points
(bps) in the Bank Rate led to a reduction/increase of almost 40 bps in the banks’
deposit rates and 60 bps in their prime lending rate (Tables
4 &Table 5). Rolling regressions suggest some improvement
in pass-through to lending rates and deposits. Thus, though pass-through is less
than complete, there are signs of an increase in pass-through over time (RBI,
2004b).
Table
4: Outstanding Term Deposits of Scheduled Commercial Banks by Interest Rate
| (At the end
of March) | (Per
cent to total deposits) | Interest
Rate Slab | 1996 | 1997 | 1998 | 1999 | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 |
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | 8 | 9 | 10 | 11 |
< 8% |
10.8 | 11.2 |
11.5 | 13.3 |
16.8 | 16.9 |
25.0 | 53.7 |
74.0 | 86.4 |
8 – 9% |
2.4 | 5.2 |
4.8 | 6.1 |
6.5 | 10.5 |
22.6 | 16.4 |
9.9 | 5.8 |
9 – 10% |
4.5 | 7.1 |
6.4 | 9.0 |
14.3 | 16.1 |
19.8 | 12.0 |
7.3 | 3.1 |
10 – 11% |
15.2 | 14.1 |
13.7 | 17.7 |
20.9 | 23.9 |
17.3 | 10.5 |
5.1 | 2.5 |
11 – 12% |
13.9 | 14.3 |
16.3 | 20.2 |
19.2 | 17.9 |
9.1 | 4.5 |
2.3 | 1.1 |
12 – 13% |
23.4 | 20.9 |
22.3 | 19.2 |
13.9 | 9.1 |
4.3 | 2.3 |
1.1 | 0.5 |
>13% |
29.8 | 27.2 |
25.0 | 14.5 |
8.4 | 5.6 |
1.9 | 0.8 |
0.5 | 0.7 |
Source: Basic
Statistical Returns of Scheduled Commercial Banks in India, various issues,
Reserve Bank of India. |
Table
5: Outstanding Loans of Scheduled Commercial Banks by Interest Rate (At
the end of March) | (Per
cent to total loans) | Interest
Rate Slab | 1990 | 1995 | 1997 | 1998 | 1999 | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 |
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | 8 | 9 | 10 | 11 | 12 |
| | | | | | | | | | | |
6% | 2.7 | 2.3 | 1.1 | 1.0 | 0.3 | 0.2 | 0.2 | 0.1 | 0.1 | 0.4 | 0.4 |
| | | | | | | | | | | |
6-10% | 6.8 | 2.1 | 0.5 | 0.4 | 3.7 | 1.0 | 0.6 | 3.2 | 5.3 | 13.6 | 19.5 |
| | | | | | | | | | | |
10-12% | 4.8 | 2.3 | 1.4 | 2.3 | 3.3 | 7.9 | 17.0 | 24.5 | 22.9 | 16.1 | 17.5 |
| | | | | | | | | | | |
12-14% | 21.4 | 10.6 | 10.7 | 13.2 | 20.3 | 26.8 | 28.6 | 22.5 | 25.1 | 25.7 | 22.4 |
| | | | | | | | | | | |
14-15% | 4.4 | 6.7 | 10.9 | 14.9 | 9.7 | 11.5 | 12.6 | 14.1 | 19.4 | 16.2 | 16.6 |
| | | | | | | | | | | |
> 15% | 59.8 |
76.0 | 75.4 | 68.2 | 62.7 | 52.6 | 41.0 | 35.6 | 27.1 | 28.0 | 23.6 |
| | | | | | | | | | | |
Source: As
in Table 4. | The improvement in
the pass-through can be attributed to policy efforts to impart greater flexibility
to the interest rate structure in the economy through various measures such as
advising banks: to introduce flexible interest rate option for new deposits; to
review their maximum spreads over prime lending rate (PLR) and reduce them wherever
they are unreasonably high; to announce the maximum spread over PLR to the public
along with the announcement of their PLR; and, to switch over to “all cost”
concept for borrowers by explicitly declaring the various charges such as processing
and service charges (Table 6). Besides, interest rates have
emerged as a more potent instrument than before with the move towards floating
as against fixed rate products under which the transmission is limited at the
margin.
Table
6: Lending Rates of Scheduled Commercial Banks in India |
(Per cent) |
| Public
Sector Banks | Foreign Banks | Private
Sector Banks | Demand
Loans | Term Loans | Demand
Loans | Term Loans | Demand
Loans | Term Loans |
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 |
Jun-02 | 12.75-14.00 | 12.75-14.00 | 13.00-14.75 | 13.00-15.50 | 13.75-16.00 | 14.00-16.00 |
Sep-02 | 12.00-14.00 | 12.25-14.00 | 13.00-14.75 | 12.75-14.50 | 14.00-16.00 | 13.50-15.00 |
Dec-02 | 11.85-14.00 | 12.25-14.00 | 12.00-14.75 | 11.70-13.63 | 13.50-15.75 | 13.50-15.00 |
Mar-03 | 11.50-14.00 | 12.00-14.00 | 10.50-12.75 | 10.25-13.50 | 13.50-15.50 | 13.00-15.00 |
Jun-03 | 11.50-14.00 | 11.50-14.00 | 10.00-14.00 | 9.73-13.00 | 13.00-15.00 | 12.50-14.75 |
Sep-03 | 11.50-13.50 | 11.00-13.50 | 9.50-12.75 | 9.25-13.50 | 13.00-14.50 | 12.00-14.50 |
Dec-03 | 11.50-13.00 | 11.00-13.25 | 7.75-13.65 | 9.00-13.00 | 12.50-14.50 | 11.50-14.50 |
Mar-04 | 11.00-12.75 | 11.00-12.75 | 7.50-11.00 | 8.00-11.60 | 12.00-14.00 | 11.25-14.00 |
Jun-04 | 10.50-12.50 | 10.75-12.75 | 6.50-11.50 | 7.25-10.95 | 11.50-13.75 | 11.00-14.00 |
Sep-04 | 10.50-12.50 | 9.50-12.25 | 6.75-9.00 | 7.25-11.00 | 11.25-13.25 | 9.50-13.00 |
Dec-04 | 9.00-12.50 | 8.38-12.13 | 7.25-9.00 | 7.38-10.95 | 10.00-13.00 | 9.25-13.00 |
Mar-05 | 9.00-12.50 | 8.38-12.00 | 7.13-9.00 | 7.63-9.50 | 10.00-12.50 | 9.00-13.00 |
Jun-05 | 8.00-12.13 | 8.00-11.88 | 7.75-9.00 | 7.50-9.50 | 10.00-12.75 | 9.00-13.00 |
Sep-05 | 8.00-11.63 | 8.00-11.88 | 7.00-10.25 | 7.35-9.50 | 10.00-12.50 | 9.00-13.00 |
Dec-05 | 8.00-11.63 | 8.00-11.63 | 7.00-9.50 | 7.20-9.50 | 10.00-13.00 | 9.25-13.00 |
Mar-06 | 8.00-11.63 | 8.00-11.63 | 8.00-9.75 | 7.53-9.75 | 9.50-13.00 | 9.00-13.18 |
Jun-06 | 8.00-11.25 | 8.00-12.00 | 7.63-9.75 | 7.53-9.75 | 9.75-13.50 | 9.23-13.75 |
Sep-06 | 8.25-11.50 | 8.50-12.13 | 8.08-9.57 | 7.85-9.75 | 10.00-13.50 | 9.45-13.50 |
Dec-06 | 8.00-11.88 | 8.50-12.00 | 8.05-10.00 | 8.00-9.50 | 10.00-13.13 | 9.23-12.63 |
Note: Median lending rates
in this table are the range within which at least 60 per cent business is contracted.
Source: Reserve Bank of India, available at http://rbidocs.rbi.org.in/lendingrate/home.html. |
In recent times, there has been some tendency to widen the net of administered
interest rates to cover bank loans for agriculture. While such a tendency may
not be an unlikely outcome given the predominance of publicly-owned financial
intermediaries, it needs to be recognized that the current system of pricing of
bank loans appears less than satisfactory particularly in respect of agriculture
and small scale industries (SSI). Competition has turned the pricing of a significant
proportion of loans far out of alignment with the BPLR and in a non-transparent
manner. Thus, there is a public perception that banks’ risk assessment processes
are less than appropriate and that there is underpricing of credit for corporates,
while there could be overpricing of lending to agriculture and SSI. Therefore,
the current practices on pricing of credit need to be revamped by banks through
well structured, segment-wise analysis of costs at various stages of intermediation
in the whole credit cycle. The Indian financial system appears to have
responded favourably to reforms initiated in the early 1990s with relatively higher
efficiency, competitiveness and resilience. This has enabled banks to increase
their lending to the commercial sector. Non-food credit extended by scheduled
commercial banks recorded an average annual growth of 26.4 per cent between 2002-03
and 2005-06, notably higher than that of 14.5 per cent recorded during the preceding
four-year period (1998-99 to 2001-02) as well as the long-run average of 17.8
per cent (1970-2006). Reflecting the growth in bank credit, the ratio of bank
credit to GDP has also witnessed a sharp rise. The credit-GDP ratio, after moving
in a narrow range of around 30 per cent between mid-1980s and late 1990s, started
increasing from 2000-01 onwards to 35 per cent during 2004-05 and further to 40
per cent during 2006-07. The stagnation in credit flow observed during the late
1990s, in retrospect, was partly caused by reduction in demand on account of increase
in real interest rates, the cyclical down turn and the significant business restructuring
that occurred during that period. The sharp expansion in bank credit in the past
4-5 years also reflects, in part, policy initiatives to improve flow of credit
to sectors like agriculture. While demand for agricultural and industrial credit
has remained strong in the current cycle, increasingly, retail credit has emerged
as the driver of growth. The strengthening of the banking system has thus worked
towards financial widening and deepening. In the process, greater monetization
and financial inclusion are extending the net of the formal financial system and
hence, enhancing the scope of monetary transmission. The increasing
reach of formal finance has gradually expanded to cover larger segments of the
population. The ‘demographic dividend’ of a larger and younger labour
force has meant that banks have been able to expand their loan portfolio rapidly,
enabling consumers to satisfy their lifestyle aspirations at a relatively young
age with an optimal combination of equity and debt to finance consumption and
asset creation. In the process, interest has become a much more potent tool of
monetary policy, affecting consumption and investment decisions of the population
in a fashion much more rapidly than was the case earlier. This is evident in the
share of retail credit in total bank credit, increasing from around 6 per cent
in March 1990 to over 22 per cent in March 2005. A large part of this increase
has taken place in the past 5-6 years. In view of this growing share of household
credit, it is likely that household consumption decisions, in the coming years,
may be more strongly influenced by monetary policy decisions with implications
for the monetary transmission mechanism. Consequently, the monetary authority
may need to contend increasingly with public opinion on monetary management, much
more than hitherto in the context of the rising share of personal/ household loans.
In the context of large scale public ownership of banks, such pressures of public
opinion would also manifest themselves into political pressures.
In brief, there is increasing evidence that the bank credit and lending rates
channels of monetary transmission are gaining in strength with the widening and
deepening of the financial system and the progress towards greater price discovery.
A number of constraints continue, however, to interfere with monetary transmission.
First, the stipulation of priority sector lending of 40 per cent of net bank credit
affects flexibility in sectoral credit allocation even though there is no interest
rate stipulation for the priority sector. Second, allocational flexibility is
further constrained under the extant prescription of a SLR of 25 per cent of net
demand and time liabilities (NDTL), though now the relevant Act has been amended
to give the Reserve Bank flexibility to reduce this statutory liquidity ratio.
Third, the system of BPLR for credit pricing has proved to be relatively sticky
downward and more so for specific sectors like agriculture and small scale industries
(SSI). As the BPLR has ceased to be a reference rate, assessment of the efficacy
of monetary transmission has become difficult. Fourth, the Government of India
continues to own around 70 per cent of banks’ assets. While the Government,
as a legitimate owner, is entitled to issue direction to public sector banks,
such exercise by the Government infuses elements of uncertainty and market imperfections,
impacting monetary transmission. III.4
Debt Market Channel While government debt management was one
of the motivating factors for the setting up of central banks in many countries,
currently the function with its focus on lowering the cost of public debt is often
looked upon as constraining monetary management, particularly when compulsions
of monetary policy amidst inflation expectations may necessitate a tighter monetary
policy stance. Therefore, it is now widely believed that the two functions - monetary
policy and public debt management – need to be conducted in a manner that
ensures transparency and independence in monetary operations. The fuller development
of financial markets, reasonable control over the fiscal deficit and necessary
legislative changes are regarded as pre-conditions for separation of debt management
from monetary management. The Reserve Bank currently performs the twin function
of public debt and monetary management. ‘‘The logical
question that follows is whether the experience of fiscal dominance over monetary
policy would have been different if there had been separation of debt management
from monetary management in India? Or, were we served better with both the
functions residing in the Reserve Bank? What has really happened is that
there was a significant change in thinking regarding overall economic policy during
the early 1990s, arguing for a reduced direct role of the Government in the economy.
A conscious view emerged in favour of fiscal stabilisation and reduction of fiscal
deficits aimed at eliminating the dominance of fiscal policy over monetary policy
through the prior practice of fiscal deficits being financed by automatic monetization.
It is this overall economic policy transformation that has provided greater autonomy
to monetary policy making in the 1990s. ‘‘The Indian economy
has made considerable progress in developing its financial markets, especially
the government securities market since 1991. Furthermore, fiscal dominance in
monetary policy formulation has significantly reduced in recent years. With the
onset of a fiscal consolidation process, withdrawal of the RBI from the primary
market of Government securities and expected legislative changes permitting a
reduction in the statutory minimum Statutory Liquidity Ratio, fiscal dominance
would be further diluted. ‘‘All of these changes took
place despite the continuation of debt management by the Reserve Bank. Thus, one
can argue that effective separation of monetary policy from debt management is
more a consequence of overall economic policy thinking rather than adherence to
a particular view on institutional arrangements’’ (Mohan, 2006b).
The Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management (FRBM) Act, 2003 has set
the stage for a front-loaded fiscal correction path for the Central Government.
Similar enactments have also taken place in a number of States. As already mentioned,
the FRBM Act, 2003 has prohibited the Reserve Bank from participating in primary
issuances of government securities with effect from April 1, 2006, except under
exceptional circumstances. In preparation, the institutional structures within
the Reserve Bank have been modified to strengthen monetary operations with a view
to moving towards functional separation between debt management and monetary operations.
Accordingly, a new Financial Markets Department (FMD) has been constituted to
undertake (i) monetary operations, (ii) regulation and development of money market
instruments and (iii) monitoring of money, government securities and foreign exchange
markets. The enactment of the FRBM Act has arguably strengthened monetary transmission
through the debt market. It has also mitigated the possibility of conflict in
monetary policy in order to contain the cost of Government borrowing. The
auction-based issue of government debt according to a pre-announced calendar has
enabled price discovery and liquidity in the market. A Negotiated Dealing System
was introduced in February 2002 to facilitate electronic bidding, secondary market
trading and settlement and to disseminate information on trades on a real-time
basis. In the context of the Reserve Bank’s absence from primary auctions,
‘when, as and if issued’ market in Government securities has been
allowed recently. Vibrant secondary market trading has helped to develop
a yield curve and the term structure of interest rates. This has facilitated pricing
of debt instruments in various market segments and, thereby, monetary transmission
across maturity and financial instruments. While market yields, at times, turn
out to be puzzling, particularly in the wake of global policy signaling as also
in times of re-pricing of risks, the reverse repo rate set out by the Reserve
Bank remains the overnight floor for the market. The falling interest rate scenario
witnessed up to 2003-04 and the comfortable liquidity position in the system had
helped to bring down the yields and the yield curve turned relatively flat. The
long-term yields, however, continue to be impervious across the globe to subsequent
reversal of the interest rate cycle, giving rise to a ‘conundrum’
a la Greenspan (2005). In the Indian context, the transmission from shorter
to longer end of the yield curve has been vacillating linked, inter alia,
to changes in monetary policy rates, inflation rates, international interest
rates and, on other occasions, the SLR stipulation. With the increasing openness
of the domestic economy, it appears that international economic developments are
set to exert a greater influence on the domestic yield curve than before. Thus,
even in the absence of fuller capital account convertibility, monetary transmission
may need to contend with impulses that arise from international developments.
Furthermore, the process of fiscal consolidation currently underway could potentially
lead to a situation of excess demand for government securities in relation to
their supply, which would, in turn, impact the shape of the yield curve and, thereby,
impede monetary transmission. The stipulation for SLR could also undergo a change
guided by prudential considerations, affecting, in the process, the demand for
government securities and thereby, the yield curve as banks remain invested with
government securities for the purpose of SLR. Such developments, however, may
not be in consonance with the monetary policy stance and hence, could come in
the way of intended monetary transmission. While the government
securities market is fairly well developed now, the corporate debt market remains
to be developed for facilitating monetary signaling across various market segments.
In the absence of a well developed corporate debt market, the demand for debt
instruments has largely concentrated on government securities with the attendant
implications for the yield curve and, in turn, for monetary transmission. The
secondary market for corporate debt has suffered from lack of market making resulting
in poor liquidity. Corporates continue to prefer private placements to public
issues for raising resources in view of ease of procedures and lower costs. There
is a need for development of mortgage-backed securities, credit default swaps,
bond insurance institutions for credit enhancement, abridgment of disclosure requirements
for listed companies, rating requirements for unlisted companies, real time reporting
of primary and secondary trading, retail access to bond market by non-profit institutions
and small corporates and access to RTGS. A concerted effort is now being made
to set up the institutional and technological structure that would enable the
corporate debt market to operate. Furthermore, the on-going reforms in the area
of social security coupled with the emergence of pension and provident funds are
expected to increase the demand for long-term debt instruments. In the process,
the investor base for government securities would be broadened, extending the
monetary transmission across new players and participants. III.5
Exchange Rate Channel The foreign exchange market in India
has acquired increasing depth with the transition to a market determined exchange
rate system in March 1993 and the subsequent gradual but significant liberalisation
of restrictions on various external transactions. Payments restrictions on all
current account transactions have been removed with the acceptance of the obligations
of Article VIII of the IMF’s Articles of Agreement in August 1994. While
the rupee remains virtually convertible on the capital account for foreign nationals
and non-resident Indians (NRIs), similar moves are on course for the domestic
residents. Significant relaxations have been allowed for capital outflows in the
form of direct and portfolio investment, non-resident deposits, repatriation of
assets and funds held abroad. Indian residents can now open foreign currency accounts
with banks in India. The major initiatives taken to widen and deepen
the Indian forex market and to link it with the global financial system have been:
(i) freedom to banks to fix net overnight position limits and gap limits, initiate
trading positions in the overseas markets, and use derivative products for asset-liability
management; (ii) permission to authorised dealers (ADs) in foreign exchange to
borrow abroad up to limits related to their capital base as a prudential measure;
and (iii) freedom to corporates to hedge anticipated exposures, cancel and rebook
forward contracts. The CCIL has commenced settlement of forex operations for inter-bank
US Dollar/Indian rupee spot and forward trades from November 2002 and inter-bank
US dollar/Indian rupee cash and tom trades from February 2004. The
annual turnover in the foreign exchange market has increased more than threefold
from US $ 1434 billion in 2000-01 to US $ 4413 billion in 2005-06 (Table
7). The inter-bank transactions continue to account for bulk of the transactions
in the forex market, albeit with a declining share over the years. The
forward market segment (swaps plus forward) is also growing at a faster pace.
Reflecting the build-up of forex reserves, the strong capital flows and the confidence
in the Indian economy, the forward premia has come down sharply from the peak
reached in 1995-96. Under the market determined exchange rate regime, the Indian
rupee has exhibited two way movements and the foreign exchange market has displayed
stable conditions as reflected in the annual coefficient of variation of 0.9-2.3
per cent during 2000-01 to 2005-06. The exchange rate policy of the Reserve Bank
in recent years has been guided by the broad principles of careful monitoring
and management of exchange rates with flexibility, without a fixed target or a
pre-announced target or a band, coupled with the ability to intervene, if and
when necessary.
Table
7: Foreign Exchange Market: Activity Indicators |
Year | Foreign
Exchange Market-Annual Turnover (US $ billion) | Gross
Volume of BoP Transactions (US $ billion) | RBI’s
Foreign Currency Assets* (US $ billion) | C.V.
of Exchange Rate of Rupee (per cent) | Col.
2 over Col. 3 |
Col. 2 over Col. 4 | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 |
2000-01 | 1434 | 258 | 40 | 2.3 | 5.6 | 36 |
2001-02 | 1487 | 237 | 51 | 1.4 | 6.3 | 29 |
2002-03 | 1585 | 267 | 72 | 0.9 | 5.9 | 22 |
2003-04 | 2141 | 362 | 107 | 1.6 | 5.9 | 20 |
2004-05 | 2892 | 481 | 136 | 2.3 | 6.0 | 21 |
2005-06 | 4413 | 657 | 145 | 1.5 | 6.7 | 30 |
*At end-March; C.V.: Coefficient
of Variation; BoP: Balance of Payments. Source: Reserve Bank
of India. | Exchange rate flexibility,
coupled with the gradual removal of capital controls, has widened the scope for
monetary maneuverability, enabling transmission through exchange rates. In the
event of interest rate arbitrage triggered by monetary policy action, foreign
exchange inflows can tend to pick up until the interest rate parity is restored
by exchange rate adjustments. An appreciating exchange rate, in turn, would have
a dampening effect on aggregate demand, containing inflationary pressures. However,
if large segments of economic agents lack adequate resilience to withstand volatility
in currency and money markets, the option of exchange rate adjustments may not
be available, partially or fully. Therefore, the central bank may need to carry
out foreign exchange operations for stabilizing the market. In the process, the
injection of liquidity into the system by the central bank would go against its
policy stance and weaken monetary transmission. Thus, monetary management becomes
complicated, and the monetary authority may need to undertake offsetting sterilisation
transactions in defence of monetary stability and intended transmission. In the
Indian context, faced with similar circumstances, sterilization operations are
being carried out from 2004 by issuances of government securities under the Market
Stabilisation Scheme (MSS). Available evidence suggests that
exchange rate depreciation has the expected effect of raising domestic prices
and the coefficient of exchange rate pass-through to domestic inflation ranges
between 8-17 basis points (depending upon the measure of inflation), i.e.,
a 10 per cent depreciation of the Indian rupee (vis-a-vis the US dollar)
would, other things remaining unchanged, increase consumer inflation by less than
one percentage point and the GDP deflator by 1.7 percentage points. Rolling regressions
suggest some decline in exchange rate pass-through coefficient in the recent years
(RBI, 2004b). The coefficient on the exchange rate exhibits a declining trend
although the estimates turn out to be somewhat imprecise. This suggests a possible
decline in exchange rate pass-through to domestic inflation. The decline in pass-through
during the 1990s is consistent with the cross-country evidence. In India, inflation
rates have declined significantly since the second half of the 1990s and this
could be one explanation for the lower pass-through. Another key factor that could
have lowered the pass-through is the phased decline in tariffs as well as non-tariff
barriers such as quotas. Average import duties are now less than one-third of
what they were a decade ago. This steep reduction in tariffs could have easily
allowed domestic producers to absorb some part of the exchange rate depreciation
without any effect on their profitability. Another factor that could
reduce the pass-through is related to globalisation and “Walmartisation”.
The increased intensity of globalisation and the commodification of many goods
have perhaps reduced the pricing power of producers, particularly of low technology
goods in developing countries, whereas the pricing power of large retailers like
Walmart has risen. The decline in pass-through across a number of countries, as
suggested by various studies, has implications for the efficacy of exchange rate
as an adjustment tool. The lower pass-through suggests that, in the new globalised
economy, exchange rate adjustments as a means of correction of imbalances may
have become less potent; if so, then the swing in exchange rates to correct emerging
imbalances will have to be much larger than before, bringing in their wake greater
instability eventually (Mohan, 2004). III.6 Communication
and Expectations Channel In a market-oriented economy, well-informed
market participants are expected to enable an improved functioning of the markets,
and it is held that a central bank is in the best position to provide such
useful information to the market participants. Whether providing information would
result in shaping and managing expectations, and if so, whether it is desirable,
remain unsettled issues. There are several dilemmas faced by central banks while
designing an appropriate communications policy. What should be communicated
and to what degree of disaggregation? The second set relates to: at what stage
of evolution of internal thinking and debate should there be dissemination? The
third set relates to the timing of communication with reference to its market
impact. The fourth relates to the quality of information and the possible ways
in which it could be perceived. Thus, alleged incoherence or an element
of ambiguity at times on the part of central bankers in explaining policies is
as much a reflection of the complexity of the issues as it is of the differing
perceptions of a variety of audiences to which the communication is addressed.
It is essential to appreciate that communication policy is not merely about explaining
or getting a feedback on policy, but may include elements of influencing the policy
direction itself. A central bank does this through several channels, including
research publications and speeches (Reddy, 2001; 2006). It is recognised that
credible communication and creative engagement with the market and economic agents
have emerged as the critical channel of monetary transmission as against the traditional
channels. For example, the US Federal Reserve, since 1994, appears to have been
providing forward guidance, while the European Central Bank appears to be in the
mould of keeping the markets informed rather than guiding it. With
the widening and deepening of inter-linkages between various segments of financial
markets, the Reserve Bank has adopted a consultative process for policy making
in order to ensure timely and effective implementation of the measures. The Bank
has taken a middle path of sharing its analysis in addition to providing information,
but in no way guiding the market participants. However, in doing so, the RBI has
the benefit of the process of two-way communication, of information as well as
perceptions, between the market participants and the RBI. In the process, the
Bank’s signaling/ announcements are increasingly seen to have an influence
on the expectations formation in the market.
The more complex is the mandate for the central bank, the more is the necessity
of communication (Mohan, 2005). The Reserve Bank of India clearly has complex
objectives. Apart from pursuing monetary policy, financial stability is one of
the overriding concerns of the RBI. Within the objective of monetary policy, both
control of inflation and providing adequate credit to the productive sectors of
the economy so as to foster growth are equally important. This apart, the Reserve
Bank acts as a banking regulator, public debt manager, government debt market
regulator and currency issuer. Faced with such multiple tasks and complex mandate,
there is an utmost necessity of clearer communication on the part of the Reserve
Bank. In general, for a central bank, there is necessity of three
kinds of communication, viz., (a) policy measures, (b) reasons behind such policy
measures and (c) analysis of the economy. The Reserve Bank is engaged with all
these three kinds of communication. In fact, by international standards the Reserve
Bank has a fairly extensive and transparent communication system. Policy statements
(quarterly since April 2005 onwards and bi-annual prior to this period) have traditionally
communicated the Reserve Bank’s stance on monetary policy in the immediate
future of six months to one year. The practice of attaching a review of
macroeconomic developments to the quarterly reviews gives an expansive view of
how the central bank sees the economy. In the bi-annual policy meetings with leading
bankers, the Governor explains the rationale behind the measures at length.
These policy meetings are not one-way traffic. Each banker present in the
meeting interacts with the Governor to express his or her reaction to the policy
announcement. After the policy announcement is over, the Governor addresses
a press conference in the afternoon. The Deputy Governor in charge of monetary
policy normally gives live interviews to all the major television channels on
the same day. The Governor also gives interviews to print and electronic media
over the next few days after the monetary policy announcement. Communication
of policy also takes place through speeches of the Governor and Deputy Governors,
and various periodic reports. A significant step towards transparency of monetary
policy implementation is formation of various Technical Advisory Committees (TACs)
in the Reserve Bank with representatives from market participants, other regulators
and experts. In line with the international best practices and with a view to
further strengthening the consultative process in monetary policy, the Reserve
Bank, in July 2005, set up a Technical Advisory Committee on Monetary Policy (TACMP)
with external experts in the areas of monetary economics, central banking, financial
markets and public finance. The Committee meets at least once in a quarter, reviews
macroeconomic and monetary developments and advises the Reserve Bank on the stance
of monetary policy. The Committee has contributed to enriching the inputs and
processes of monetary policy setting in India. Recognising the importance of expectations
in the conduct and formulation of monetary policy, the Reserve Bank has recently
initiated surveys of business and inflation expectations. Finally, in the
context of growing openness of the Indian economy and increasing integration with
the rest of the world, global economic and financial developments – such
as monetary policy decisions of the US Fed and other major economies and trends
in international crude oil prices – are also shaping expectations. The Reserve
Bank takes such factors and expectations also into account. The process
of monetary policy formulation in India is now relatively transparent, consultative
and participative with external orientation and this has contributed to stabilizing
expectations of market participants. Illustratively, an important element in coping
with liquidity management has been smoothening behaviour of the Reserve Bank and
its communication strategy. In August 2004, the headline inflation rate shot up
to 8.7 per cent, partly on account of rising global oil prices and partly due
to resurgence in manufacturing inflation. The turning of the interest rate cycle
looked imminent. The issue was addressed through burden sharing by appropriate
monetary and fiscal coordination and by preparing markets for a possible interest
rate reversal. In measured and calibrated steps the monetary policy stance was
changed and measures such as those on CRR and reverse repo were taken in a phased
manner. Also, banks were allowed to transfer HFT (Held for Trading) and AFS (Available
for Sale) securities to HTM (Held to Maturity) category, thereby affording them
some cushion against the possible interest rate shock. Markets were prepared with
a careful communication on the stance of the monetary policy that the central
bank would strive for provision of appropriate liquidity while placing equal emphasis
on price stability. Monetary management thus succeeded in building credibility
and keeping inflation expectations low. In brief, there has been a noteworthy
improvement in the operational efficiency of monetary policy from the early 1990s.
Financial sector reforms and the contemporaneous development of the money market,
Government securities market and the foreign exchange market have strengthened
monetary transmission by enabling more efficient price discovery, and improving
allocative efficiency even as the RBI has undertaken developmental efforts to
ensure the stability and smooth functioning of financial markets. The approach
has been one of simultaneous movement on several fronts, graduated and calibrated,
with an emphasis on institutional and infrastructural development and improvements
in market microstructure. The pace of the reform was contingent upon putting in
place appropriate systems and procedures, technologies and market practices. There
has been close co-ordination between the Government and the RBI, as also between
different regulators, which helped in orderly and smooth development of the financial
markets in India. Markets have now grown in size, depth and activity, paving the
way for flexible use of indirect instruments. The Reserve Bank has also engaged
in refining the operating procedures and instruments as also risk management systems,
income recognition and provisioning norms, disclosure norms, accounting standards
and insolvency in line with international best practices with a view to fostering
the seamless integration of Indian financial markets with global markets. IV.
How Well Do Monetary Transmission Channels Work? Turning to
an assessment of monetary policy transmission, it would be reasonable to assert
that monetary policy has been largely successful in meeting its key objectives
in the post-reforms period. There has been a fall in inflation worldwide since
the early 1990s, and in India since the late 1990s. Inflation has averaged close
to five per cent per annum in the decade gone by, notably lower than that of eight
per cent in the previous four decades (Chart 6). Structural reforms since the
early 1990s coupled with improved monetary-fiscal interface and reforms in the
Government securities market enabled better monetary management from the second
half of the 1990s onwards. More importantly, the regime of low and stable inflation
has, in turn, stabilised inflation expectations and inflation tolerance in the
economy has come down. It is encouraging to note that despite record high international
crude oil prices, inflation remains low and inflation expectations also remain
stable (Table 8). Since inflation expectations are a key
determinant of the actual inflation outcome, and given the lags in monetary transmission,
the Reserve Bank has been taking pre-emptive measures to keep inflation expectations
stable. As discussed earlier, a number of instruments, both existing as well as
new, were employed to modulate liquidity conditions to achieve the desired objectives.
A number of other factors such as increased competition, productivity gains and
strong corporate balance sheets have also contributed to this low and stable inflation
environment, but it appears that calibrated monetary measures had a substantial
role to play as well. In
the context of the recent firming up of core as against headline inflation particularly
in industrial countries, primarily on account of higher non-oil commodity prices,
issues of proper measurement of inflation and inflationary pressures have attracted
renewed debate. In particular, the debate involves the relevance of core inflation
as a guide for the conduct of monetary policy vis-à-vis the use of headline
inflation. In India, core inflation is not considered as relevant for several
reasons, but specially because the two major sources of supply shock, food and
fuel, account for a large share of the index. Further, in the absence of a harmonized
consumer price index for India, use of core inflation based on wholesale prices
may not be much meaningful. While the permanent component is judgmental, broad
magnitudes could be perceived and articulated. Such an explanatory approach to
headline and underlying inflation pressure in monetary policy has added credibility
to the policy and influenced and guided the inflation expectations in India.
Table
8: Wholesale Price Inflation (WPI) and Consumer Price Inflation(CPI)
(Year-on-Year) | (Per
cent) | Inflation | March | March | March | March | March | March | March | February |
Measure | 2000 | 2001 | 2002 | 2003 | 2004 | 2005 | 2006 | 2007 |
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | 8 | 9 |
WPI Inflation (end-Month) | 6.5 | 5.5 | 1.6 | 6.5 | 4.6 | 5.1 | 4.1 | 6.6+ |
CPI-IW | 4.8 | 2.5 | 5.2 | 4.1 | 3.5 | 4.2 | 4.9 | 6.9* |
CPI- UNME | 5.0 | 5.6 | 4.8 | 3.8 | 3.4 | 4.0 | 5.0 | 6.9*
| CPI-AL | 3.4 | -2.0 | 3.0 | 4.9 | 2.5 | 2.4 | 5.3 | 9.5$ |
CPI-RL | … | -1.6 | 3.0 | 4.8 | 2.5 | 2.4 | 5.3 | 8.9$ |
…: Not available. IW : Industrial
Workers UNME : Urban Non-Manual Employees AL : Agricultural Labourers; RL
: Rural Labourers; *: as in December 2006; +: as on February 10, 2007; $:
as in January 2007. Source: Annual Report and Handbook
of Statistics of Indian Economy, various issues, Reserve Bank of India. |
How did monetary policy support the growth momentum in the economy?
As inflation, along with inflation expectations, fell during the earlier period
of this decade, policy interest rates were also brought down. Consequently, both
nominal and real interest rates fell. The growth rate in interest expenses of
the corporates declined consistently since 1995-96, from 25.0 per cent to a negative
of 5.8 per cent in 2004-05 (Table 9). Such decline in interest
costs has significant implications for the improvement in bottom lines of the
corporates. Various indicators pertaining to interest costs, which can throw light
on the impact of interest costs on corporate sector profits have turned positive
in recent years.
Table
9: Monetary Policy and Corporate Performance: Interest Rate related Indicators |
Year | Growth
Rate in Interest Expenses (%) | Debt
Service to | Interest
Coverage Ratio# | Total
Uses of Funds Ratio* | 1990-91 | 16.2 | 22.4 | 1.9 |
1991-92 | 28.7 | 28.3 | 1.9 |
1992-93 | 21.6 | 24.4 | 1.6 |
1993-94 | 3.1 | 20.9 | 2.0 |
1994-95 | 8.1 | 27.2 | 2.4 |
1995-96 | 25.0 | 21.5 | 2.7 |
1996-97 | 25.7 | 18.7 | 2.1 |
1997-98 | 12.5 | 8.1 | 1.9 |
1998-99 | 11.1 | 17.6 | 1.6 |
1999-00 | 6.7 | 17.6 | 1.7 |
2000-01 | 7.1 | 14.0 | 1.7 |
2001-02 | -2.7 | 19.4 | 1.7 |
2002-03 | -11.2 | 8.9 | 2.3 |
2003-04 | -11.9 | 12.7 | 3.3 |
2004-05 | -5.8 | 21.8 | 4.6 |
Source: The data is based
on selected non-government non-financial public limited companies, collected by
RBI. | *: Represents
ratio of loans and advances plus interest accrued on loan to total uses of funds.
# Represents the ratio of gross profit (i.e., earning before interest and
taxes) to interest expenses. | V.
What is Needed to Improve Monetary Transmission? While the
changes in policy rates are quickly mirrored in the money market rates as well
as in Government bond yields, lending and deposits rates of banks exhibit a degree
of downward inflexibility. In this context, administered interest rates fixed
by the Government on a number of small saving schemes and provident funds are
of special relevance as they generally offer a rate higher than corresponding
instruments available in the market as well as tax incentives (RBI, 2001; RBI,
2004a). As banks have to compete for funds with small saving schemes, the rates
offered on long-term deposits mobilized by banks set the floor for lending rates
at a level higher than would have obtained under competitive market conditions
(Chart 7). In fact, this was observed to be a factor contributing to downward
stickiness of lending rates, with implications for the effectiveness of monetary
policy (Table 10). These
small savings schemes administered by the government through the wide reach of
post offices, and some through commercial banks, provide small savers access to
tax savings instruments that are seen as safe and stable. Benchmarking these administered
interest rates to market determined rates has been proposed from time to time.
Whereas some rationalisation in such schemes has taken place, further progress
in this direction will depend on the provision of better social security and pension
systems, and perhaps easier access to marketable sovereign instruments (Mohan,
2006c).
Table
10: Small Savings and Bank Deposits | (Amount
in Rupees billion) | | Average
Interest Rate on Small Savings (%) | Small
Savings Outstanding | Average
Interest Rate on Banks’ Term Deposits (%) | Bank
Term Deposits Outstanding | Small
Savings as % of Bank Deposits | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 |
1991-92 | 9.95 | 586 | 9.1 | 2,308 | 25.4 |
1992-93 | 9.48 | 609 | 9.6 | 2,686 | 22.7 |
1993-94 | 12.21 | 677 | 8.7 | 3,151 | 21.5 |
1994-95 | 13.20 | 833 | 7.0 | 3,869 | 21.5 |
1995-96 | 11.33 | 937 | 8.5 | 4,338 | 21.6 |
1996-97 | 13.03 | 1,061 | 9.4 | 5,056 | 21.0 |
1997-98 | 11.92 | 1,268 | 8.8 | 5,985 | 21.2 |
1998-99 | 10.34 | 1,553 | 8.9 | 7,140 | 21.7 |
1999-00 | 11.50 | 1,875 | 8.6 | 8,133 | 23.1 |
2000-01 | 11.60 | 2,251 | 8.1 | 8,201 | 27.4 |
2001-02 | 11.61 | 2,629 | 9.6 | 9,503 | 27.7 |
2002-03 | 11.56 | 3,138 | 8.7 | 10,809 | 29.0 |
2003-04 | 10.88 | 3,758 | 6.5 | 12,794 | 29.4 |
2004-05 | 9.37 | 4,577 | 6.2 | 14,487 | 31.6 |
2005-06 | 8.91 | 5,246 | | 17,444 | 30.1 |
Source: Annual Report
and Handbook of Statistics on the Indian Economy, various issues, Reserve
Bank of India. | In consonance with the objective of enhancing
efficiency and productivity of banks through greater competition – from
new private sector banks and entry and expansion of several foreign banks –
there has been a consistent decline in the share of public sector banks in total
assets of commercial banks. Notwithstanding such transformation, public sector
banks still account for over 70 per cent of assets and income of commercial banks.
While the public sector banks have responded well to the new challenges of competition,
this very public sector character does influence their operational flexibility
and decision making and hence, interferes, on occasions, with the transmission
of monetary policy impulses. Similar influence on monetary transmission is exerted
by the priority sector directives in terms of allocation of 40 per cent of credit
for specified sectors. The impact is, however, much limited now with the deregulation
of lending rates and the rationalization of the sectors for priority credit allocation.
VI. Summing up The brief survey of monetary
policy transmission in India suggests that monetary policy impulses impact output
and prices through interest rates and exchange rate movements in addition to the
traditional monetary and credit aggregates. It is necessary, however, to take
note of a few caveats. First, the transmission lags are surrounded by a great
deal of uncertainty. In view of the ongoing structural changes in the real sector
as well as financial innovations, the precise lags may differ in each business
cycle. Second, the period was also marked by heightened volatility in the international
economy, including developments such as the series of financial crises beginning
with the Asian crisis. Third, the period under study has been marked by sharp
reductions in customs duties and increasing trade openness which could have impacted
the transmission process. The 1990s were also witness to global disinflation.
Overall, the period has been one of substantial ongoing changes in various spheres
of the Indian economy as well as in its external environment. Fourth, the period
of study has been characterised by significant shifts in the monetary policy operating
framework from a monetary-targeting framework to a multiple indicator approach.
Fifth, the size of interest rate pass-through has increased in recent years, with
implications for transmission. Finally, empirical investigation is constrained
by the use of industrial production as a measure of output in the absence of a
reasonably long time series on quarterly GDP of the economy. In view of the significant
structural shifts towards the services sector and the inter-linkages between agriculture,
industry and services, the results of these empirical exercises should be considered
tentative and need to be ratified with a comprehensive measure of output, as also
by considering alternative techniques. On the whole, the Indian experience
highlights the need for emerging market economies to allow greater flexibility
in exchange rates but the authorities can also benefit from the capacity to intervene
in foreign exchange markets in view of the volatility observed in international
capital flows. Therefore, there is a need to maintain an adequate level of foreign
exchange reserves and this in turn both enables and constrains the conduct of
monetary policy. A key lesson is that flexibility and pragmatism are required
in the management of the exchange rate and monetary policy in developing countries
rather than adherence to strict theoretical rules. References Bernanke,
B. and M. Gertler (1995), ‘‘Inside the Black Box: the Credit Channel
of Monetary Policy Transmission’’, Journal of Economic Perspectives,
9 (4). Greenspan, A. (2005), Testimony before the Committee on Banking, Housing,
and Urban Affairs, US Senate, February 16. Mohan, Rakesh (2004), ‘‘Orderly
Global Economic Recovery: Are Exchange Rate Adjustments Effective Any More?’’,
Reserve Bank of India Bulletin, April. -------- (2005), ‘‘Communications
in Central Banks: A Perspective’’, Reserve Bank of India Bulletin,
October. -------- (2006a), "Coping with Liquidity Management in India:
Practitioner's View", Reserve Bank of India Bulletin, April.
-------- (2006b), "Evolution of Central Banking in India", Reserve
Bank of India Bulletin, June. -------- (2006c), "Monetary Policy
and Exchange Rate Frameworks: The Indian Experience", Reserve Bank of
India Bulletin, June. Nag, A. and A. Das (2002), ‘‘Credit
Growth and Response to Capital Requirements: Evidence from Indian Public Sector
Banks’’, Economic and Political Weekly, August 10. Pandit,
B.L., A. Mittal, M. Roy and S. Ghosh (2006), ‘‘Transmission of Monetary
Policy and the Bank Lending Channel: Analysis and Evidence for India’’,
Development Research Group Study No. 25, Reserve Bank of India. Poole, W.
(1970), ‘‘Optimal Choice of Monetary Policy Instrument in a Simple
Stochastic Macro Model’’, Quarterly Journal of Economics,
84 (2), May, 197-216. Reserve Bank of India (2001), Report of the Expert
Committee to Review the System of Administered Interest Rates and Other Related
Issues (Chairman: Y.V. Reddy), September. -------- (2002), Report
on Currency and Finance 2000-01, January, Mumbai. -------- (2004a),
Report of the Advisory Committee to Advise on the Administered Interest Rates
and Rationalisation of Saving Instruments (Chairman: Dr. Rakesh Mohan), RBI,
July. -------- (2004b), Report on Currency and Finance, 2003-04,
December. -------- (2006), Annual Policy Statement for 2006-07, April.
Reddy, Y.V. (2001), ‘‘Communications Policy of the Reserve Bank of
India’’, Reserve Bank of India Bulletin, September. --------
(2006), ‘‘Central Bank Communications: Some Random Thoughts’’,
Reserve Bank of India Bulletin, January.
Annex
I: Reforms in the Monetary Policy Framework Objectives
- Twin objectives of “maintaining price stability” and “ensuring
availability of adequate credit to productive sectors of the economy to support
growth” continue to govern the stance of monetary policy, though the relative
emphasis on these objectives has varied depending on the importance of maintaining
an appropriate balance.
- Reflecting the increasing development of financial
market and greater liberalisation, use of broad money as an intermediate target
has been de-emphasised and a multiple indicator approach has been adopted.
- Emphasis
has been put on development of multiple instruments to transmit liquidity and
interest rate signals in the short-term in a flexible and bi-directional manner.
- Increase
of the interlinkage between various segments of the financial market including
money, government security and forex markets.
Instruments
- Move from direct instruments (such as, administered interest rates, reserve
requirements, selective credit control) to indirect instruments (such as, open
market operations, purchase and repurchase of government securities) for the conduct
of monetary policy.
- Introduction of Liquidity Adjustment Facility (LAF),
which operates through repo and reverse repo auctions, effectively provide a corridor
for short-term interest rate. LAF has emerged as the tool for both liquidity management
and also as a signalling devise for interest rate in the overnight market.
- Use
of open market operations to deal with overall market liquidity situation especially
those emanating from capital flows.
- Introduction of Market Stabilisation
Scheme (MSS) as an additional instrument to deal with enduring capital inflows
without affecting short-term liquidity management role of LAF.
Developmental
Measures - Discontinuation of automatic monetisation through
an agreement between the Government and the Reserve Bank. Rationalisation of Treasury
Bill market. Introduction of delivery versus payment system and deepening of inter-bank
repo market.
- Introduction of Primary Dealers in the government securities
market to play the role of market maker.
- Amendment of Securities Contracts
Regulation Act (SCRA), to create the regulatory framework.
- Deepening of
government securities market by making the interest rates on such securities market
related. Introduction of auction of government securities. Development of a risk-free
credible yield curve in the government securities market as a benchmark for related
markets.
- Development of pure inter-bank call money market. Non-bank participants
to participate in other money market instruments.
- Introduction of automated
screen-based trading in government securities through Negotiated Dealing System
(NDS). Setting up of risk-free payments and system in government securities through
Clearing Corporation of India Limited (CCIL). Phased introduction of Real Time
Gross Settlement (RTGS) System.
- Deepening of forex market and increased
autonomy of Authorised Dealers.
Institutional Measures
- Setting up of Technical Advisory Committee on Monetary Policy with outside
experts to review macroeconomic and monetary developments and advise the Reserve
Bank on the stance of monetary policy.
- Creation of a separate Financial
Market Department within the RBI.
|
Annex
II: Money Market Instruments for Liquidity Management The Reserve
Bank has been making efforts to develop a repo market outside the LAF for bank
and non-bank participants, so as to provide a stable collateralised funding alternative
with a view to promoting smooth transformation of the call/notice money market
into a pure inter-bank market and for deepening the underlying Government securities
market. Thus, the following new instruments have been introduced.
Collateralised Borrowing and Lending Obligation (CBLO)
- Developed by the Clearing Corporation of India Limited (CCIL) and introduced
on January 20, 2003, it is a discounted instrument available in electronic book
entry form for the maturity period ranging from one day to ninety days (can be
made available up to one year as per RBI guidelines).
- In order to enable
the market participants to borrow and lend funds, CCIL provides the Dealing System
through Indian Financial Network (INFINET), a closed user group to the Members
of the Negotiated Dealing System (NDS) who maintain Current account with RBI and
through Internet for other entities who do not maintain Current account with RBI.
- Membership
(including Associate Membership) of CBLO segment is extended to banks, financial
institutions, insurance companies, mutual funds, primary dealers, NBFCs, non-Government
Provident Funds, Corporates, etc.
- Eligible securities are Central Government
securities including Treasury Bills.
- Borrowing limits for members is
fixed by CCIL at the beginning of the day taking into account the securities deposited
by borrowers in their CSGL account with CCIL. The securities are subjected to
necessary hair-cut after marking them to market.
- Auction market is available
only to NDS Members for overnight borrowing and settlement on T+0 basis. At the
end of the Auction market session, CCIL initiates auction matching process based
on Uniform Yield principle.
- CCIL assumes the role of the central
counter party through the process of novation and guarantees settlement of transactions
in CBLO.
- Automated value-free transfer of securities between market participants
and the CCIL was introduced during 2004-05.
- Members can reckon unencumbered
securities for SLR calculations.
- The operations in CBLO are exempted from
cash reserve requirement (CRR).
Market Repo
- To broaden the repo market, the Reserve Bank enabled non-banking financial
companies, mutual funds, housing finance companies and insurance companies not
holding SGL accounts to undertake repo transactions with effect from March 3,
2003. These entities were permitted to access the repo market through their ‘gilt
accounts’ maintained with the custodians.
- Subsequently, non-scheduled
urban co-operative banks and listed companies with gilt accounts with scheduled
commercial banks were allowed to participate.
- Necessary precautions were
built into the system to ensure ‘delivery versus payment’
(DvP) and transparency, while restricting the repos to Government securities
only.
- Rollover of repo transactions in Government securities was facilitated
with the enabling of DvP III mode of settlement in Government securities
which involves settlement of securities and funds on a net basis, effective April
2, 2004. This provided significant flexibility to market participants in managing
their collateral.
Some Assessments
- CBLO and market repo helped in aligning short-term money market rates to the
LAF corridor.
- Mutual funds and insurance companies are generally the main
supplier of funds while banks, primary dealers and corporates are the major borrowers
in the repo market outside the LAF.
|
Annex III: Reforms in the Government
Securities Market Institutional Measures - Administered
interest rates on government securities were replaced by an auction system for
price discovery.
- Automatic monetisation of fiscal deficit through the
issue of ad hoc Treasury Bills was phased out.
- Primary Dealers
(PD) were introduced as market makers in the government securities market.
- For
ensuring transparency in the trading of government securities, Delivery versus
Payment (DvP) settlement system was introduced.
- Repurchase agreement
(repo) was introduced as a tool of short-term liquidity adjustment. Subsequently,
the Liquidity Adjustment Facility (LAF) was introduced.
- LAF operates through
repo and reverse repo auctions and provide a corridor for short-term interest
rate. LAF has emerged as the tool for both liquidity management and also signalling
device for interest rates in the overnight market. The Second LAF (SLAF) was introduced
in November 2005.
- Market Stabilisation Scheme (MSS) has been introduced,
which has expanded the instruments available to the Reserve Bank for managing
the enduring surplus liquidity in the system.
- Effective April 1, 2006,
RBI has withdrawn from participating in primary market auctions of Government
paper.
- Banks have been permitted to undertake primary dealer business
while primary dealers are being allowed to diversify their business.
- Short
sales in Government securities is being permitted in a calibrated manner while
guidelines for ‘when issued’ market have been issued recently.
Increase in Instruments in the Government Securities Market
- 91-day Treasury bill was introduced for managing liquidity
and benchmarking. Zero Coupon Bonds, Floating Rate Bonds, Capital Indexed Bonds
were issued and exchange traded interest rate futures were introduced. OTC interest
rate derivatives like IRS/ FRAs were introduced.
- Outright sale of Central
Government dated security that are not owned have been permitted, subject to the
same being covered by outright purchase from the secondary market within the same
trading day subject to certain conditions.
- Repo status has been granted
to State Government securities in order to improve secondary market liquidity.
- Foreign
Institutional Investors (FIIs) were allowed to invest in government securities
subject to certain limits.
- Introduction of automated screen-based trading
in government securities through Negotiated Dealing System (NDS).
- Setting
up of risk-free payments and settlement system in government securities through
Clearing Corporation of India Limited (CCIL).
- Phased introduction of
Real Time Gross Settlement System (RTGS).
- Introduction of trading in government securities on stock exchanges for promoting
retailing in such securities, permitting non-banks to participate in repo market.
- Recent
measures include introduction of NDS-OM and T+1 settlement norms.
Annex IV: Reforms
in the Foreign Exchange Market Exchange Rate Regime
- Evolution of exchange rate regime from a single-currency fixed-exchange rate
system to fixing the value of rupee against a basket of currencies and further
to market-determined floating exchange rate regime.
- Adoption of convertibility
of rupee for current account transactions with acceptance of Article VIII of the
Articles of Agreement of the IMF. De facto full capital account convertibility
for non residents and calibrated liberalisation of transactions undertaken for
capital account purposes in the case of residents.
Institutional
Framework - Replacement of the earlier Foreign
Exchange Regulation Act (FERA), 1973 by the market friendly Foreign Exchange Management
Act, 1999. Delegation of considerable powers by RBI to Authorised Dealers
to release foreign exchange for a variety of purposes.
Increase
in Instruments in the Foreign Exchange Market - Development
of rupee-foreign currency swap market.
- Introduction of additional hedging
instruments, such as, foreign currency-rupee options. Authorised dealers permitted
to use innovative products like cross-currency options, interest rate swaps (IRS)
and currency swaps, caps/collars and forward rate agreements (FRAs) in the international
forex market.
Liberalisation Measures - Authorised
dealers permitted to initiate trading positions, borrow and invest in overseas
market subject to certain specifications and ratification by respective Banks’
Boards. Banks are also permitted to fix interest rates on non-resident deposits,
subject to certain specifications, use derivative products for asset-liability
management and fix overnight open position limits and gap limits in the foreign
exchange market, subject to ratification by RBI.
- Permission to various
participants in the foreign exchange market, including exporters, Indians investing
abroad, FIIs, to avail forward cover and enter into swap transactions without
any limit subject to genuine underlying exposure.
- FIIs and NRIs permitted
to trade in exchange-traded derivative contracts subject to certain conditions.
- Foreign
exchange earners permitted to retain up to 100 per cent of their foreign exchange
earnings in their Exchange Earners’ Foreign Currency accounts. Residents
are permitted to remit up to US $ 50, 000 per financial year.
- Authorised
dealer banks may borrow funds from their overseas branches and correspondent banks
(including borrowing for export credit, external commercial borrowings (ECBs)
and overdrafts from their Head Office/Nostro account) up to a limit of 50 per
cent of their unimpaired Tier I capital or US $ 10 million, whichever is higher.
- Borrowers
eligible for accessing ECBs can avail of an additional US $ 250 million with average
maturity of more than 10 years under the approval route. Prepayment of ECB up
to US $ 300 million without prior approval of the Reserve Bank.
- The existing
limit of US $ 2 billion on investments in Government securities by foreign institutional
investors (FIIs) to be enhanced in phases to US $ 3.2 billion by March 31, 2007.
- The
extant ceiling of overseas investment by mutual funds of US $ 2 billion is enhanced
to US $ 3 billion.
- Importers to be permitted to book forward contracts
for their customs duty component of imports.
- FIIs to be allowed to rebook
a part of the cancelled forward contracts.
- Forward contracts booked by
exporters and importers in excess of 50 per cent of the eligible limit to be on
deliverable basis and cannot be cancelled.
- Authorised dealer banks to
be permitted to issue guarantees/letters of credit for import of services up to
US $ 100,000 for securing a direct contractual liability arising out of a contract
between a resident and a non-resident.
- Lock-in period for sale proceeds
of the immovable property credited to the NRO account to be eliminated, provided
the amount being remitted in any financial year does not exceed US $ one million.
Annex
V: Reforms in the Banking Sector Competition Enhancing
Measures - Granting of operational autonomy to public sector
banks, reduction of public ownership in public sector banks by allowing them to
raise capital from equity market up to 49 per cent of paid-up capital.
- Transparent
norms for entry of Indian private sector, foreign and joint-venture banks and
insurance companies, permission for foreign investment in the financial sector
in the form of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) as well as portfolio investment,
permission to banks to diversify product portfolio and business activities.
- Roadmap
for presence of foreign banks and guidelines for mergers and amalgamation of private
sector banks and banks and NBFCs.
- Guidelines on ownership and governance
in private sector banks.
Measures Enhancing Role of Market
Forces - Sharp reduction in pre-emption through reserve requirement,
market determined pricing for government securities, disbanding of administered
interest rates with a few exceptions and enhanced transparency and disclosure
norms to facilitate market discipline.
- Introduction of pure inter-bank
call money market, auction-based repos-reverse repos for short-term liquidity
management, facilitation of improved payments and settlement mechanism.
- Significant
advancement in dematerialisation and markets for securitised assets are being
developed.
Prudential Measures - Introduction
and phased implementation of international best practices and norms on risk-weighted
capital adequacy requirement, accounting, income recognition, provisioning and
exposure.
- Measures to strengthen risk management through recognition
of different components of risk, assignment of risk-weights to various asset classes,
norms on connected lending, risk concentration, application of marked-to-market
principle for investment portfolio and limits on deployment of fund in sensitive
activities.
- 'Know Your Customer' and 'Anti Money Laundering' guidelines,
roadmap for Basel II, introduction of capital charge for market risk, higher graded
provisioning for NPAs, guidelines for ownership and governance, securitisation
and debt restructuring mechanisms norms, etc.
Institutional
and Legal Measures - Setting up of Lok Adalats (people’s
courts), debt recovery tribunals, asset reconstruction companies, settlement advisory
committees, corporate debt restructuring mechanism, etc. for quicker
recovery/ restructuring.
- Promulgation of Securitisation and Reconstruction
of Financial Assets and Enforcement of Securities Interest (SARFAESI) Act, 2002
and its subsequent amendment to ensure creditor rights.
- Setting up of
Credit Information Bureau of India Limited (CIBIL) for information sharing on
defaulters as also other borrowers.
- Setting up of Clearing Corporation
of India Limited (CCIL) to act as central counter party for facilitating payments
and settlement system relating to fixed income securities and money market instruments.
Supervisory Measures - Establishment of
the Board for Financial Supervision as the apex supervisory authority for commercial
banks, financial institutions and non-banking financial companies.
- Introduction
of CAMELS supervisory rating system, move towards risk-based supervision, consolidated
supervision of financial conglomerates, strengthening of off-site surveillance
through control returns.
- Recasting of the role of statutory auditors,
increased internal control through strengthening of internal audit.
- Strengthening
corporate governance, enhanced due diligence on important shareholders, fit and
proper tests for directors.
Technology Related Measures
- Setting up of INFINET as the communication backbone for the financial sector,
introduction of Negotiated Dealing System (NDS) for screen-based trading in government
securities and Real Time Gross Settlement (RTGS) System.
|
Annex
VI: Liquidity Adjustment Facility - As part of the financial
sector reforms launched in mid-1991, India began to move away from direct instruments
of monetary control to indirect ones. The transition of this kind involves considerable
efforts to develop markets, institutions and practices. In order to facilitate
such transition, India developed a Liquidity Adjustment Facility (LAF) in phases
considering country-specific features of the Indian financial system. LAF is based
on repo / reverse repo operations by the central bank.
- In 1998 the Committee
on Banking Sector Reforms (Narasimham Committee II) recommended the introduction
of a Liquidity Adjustment Facility (LAF) under which the Reserve Bank would conduct
auctions periodically, if not necessarily daily. The Reserve Bank could reset
its Repo and Reverse Repo rates which would in a sense provide a reasonable corridor
for the call money market. In pursuance of these recommendations, a major change
in the operating procedure became possible in April 1999 through the introduction
of an Interim Liquidity Adjustment Facility (ILAF) under which repos and reverse
repos were formalised. With the introduction of ILAF, the general refinance facility
was withdrawn and replaced by a collateralised lending facility (CLF) up to 0.25
per cent of the fortnightly average outstanding of aggregate deposits in 1997-98
for two weeks at the Bank Rate. Additional collateralised lending facility (ACLF)
for an equivalent amount of CLF was made available at the Bank Rate plus 2 per
cent. CLF and ACLF availed for periods beyond two weeks were subjected to a penal
rate of 2 per cent for an additional two week period. Export Credit refinance
for scheduled commercial banks was retained and continued to be provided at the
bank rate. Liquidity support to PDs against collateral of government securities
at the bank rate was also provided for. ILAF was expected to promote stability
of money market and ensure that the interest rates move within a reasonable range.
- The
transition from ILAF to a full-fledged LAF began in June 2000 and was undertaken
in three stages. In the first stage, beginning June 5, 2000, LAF was formally
introduced and the Additional CLF and level II support to PDs was replaced by
variable rate repo auctions with same day settlement. In the second stage, beginning
May 2001 CLF and level I liquidity support for banks and PDs was also replaced
by variable rate repo auctions. Some minimum liquidity support to PDs was continued
but at interest rate linked to variable rate in the daily repos auctions as determined
by RBI from time to time. In April 2003, the multiplicity of rates at which liquidity
was being absorbed/injected under back-stop facility was rationalised and the
back-stop interest rate was fixed at the reverse repo cut-off rate at the regular
LAF auctions on that day. In case of no reverse repo in the LAF auctions, back-stop
rate was fixed at 2.0 percentage point above the repo cut-off rate. It was also
announced that on days when no repo/reverse repo bids are received/accepted, back-stop
rate would be decided by the Reserve Bank on an ad-hoc basis. A revised
LAF scheme was operationalised effective March 29, 2004 under which the reverse
repo rate was reduced to 6.0 per cent and aligned with bank rate. Normal facility
and backstop facility was merged into a single facility and made available at
a single rate. The third stage of full-fledged LAF had begun with the full computerisation
of Public Debt Office (PDO) and introduction of RTGS marked a big step forward
in this phase. Repo operations today are mainly through electronic transfers.
Fixed rate auctions have been reintroduced since April 2004. The possibility of
operating LAF at different times of the same day is now close to getting materialised.
In that sense we have very nearly completed the transition to operating a full-fledged
LAF.
- With the introduction of Second LAF (SLAF) from November 28, 2005
market participants now have a second window to fine-tune the management of liquidity.
In past, LAF operations were conducted in the forenoon between 9.30 a.m. and 10.30
a.m. SLAF is conducted by receiving bids between 3.00 p.m. and 3.45 p.m. The salient
features of SLAF are the same as those of LAF and the settlement for both is conducted
separately and on gross basis. The introduction of LAF has been a process and
the Indian experience shows that phased rather than a big bang approach is required
for reforms in the financial sector and in monetary management.
References:
Reserve Bank of India (1999), Repurchase Agreements (Repos): Report of the
Sub-group of the Technical Advisory Committee on Government Securities Market,
April, 1999, Mumbai. ----- (2003), Report of the Internal Group on Liquidity
Adjustment Facility, December 2003, Mumbai. |
Annex
VII: Market Stabilisation Scheme (MSS) - The money markets
operated in liquidity surplus mode since 2002 due to large capital inflows and
current account surplus. The initial burden of sterilisation was borne by the
outright transaction of dated securities and T-bills. However, due to the depletion
in stock of government securities, the burden of liquidity adjustment shifted
on LAF, which is essentially a tool of adjusting for marginal liquidity. Keeping
in view the objective of absorbing the liquidity of enduring nature using instruments
other than LAF, the Reserve Bank appointed a Working Group on Instruments of Sterilisation
(Chairperson: Smt Usha Thorat). The Group recommended issue of T-bills and dated
securities under Market Stabilisation Scheme (MSS) where the proceeds of MSS were
to be held by the Government in a separate identifiable cash account maintained
and operated by RBI. The amounts credited into the MSS Account would be appropriated
only for the purpose of redemption and / or buy back of the Treasury Bills and
/ or dated securities issued under the MSS. In pursuance of the recommendation
the Government of India and RBI signed a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) on
March 25, 2004. As part of the MoU, the scheme was made operational since April
2004. It was agreed that the Government would issue Treasury Bills and/or dated
securities under the MSS in addition to the normal borrowing requirements, for
absorbing liquidity from the system. These securities would be issued by way of
auctions by the Reserve Bank and the instruments would have all the attributes
of existing T-bills and dated securities. They were to be serviced like any other
marketable government securities. MSS securities are being treated as eligible
securities for Statutory Liquidity Ratio (SLR), repo and Liquidity Adjustment
Facility (LAF).
- The proceeds of the MSS are held by the Government in
a separate identifiable cash account maintained and operated by the Reserve Bank.
The amount held in this account is appropriated only for the purpose of redemption
and/or buyback of the Treasury Bills and/or dated securities issued under the
MSS. The payments for interest and discount on MSS securities are not made from
the MSS Account. The receipts due to premium and/or accrued interest are also
not credited to the MSS Account. Such receipts and payments towards interest,
premium and discount are shown in the budget and other related documents as distinct
components under separate sub-heads. Thus, they only have a marginal impact on
revenue and fiscal balances of the Government to the extent of interest payment
on the outstanding under the MSS.
- For mopping up enduring surplus liquidity,
policy choice exist between central bank issuing its own securities or government
issuing additional securities. A large number of countries, such as, Chile, China,
Colombia, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Peru, Philippines, Russia, Sri Lanka, Tawian
and Thailand have issued central bank securities. However, central banks of many
of these countries faced deterioration in their balance sheets. As such, there
are merits in issuing sterilisation bonds on government account. This is more
so, in case of an already well established government debt market, where issuing
of new central bank bills of overlapping maturity could cause considerable confusion
and possible market segmentation which could obfuscate the yield curve, reduce
liquidity of the instruments and make operations that much more difficult.
- MSS
has considerably strengthened the Reserve Bank's ability to conduct exchange rate
and monetary management operations. It has allowed absorption of surplus liquidity
by instruments of short term (91-day, 182-day and 364-day T-bills) and the medium-term
(dated Government securities) maturity. Generally, the preference has been for
the short-term instruments. This has given the monetary authorities a greater
degree of freedom in liquidity management during transitions in liquidity situation.
Reference:
Reserve Bank of India (2003), Report of the Working Group on Instruments of
Sterlisation, Mumbai, December. |
Annex
VIII: Liquidity Management during IMD Redemption - The India
Millennium Deposits (IMDs) were foreign currency denominated deposits issued by
State Bank of India in 2000, on advice of the Government of India. It mobilised
a sum of USD 5.5 billion for a tenor of five years. IMD carried coupons of 8.50
per cent, 7.85 per cent and 6.85 per cent on US dollar, Pound Sterling and Euro
denominated deposits respectively. IMD subscription was limited to non-resident
Indians, persons of Indian origin and overseas corporate bodies. The interest
income earned on IMD was exempted from tax and there was provision of premature
encashment after six months only in non-repatriable Indian rupees. These IMDs
matured on December 28-29, 2005 and the large sums involved threw a challange
for liquidity management.
- Liquidity management in face of IMD redemptions
was carried out to contain disequilibrium while retaining monetary policy stance
with a medium-term objective. Outflows on account of the redemptions were met
by smooth arrangements worked out in this regard. During December 27-29, 2005,
RBI sold foreign exchange out of its foreign exchange reserves to State Bank of
India (SBI) totaling nearly US$ 7.1 billion, which in rupee equivalent terms was
about Rs.32,000 crore. SBI on its part had built up the necessary rupee resources
to meet the obligations. Temporary tightness in liquidity, was met by release
of liquidity through repo window (including the second LAF) averaging about Rs.23,000
crore per day in the last week of December coinciding with the IMD redemptions,
outflows due to advance tax payments and the continued surge in credit offtake.
The second LAF window made available since November 28, 2005 provided an additional
opportunity to market participants to fine tune their liquidity management. The
smooth redemption of the IMD liability of this size, bunched at a point of time,
reflects the growing maturity of the financial markets and the strength of the
liquidity management system that has been put in place. Short-term money market
rates eased remarkably in the first week of January 2006 reflecting smooth redemptions
of IMDs but again firmed up in the second week reflecting pressures emanating
from scheduled auctions of Government securities.
Source:
Mohan (2006a) |
Annex
IX: Prudential guidelines impacting monetary transmission in
India The Reserve Bank has issued several prudential capital requirement
and supervisory guidelines which could have impact on the transmission of monetary
policy in India. These include, inter alia: - For ensuring
smooth transition to Basel II norms, banks were required to maintain capital charge
for market risk on their trading book exposures (including derivatives) by March
31, 2005 and on the securities included under Available for Sale category by March
31, 2006.
- Banks in India have been advised to adopt the Standardised Approach
for credit risk and Basic Indicator Approach for operational risk under the New
Capital Adequacy Framework with effect from March 31, 2008.
- Effective
from March 31, 2002, banks were permitted to have single or group borrower credit
exposure up to 15 per cent and 40 per cent of their capital funds (Tier I and
Tier II capital) with an additional allowance of 5 per cent and 10 per cent of
their capital funds for infrastructure sector. In May 2004 banks were permitted
to consider enhancement of their exposure to the borrower up to a further 5 per
cent of capital funds, subject to the banks making disclosure in their annual
reports.
- Banks' aggregate exposure to the capital market was restricted
to 40 per cent of their net worth on a solo and consolidated basis. The consolidated
direct capital market exposure was restricted to 20 per cent of the banks’
consolidated net worth.
- The RBI issued a 'Guidance Note on Management
of Operational Risk' in October 2005 to enable the banks to have a smooth transition
to the New Capital Adequacy Framework. Banks using the Basic Indicator Approach
were encouraged to comply with 'Sound Practices for the Management and Supervision
of Operational Risk' issued by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision in February
2003.
- In order to encourage banks for early compliance with the guidelines
for maintenance of capital charge for market risks, banks were advised in April
2005 that such banks which have maintained capital of at least 9 per cent of the
risk weighted assets for both credit risk and market risks for both Held For Trading
(HFT) and Available For Sale (AFS) category may treat the balance in excess of
5 per cent of securities included under HFT and AFS categories, in the Investment
Fluctuation Reserves (IFR), as Tier I capital.
- In view of strong growth
of housing and consumer credit, risk containment measures were put in place and
the risk weights were increased in October 2004 from 50 per cent to 75 per cent
in the case of housing loans and from 100 per cent to 125 per cent in the case
of consumer credit including personal loans and credit cards. The risk weight
on banks' exposure to commercial real estate was increased from 100 per cent to
125 per cent in July 2005 and further to 150 per cent in April 2006.
- It
was decided in April 2006 that bank’s total exposure to venture capital
funds will form a part of their capital market exposure and banks should, henceforth,
assign a higher risk weight of 150 per cent to these exposures.
- Taking
into account the trends in credit growth, the general provisioning requirement
for ‘standard advances’ was increased in October 2005 from 0.25 per
cent to 0.40 per cent. Banks’ direct advances to agricultural and SME sectors
were exempted from the additional provisioning requirement. In April 2006, the
RBI further increased the general provisioning requirement on standard advances
in specific sectors, i.e., personal loans, loans and advances qualifying
as capital market exposures, residential housing loans beyond Rs.20 lakh and commercial
real estate loans from the existing level of 0.40 per cent to 1.0 per cent. These
provisions are eligible for inclusion in Tier II capital for capital adequacy
purposes up to the permitted extent.
- Having regard to the trends in the
credit markets, a supervisory review process was initiated with select banks
having significant exposure to some sectors, namely, real estate, highly leveraged
NBFCs, venture capital funds and capital markets, in order to ensure that effective
risk mitigates and sound internal controls are in place for managing such exposures.
- In
October 2005, the RBI restricted banks' aggregate exposure to the capital market
to 40 per cent of their net worth on a solo and consolidated basis. The consolidated
direct capital market exposure has been restricted to 20 per cent of the banks’
consolidated net worth.
- In January 2007, provisioning requirement was
increased to two per cent for standard assets in the real estate sector, outstanding
credit card receivables, loans and advances qualifying as capital market exposure
and personal loans (excluding residential housing loans); provisioning requirement
was also increased to two per cent for the banks’ exposures in the standard
assets category to the non-deposit taking systemically important non-banking financial
companies (NBFCs); risk weight was increased to 125 per cent for banks’
exposure to the non-deposit taking systemically important NBFCs.
|
Annex
X: The Evolving Stance of Monetary Policy in India Highlights
- The statement on the stance of the monetary policy was introduced from the
policy statement of April 1996.
- The emphasis on price
stability and provision of credit to support growth has since run through the
statements on stance.
- Exchange rate stability was underlined
in the stance of April 1996.
- The pursuit of financial
reforms, accelerated investment, improvement in credit delivery mechanisms particularly
for agriculture and small and medium sectors, soft interest rate regime, interest
rate signaling and liquidity management found place for the first time in the
stance of April 1998.
- The role of active debt management
was emphasized in the stance of April 1999.
- Ensuring
financial stability came to be recognized from the stance of October 1999.
- Macroeconomic
stability was emphasized in the stance of April 2004.
- The
need for support to export demand, stabilization of inflation expectations and
calibrated actions was underlined in the stance of October 2004.
- Prompt
and effective response to the evolving situation was underlined in the stance
of July 2005.
- The aspect of credit quality was emphasized
in the stance of January 2006.
- Swift response to evolving
global developments was promised in the stance of April 2006.
- Financial
inclusion was emphasized, for the first time, in the stance of January 2007.
| Details |
Year | Annual
Policy | Mid
Term Review | 1996-97 | Credit
support to sustain growth and a reasonable degree of price and exchange rate stability. | Price
stability and adequate supply of bank credit to the productive sectors of the
economy. | 1997-98 | Maintaining
reasonable price stability and ensuring availability of adequate bank credit to
support the growth of the real sector. | Promoting
price stability and ensuring availability of adequate bank credit to meet the
requirements of productive sectors of the economy. | 1998-99 | Need
to accelerate industrial investment and output in the economy; maintenance of
low rates of inflation; continued pursuit of financial reform; reduction in interest
srates; and improvement in credit delivery mechanisms, particularly for agriculture
and medium and small sectors. | Flexible
use of interest rate instruments to signal RBI’s stance regarding monetary
conditions and management of the flow of liquidity in the system. |
1999-00 | Provision
of reasonable liquidity; stable interest rates with policy preference for softening
to the extent circumstances permit; active debt-management; orderly development
of financial markets; and further steps in financial sector reforms. | Provision
of reasonable liquidity; stable interest rates with preference for softening to
the extent possible within the existing operational and structural constraints;
orderly development of financial markets and ensuring financial stability.
| 2000-01 | Continue
the current stance of monetary policy and ensure that all legitimate requirements
for bank credit are met while guarding against any emergence of inflationary pressures
due to excess demand. | |
2001-02 | Provision
of adequate liquidity to meet credit growth and support revival of investment
demand while continuing a vigil on movements in the price level. Within
the overall framework of imparting greater flexibility to the interest rate regime
in the medium-term, to continue the present stable interest rate environment with
a preference for softening to the extent the evolving situation warrants. | |
2002-03 | Provision
of adequate liquidity to meet credit growth and support revival of investment
demand while continuing a vigil on movements in the price level. Within
the overall framework of imparting greater flexibility to the interest rate regime
in the medium-term, to continue the present stable interest rate environment with
a preference for softening to the extent the evolving situation warrants. | Same
as outlined in Annual Policy of April 2002. | 2003-04 | Provision
of adequate liquidity to meet credit growth and support investment demand in the
economy while continuing a vigil on movements in the price level. In line
with the above, to continue the present stance on interest rates including preference
for soft interest rates. To impart greater flexibility to the interest rate
structure in the medium-term. | Same as
outlined in Annual Policy of April 2003. | 2004-05 | Provision
of adequate liquidity to meet credit growth and support investment demand in the
economy while continuing a vigil on movements in the price level. In line
with the above, to continue with the present stance of preference for a soft and
flexible interest rate environment within the framework of macroeconomic stability. | Provision
of appropriate liquidity to meet credit growth and support investment and export
demand in the economy while placing equal emphasis on price stability. Consistent
with the above, to pursue an interest rate environment that is conducive to macroeconomic
and price stability, and maintaining the momentum of growth. To consider
measures in a calibrated manner, in response to evolving circumstances with a
view to stabilising inflationary expectations. | Year
| Annual Policy | First
Quarter Review | Mid Term
Review | Third Quarter
Review | 2005-06 | Provision
of appropriate liquidity to meet credit growth and support investment and export
demand in the economy while placing equal emphasis on price stability. Consistent
with the above, to pursue an interest rate environment that is conducive to macroeconomic
and price stability, and maintaining the momentum of growth. To consider
measures in a calibrated manner, in response to evolving circumstances with a
view to stabilising inflationary expectations. | Same
stance for the remaining part of the year as set out in the annual policy Statement
of April 2005, but the Reserve Bank would respond, promptly and effectively, to
the evolving situation depending on the unfolding of the risks. | Consistent
with emphasis on price stability, provision of appropriate liquidity to meet genuine
credit needs and support export and investment demand in the economy. Ensuring
an interest rate environment that is conducive to macroeconomic and price stability,
and maintaining the growth momentum. To consider measures in a calibrated
and prompt manner, in response to evolving circumstances with a view to stabilising
inflationary expectations. | To maintain
the emphasis on price stability with a view to anchoring inflationary expectations. To
continue to support export and investment demand in the economy for maintaining
the growth momentum by ensuring a conducive interest rate environment for macroeconomic,
price and financial stability. To provide appropriate liquidity to meet
genuine credit needs of the economy with due emphasis on quality. To consider
responses as appropriate to evolving circumstances. | 2006-07 | To
ensure a monetary and interest rate environment that enables continuation of the
growth momentum consistent with price stability while being in readiness to act
in a timely and prompt manner on any signs of evolving circumstances impinging
on inflation expectations. To focus on credit quality and financial market
conditions to support export and investment demand in the economy for maintaining
macroeconomic, in particular, financial stability. To respond swiftly to
evolving global developments. | To ensure
a monetary and interest rate environment that enables continuation of the growth
momentum while emphasizing price stability with a view to anchoring inflation
expectations. To reinforce the focus on credit quality and financial market
conditions to support export and investment demand in the economy for maintaining
macroeconomic and, in particular, financial stability. To consider measures
as appropriate to the evolving global and domestic circumstances impinging on
inflation expectations and the growth momentum. | To
ensure a monetary and interest rate environment that supports export and investment
demand in the economy so as to enable continuation of the growth momentum while
reinforcing price stability with a view to anchoring inflation expectations. To
maintain the emphasis on macroeconomic and, in particular, financial stability. To
consider promptly all possible measures as appropriate to the evolving global
and domestic situation. | To reinforce the
emphasis on price stability and well anchored inflation expectations while ensuring
a monetary and interest rate environment that supports export and investment demand
in the economy so as to enable continuation of the growth momentum. To re-emphasise
credit quality and orderly conditions in financial markets for securing macroeconomic
and, in particular, financial stability while simultaneously pursuing greater
credit penetration and financial inclusion. To respond swiftly with all possible
measures as appropriate to the evolving global and domestic situation impinging
on inflation expectations and the growth momentum. |
Illustratively, the Reserve Bank in its Annual Policy Statement
for 2006-07 (April 2006) stressed that: “Domestic macroeconomic and financial
conditions support prospects of sustained growth momentum with stability in India.
It is important to recognise, however, that there are risks to both growth and
stability from domestic as well as global factors. At the current juncture, the
balance of risks is tilted towards the global factors. The adverse consequences
of further escalation of international crude prices and/or of disruptive unwinding
of global imbalances are likely to be pervasive across economies, including India.
Moreover, in a situation of generalised tightening of monetary policy, India cannot
afford to stay out of step. It is necessary, therefore, to keep in view the dominance
of domestic factors as in the past but to assign more weight to global factors
than before while formulating the policy stance” (RBI, 2006).
From October 18, 1994, banks have been free to fix the lending
rates for loans above Rupees 2,00,000. Banks were required to obtain the approval
of their respective Boards for the PLR which would be the minimum rate charged
for loans above Rupees 2,00,000. In the interest of small borrowers as also to
remove the disincentive for credit flow to such borrowers, PLR was converted into
a ceiling rate for loans up to Rupees 2,00,000 in 1998-99. Sub-PLR lending was
allowed in 2001-02 in keeping with international practice. For customers’
protection and meaningful competition, bank-wise quarterly data on PLR, and maximum
and minimum lending rates have been placed at the Reserve Bank’s website,
starting from June 2002. Towards greater transparency in loan pricing in the context
of sticky behaviour of lending rates, the system of BPLR (i.e., benchmark PLR)
was introduced in 2003-04. Banks were advised to specify their BPLR taking into
account (a) actual cost of funds, (b) operating expenses and (c) a minimum margin
to cover regulatory requirements of provisioning and capital charge, and profit
margin. Whereas, conceptually the BPLR should turn out to be a median lending
rate in practice, the specification of BPLR by banks has turned out to be sticky.
Movements in the actual interest rate charged take place less transparently through
changes in the proportion of loans above or below the announced BPLR. The share
of sub-BPLR lending has, in recent times, increased to over 75 per cent reflecting
the overall decline in interest rates, until recently. This has undermined the
role of BPLR as a reference rate, complicating the judgment on monetary transmission
in regard to lending rates.
1Paper
presented by Dr. Rakesh Mohan, Deputy Governor, Reserve Bank of India, at the
Deputy Governor's Meeting on 'Transmission Mechanisms for Monetary Policy in Emerging
Market Economies - What is New?' at Bank for International Settlements, Basel
on December 7-8, 2006. Assistance of Michael D. Patra and Sanjay Hansda in preparing
this paper is gratefully acknowledged. |