The assessment of the medium-term outlook for fiscal-monetary policy co-ordination is based on the estimation of
a linear relationship between the call rate (which is the operating target of monetary policy and can be generally
used as a proxy for the monetary policy rate) and the output gap, inflation gap and the fiscal deficit to GDP ratio.
The results of the exercise showed that an increase in the fiscal deficit to GDP ratio tends to put upward pressure
on the call rate after a lag, even after controlling for the output gap and inflation gap. At the present juncture,
with the likelihood of inflation moderating and the output gap remaining negative, stimulating investment with
a view to reverting to the trend rate of growth of the economy over the medium-term is high priority. In this
context, an orderly and qualitative fiscal adjustment would provide more headroom to monetary policy to address
macroeconomic stability, in general, and the growth objective, in particular, over the medium-term. On the issue of
institutional arrangements for debt/cash management, international experience with regard to the global financial
crisis highlights the intertwining of fiscal, monetary and debt management and, thus, underscores the need for
closer co-ordination between monetary and debt managers and fiscal authorities. At the present juncture in India,
government borrowing continues to be large and the general economic environment warrants close monitoring
of the evolving fiscal situation. In this context, persisting with the central bank’s engagement with government
debt management coupled with more intensive co-ordination with the government appears to be the appropriate
approach for the medium-term.
I. Introduction
5.1 The global financial crisis marked an inflexion
point in the history of monetary-fiscal co-ordination,
with governments and central banks in almost
all countries working on an unprecedented and
unconventional scale to restore financial stability.
While governments in many advanced economies
acted decisively in bailing out and even outright
nationalising failed investment banks, non-banks
and insurance companies and provided sizeable
fiscal stimulus to minimise the impact of the crisis
on the real economy, central banks opened liquidity
windows to banks and non-banks alike and started
currency swap lines.
5.2 A similar degree of coherence was, however,
not observed in the exit from unconventional fiscal
and monetary policies that were initiated during the
crisis. In advanced economies, as fiscal exit seems
to be an arduous and protracted process given
the size of the extant deficit as well as the lack of
political consensus towards austerity measures,
monetary policy has continued to be accommodative to provide the requisite boost to the fragile state of
economic recovery. In the euro area, the seemingly
recalcitrant sovereign debt problems, despite
several initiatives to restore fiscal discipline, have
entailed a persistent accommodative monetary
policy stance, even as the pace of contraction of the
economy has shown some remission in the recent
period. Emerging market economies, on the other
hand, had been pursuing both fiscal and monetary
consolidation contemporaneously, in view of the
early recovery from the crisis and emergence of
inflationary pressures. Subsequently, however, the
slackening of global growth, domestic structural
impediments and (past) monetary tightening to
address commodity and/or asset price pressures,
impacted the prospective growth trajectory of
emerging market countries. This has triggered some
monetary easing in the recent period even as the
policy space for further accommodation has reduced
in some countries.
5.3 In general, post-crisis, there has been a
gradual realisation that as globalisation matures,
and, more particularly, as financial globalisation deepens and exposes economies to invisible risks,
the scope for collective action is likely to broaden
where governments and central banks might have
to work in unison more frequently while respecting
each other’s domain of activities. An immediate
manifestation of the underlying turn in international
policy thinking testifying to the need for increased
fiscal-monetary co-ordination are the newly
institutionalised collegial arrangements involving the
central bank, other regulators and the government,
which have been entrusted with the primary
responsibility for fostering financial stability.
5.4 Notwithstanding the positive experience
gained on fiscal-monetary co-ordination and the
reduction in government deficits in many countries
in 2011, the IMF’s latest Fiscal Monitor (October
2012) highlighted the elevated fiscal vulnerabilities
emanating from the still very high public debt rollover
requirements in many advanced and some emerging
market economies, even as it recommended an
orderly pace of fiscal adjustment in the context of the
general slackening of activity in many countries. The
document also observed that putting public finances
on a sounder footing over the medium-term should
be a priority as this remains a key pre-requisite for
growth.
5.5 In India too, the resumption of fiscal
consolidation efforts after shaking off the indirect
drag of the global financial crisis has been beset
with challenges. Indeed during the first year (2012-13) of the Twelfth Plan, notwithstanding a modest
improvement, significant risks remain to global
economic prospects. Additionally, further reduction
in WPI inflation, despite the recent easing, is
contingent upon the alleviation of supply constraints
and progress on fiscal consolidation. Moreover,
as the fiscal deficit during 2012-13 so far remains
high, a turnaround in the fiscal position would be
imperative for generating the required resources
for the Twelfth Plan. The Union Budget for 2012-13
had, in fact, proposed to reduce the fiscal deficit to
5.1 per cent of GDP from 5.9 per cent in the revised
estimates of the previous year. The Budget had
also introduced some amendments to the FRBM
Act. On October 29, 2012, the Finance Minister announced the government’s decision to adopt
a fiscal consolidation plan during the Twelfth Five
Year Plan that would progressively bring down the
fiscal deficit from 5.3 per cent of GDP in 2012-13 to
3.0 per cent of GDP in 2016-17. Significant steps
since taken by the government largely to reduce fuel
subsidies have an important signalling impact even
though their effect on the fiscal deficit of 2012-13 is
expected to be negligible.
5.6 Against this backdrop, Section II of this
chapter assesses the entrenched relationship
between fiscal and monetary policies in the post-reforms
period and draws some implications for
their evolutionary path over the medium-term. This
exercise, which is based on Zoli (2005), estimates
a linear function with the call rate – which is the
operating target of monetary policy and can be
generally used as a proxy for the monetary policy
rate – as the dependent variable and the inflation
gap (i.e. the difference between the WPI inflation
rate and its trend component), output gap (i.e., the
de-trended or cyclical component of GDP), the ratio
of the Centre’s fiscal deficit to GDP (with a one-period
lag) and the one-period lagged call rate as
explanatory variables. Annual data largely over the
post-reforms period are used for the estimation. The
estimated equation provides broad guidance on the
implications of the evolving path of fiscal deficit,
output gap and inflation gap for monetary policy over
the medium-term.
5.7 Section III of this chapter discusses the
evolution and intertwining of debt management
policies with fiscal and monetary policies,
particularly in the context of the recent global
financial crisis, which has thrown up challenges
to well-entrenched paradigms, internationally. As
far as India is concerned, an important watershed
in the institutional arrangements for the central
government’s debt management – which have been
entrusted to the Reserve Bank of India by statute –
was the setting up of a Middle Office in the Ministry of
Finance in 2008, to formulate the debt management
strategy of the central government. Taking this
forward, the Union Budget 2011-12, presented in
end-February 2011, stated, “The Government has been in the process of setting up an independent
Debt Management Office in the Finance Ministry. A
Middle Office is already operational. As a next step,
I propose to introduce the Public Debt Management
Agency of India Bill in the next financial year.”
(Budget Speech of the Finance Minister, Paragraph
20). The Union Budget for 2012-13, presented in
mid-March 2012, has, in fact, proposed to move
the Public Debt Management Agency of India Bill,
2012 in the Budget Session of Parliament. An
important rethink in this process, however, was
earlier set in motion by Governor Subbarao of the
Reserve Bank at the meeting of the Central Bank
Governance Group on May 9, 2011 at the Bank for
International Settlements, where he averred, “….as
long as there are institutionalised mechanisms to
negotiate various trade-offs in a given context within
the overarching objective of achieving monetary and
financial stability, separation of debt management
from the central bank seems to be a sub-optimal
choice. Even internationally, the emerging post-crisis
wisdom recognises the interdependence between
the functions of monetary policy, financial stability
and sovereign debt management and the need for
close association of the central bank with sovereign
debt management.” In the context of the post-global
financial crisis, this section discusses issues that
could impinge on the institutional arrangements for
co-ordinating monetary and debt management over
the medium-term. The last section sums up the
discussion.
II. Fiscal-Monetary Co-ordination: Outlook for
the Medium-Term
Recapitulation of Past Trends
5.8 To begin, a recapitulation of the fiscal and
monetary management story since 1991-92 is
necessary, because the evolving trends will be used
to assess the medium-term outlook.
Fiscal Trends
5.9 Following the initiation of structural
reforms, including fiscal reforms, in the aftermath
of the external payments crisis in 1990-91, fiscal imbalances generally declined during the first
half of the 1990s but started increasing during
the second half, largely due to the slacking of tax
revenue induced by the growth slowdown and
rising interest payments and wages and salaries
(Chart V.1). Subsequently, fiscal imbalances again
started declining as interest payments relative to
GDP began falling (due to general monetary easing)
and, more substantially because of the enactment
and implementation of the Fiscal Responsibility
and Budget Management (FRBM) Act in 2004-
05 as well as the strong growth of over 9 per cent
during three consecutive years ending in 2007-08
that helped boost revenues. A primary surplus was,
in fact, obtained during 2003-04, 2004-05, 2006-
07 and 2007-08. The fiscal deficit, in fact, declined
to 2.5 per cent of GDP in 2007-08, the lowest
level since the initiation of reforms. Fiscal stimulus
measures to stave off the adverse indirect impact of
the global financial crisis on growth during 2008-09
and 2009-10, however, resulted in a sharp increase
in deficit measures. With the economy recovering
fairly quickly, fiscal consolidation efforts resumed in
2010-11, which was supported by substantial one-off
increase in revenues from telecommunication
services. The sharp decline in growth in 2011-12
coupled with large direct tax refunds and higher subsidies, however, resulted in a sharp increase
in fiscal imbalances. Disconcertingly, the share of
capital expenditure, as conventionally defined, in
total government expenditure has generally declined
from around 26 per cent in 1991-92 to around 12 per
cent in 2011-12.
Evolution of the Monetary Policy Stance
5.10 Monetary policy formulation in the milieu
of structural reforms beginning in 1991-92 was
facilitated by a reduction in fiscal imbalances
and institutional arrangements to limit unbridled
government access to monetisation through ad hoc
treasury bills. After recording double digit rates in
the first half of the 1990s, inflation subsequently
declined, reflecting global trends as well as the
impact of domestic reforms. Reflecting the easing
of the monetary policy stance, the Bank Rate was
progressively reduced from 12 per cent in October
1991 to 6 per cent in April 2003; after the institution
of the full-fledged Liquidity Adjustment Facility (LAF)
in June 2000, the Bank Rate was kept unchanged
at 6 per cent between April 2003 and January 2012
when it was aligned with the Marginal Standing
Facility (MSF) rate which, in turn, was linked to the
LAF repo rate. On the other hand, the LAF repo rate
was brought down from 9 per cent in April 2001 to
6 per cent in end-March 2004. The Cash Reserve
Ratio (CRR) was also progressively reduced from
15 per cent in 1991-92 to 4.5 per cent in August
2003. Subsequently, with the significant increase in
the growth rate and an upsurge in capital inflows, the
CRR was steadily hiked to 7.5 per cent by November
2007. Open Market Operations, LAF and the Market
Stabilisation Scheme (MSS) (introduced in April
2004) also helped restrain the growth of domestic
liquidity in the face of strong capital inflows.
5.11 The LAF repo rate was increased from 6 per
cent in end-March 2004 to 7.75 per cent in end-March
2007, as inflation had picked up somewhat during
this period. During the first half of 2008-09, inflation
increased sharply under the pressure of hardening
international commodity prices, which necessitated
an anti-inflationary policy response in the form of
increases in the CRR and the LAF repo rate to 9.0 per cent each by July/August 2008. The monetary
policy stance had to be changed abruptly in October
2008 to deal with domestic liquidity shortages and
the growth slowdown induced by the global financial
crisis. Reflecting this, the CRR was reduced sharply
to 6.5 per cent in October 2008 and further to 5.0 per
cent by January 2009. The LAF repo rate was also
brought down progressively to 4.75 per cent by April
2009. Unconventional monetary policy measures
were also taken to enhance domestic liquidity.
Along with the accommodative monetary policy,
fiscal policy too turned expansionary to support the
recovery process, as alluded to earlier.
5.12 As the economy recovered fairly quickly
from the indirect effects of the global financial
crisis and inflationary pressures started taking root,
the LAF repo rate was progressively increased to
8.5 per cent by October 2011 and the CRR was
raised to 6.0 per cent by April 2010. With growth
declining sharply to below-trend in 2011-12 and with
the moderation in the inflation rate, the CRR was
reduced to 4.75 per cent by March 2012 and the
LAF repo rate was reduced to 8.0 per cent in April
2012 (i.e., during 2012-13). Further reduction in the
LAF repo rate was subsequently put on hold as the
expected complementary policy actions towards
fiscal adjustment and improving the investment
climate did not follow. However, credit and liquidity
conditions were eased through a 100 basis point
reduction in the SLR in July 2012 and a cumulative 50
basis point reduction in CRR in September-October
2012. With the announcement of a series of reforms
by the government beginning in September 2012
and the moderation in inflation rate, even as growth
declined significantly below trend, the LAF repo rate
and the CRR were reduced by 25 basis points each
to 7.75 per cent and 4.0 per cent, respectively, in the
third quarter review of monetary policy in January
2013.
Changes in Sources of Reserve Money and Money
Supply
5.13 Over the period 1991-92 to 2007-08, the
steady decline in the share of net RBI credit to the
central government in the outstanding amount of reserve money and the corresponding increase in
the share of net foreign exchange assets of the RBI
was clearly evident (Chart V.2). This reflected the
impact of the general reduction in fiscal imbalances
and institutional arrangements to limit monetisation
of budget deficits coupled with the initiatives aimed
at the development of the government securities
market, on the one hand, and the liberalisation of
foreign exchange markets and capital inflows, on
the other. In fact, from 1999-2000 onwards, net
foreign exchange assets replaced net RBI credit to
the Centre as the predominant source of reserve
money. Furthermore, the period from 2004-05 to
2007-08 was marked by substantial mopping up
of excessive domestic liquidity to the sequestered
government account through MSS operations in the
face of strong capital flows. The trends in the shares
of net RBI credit to the Centre and foreign exchange
assets of the RBI in reserve money reversed sharply,
beginning in 2008-09 under the indirect impact of
the global financial crisis.
5.14 The crisis induced a reversal of capital flows
and the consequent exchange market pressures
triggered RBI’s market operations to stem volatility in
the exchange rate, which exacerbated the stressed domestic liquidity conditions. In response, domestic
liquidity was augmented through (i) monetary support
to the government’s fiscal stimulus-engendered
large market borrowing programme through OMOs;
(ii) the unwinding and de-sequestering of MSS
balances; and (iii) substantial liquidity injection to the
banking system through LAF. In 2011-12, the shares
of both net RBI credit to the Centre and net foreign
exchange assets in reserve money increased; the
increase in the share of net foreign exchange assets
was mainly due to currency revaluations, on account
of Rupee depreciation.
5.15 Similar trends were evident in the sources
of broad money as far as the share of bank credit to
the government and foreign exchange assets of the
banking system were concerned (Chart V.3). Bank
credit to the commercial sector, however, remained
the predominant component of broad money
right through the period, with its share increasing
significantly after 2003-04.
Trends in Call Rate, GDP Growth and Inflation
5.16 Post-reforms, with the market determination
of interest rates, the call rate has generally moved in
line with the monetary policy rate, responding to the liquidity and inflation conditions (Chart V.4). After
the institution of LAF in 2000, the volatility in the call
rate declined significantly. The inflation rate declined
significantly after the mid-1990s, even though there
was a sharp increase after 2010-11, reflecting a
combination of different factors on the supply and
demand sides during the year. The real GDP growth
rate picked up consequent upon the initiation of
structural reforms in 1991-92, but slackened in the
late 1990s mainly as the industrial reform process
lost momentum. The growth rate picked up again and
more substantially after 2003-04 supported by fiscal
consolidation, moderate inflation, substantial capital
inflows and high rates of savings and investment.
The growth rate slipped in 2008-09 in the aftermath
of the global financial crisis but staged a quick
recovery in the following two years, supported by
co-ordinated fiscal-monetary policy actions. The
worsening of global economic conditions and the
persistence of structural impediments adversely
impacted the growth process during 2011-12.
5.17 Having reviewed the broad trends in
fiscal-monetary interactions since the initiation of
structural reforms in the early 1990s, the theoretical
constructs underlying such interactions as also some of the empirical literature on the subject are
briefly discussed next.
Channels of Interaction between Fiscal and Monetary
Policies – An Eclectic Review of Theoretical and
Empirical Issues
5.18 Both fiscal and monetary policies are
instruments of macroeconomic stabilisation. Co-ordination
between the two policies is necessary to
judiciously harmonise the attainment of the objectives
of growth, price stability and financial stability,
which are often complicated by the differential
weights assigned to these objectives by the fiscal
and monetary authorities and by the uncertainty
about evolving macroeconomic and financial
conditions. For example, an increase in aggregate
demand brought about through an (excessively)
expansionary fiscal policy to stimulate growth could
shunt the inflation rate over the comfort zone of the
monetary authority. Similarly, a tight monetary policy
could translate into higher market interest rates and
an increase in the outgo of interest payments and
the budget deficit.
5.19 The interaction between the two policies
could also be analysed from the financing side of
the budget deficit, i.e., broadly in terms of bonds and
money. Bond financing of budget deficits could lead to
a general pressure on interest rates that could crowd
out private sector investment and, beyond a point,
adversely impact growth prospects. The crowding-out
effect plays out only in the case of non-Ricardian
behaviour on the part of the private entities, i.e.,
they do not perceive that, for instance, an increase
in budget deficit today implies an increase in future
tax burden, and accordingly do not increase their
savings to the same extent as the decline in public
savings. On the flip side, to the extent that (large)
budget deficits are (disproportionately) financed
through money creation, these inevitably interfere
with, if not compromise, the avowed monetary policy
objectives of price stability.
5.20 At the same time, as the Indian experience
with the recent global crisis showed, the substantial
increase in the budget deficit, engendered by fiscal stimulus measures, was supported by an
accommodative monetary policy stance so as
to preclude financial market instability and more
generally to sustain the process of recovery, even
as the inflation rate remained subdued initially.
Another channel through which fiscal deficits could
impinge on monetary policy is via their impact on the
current account deficit (through higher imports) and
country risk premium and, in turn, on the exchange
rate (Mohanty and Scatigna, 2003).
5.21 From a theoretical perspective, Sargent and
Wallace’s ‘Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic’ (1981)
showed that whenever the real rate of interest
exceeded the growth rate of the economy, any
attempt to curtail monetary financing of the budget
deficit by the monetary authorities in the short run
(from the viewpoint of maintaining price stability)
would eventually result in even more monetary
financing and higher inflation in the future. This is
because a reduction in monetary financing in the
short run would imply more bond financing, which
would push up interest rates. This, in turn, would
lead to higher interest payments and, thus, larger
budget deficits over time. Given the perceived limits
to the government’s ability to service a progressively
higher order of bond obligations, monetary financing
would be inevitable and large eventually, which
would have inflationary consequences.
5.22 On the other hand, even if the central bank
does not acquiesce to monetary financing of deficit,
the fiscal theory of price level (FTPL) maintains
that inflation control can still be compromised (for
example, Cochrane, 1999; Woodford,1995). This is
because, according to the FTPL, the government’s
inter-temporal budget constraint is an equilibrium
condition and the only variable that can adjust to
equate the nominal value of the extant stock of
bonds to the present value of exogenously given
primary surpluses is the price level. It is, thus, fiscal
policy that determines the price level. The FTPL has,
however, been criticised on theoretical grounds and
empirical support has also been mixed (Zoli, 2005).
5.23 From an empirical standpoint, a number of
studies have analysed the interaction between fiscal and monetary policies in a VAR framework. For
instance, Muscatelli et al. (2002), showed that the
response of monetary policy to a fiscal policy shock
was not uniform in a set of select OECD countries:
while in the UK and the US such a shock led to
a significant decline in the interest rate within the
first quarter (signifying accommodative monetary
policy), there was no clear monetary reaction in
Germany and France. Raj et al. (2011) assessed
fiscal-monetary interaction in India using quarterly
data over the period 2000 to 2010 and found, inter-alia,
that while monetary policy reacted to output
and inflation shocks in a counter-cyclical manner,
fiscal policy reaction was primarily pro-cyclical. The
positive impact of expansionary fiscal policy on
output was found to be temporary, with the impact
turning significantly negative over the medium to
long term. A fiscal policy shock (i.e. an increase
in fiscal deficit) led to a tightening of the monetary
policy stance, which peaked after three quarters
and reverted to equilibrium after seven quarters. A
monetary policy shock (i.e. an increase in the call
rate) similarly led to an initial increase in the fiscal
deficit, with the effect petering out after the fourth
quarter.
5.24 The more traditional approach towards
empirical assessment of fiscal-monetary interaction
is the monetary policy reaction function. As alluded
to earlier, Zoli (2005) empirically ascertained for a
set of seven emerging market countries whether
fiscal stance at all impacts monetary policy decisions
or, more technically, whether fiscal variables enter
significantly in the reaction function of the central
bank. In a linear-type (Taylor, 1993) monetary policy
reaction function – with the central bank’s policy
rate as the dependent variable and the output gap
and inflation rate as the independent variables –
an additional variable, viz., real primary balance
was included, as a measure of fiscal stance. The
rationale for the inclusion was based on previous
empirical work conducted by Melitz (1997, 2002)
and Wyplosz (1999) for industrialised countries.
5.25 Zoli (2005), however, found that in all the
seven countries monetary policy did not respond to changes in primary balances or, in other words, fiscal
policy did not impinge on monetary policy. Aisen and
Hauner (2008) in their study of a set of 60 advanced
and emerging market countries over the period 1970
to 2006 found that in a GMM framework, budget
deficits tend to have a positive and statistically
significant impact on interest rates. The impact was,
however, conditional on whether the budget deficits
were high, how it was funded (largely domestically
financed or whether it interacted with high domestic
debt), and whether financial openness was low,
interest rates were liberalised and financial depth was
low. In essence, the exercise brought to the fore the
non-linear impact of budget deficit on interest rates.
More recently, Tillmann (2011) found that US data
over the period 1982 to 2004 supported a non-linear
Taylor rule. Such non-linearity did not arise from the
non-linearity of the Phillips curve or non-quadratic
central bank preferences but from the monetary
policy approach to the uncertainty about the slope
of the (linear) Phillips curve. In effect, with a view to
avoiding “very bad” outcomes, the monetary policy
response to inflation becomes stronger the higher
the inflation rate and the larger the output gap.
Impact of Fiscal Policy on Monetary Policy Stance
in India – An Empirical Assessment
5.26 Against this backdrop, the impact of fiscal
policy on monetary policy in India over the period
of reforms in India is assessed using Zoli’s (2005)
approach, which estimates the following:
where INT is the monetary policy intervention rate,
INFL is the annual inflation rate, OUTPUTGAP is
the difference between actual output and potential
output, ΔRPB is the change in real primary balance
and έ is the error term. For inflation-targeting
countries, the term “INFL” in the equation was
replaced with the term “expected inflation less
the inflation target”. Real primary balances were
incorporated in the above equation in difference form
because the series was found to be non-stationary
in all the countries in the sample. Zoli conceded that
even though such a specification of the monetary policy reaction function was not obtained from
theoretical constructs, it facilitated an assessment of
the direct impact of fiscal policy on monetary policy
that transcends the indirect impact via aggregate
demand pressure (output gap) and inflation.
5.27 The above approach was adopted for India
with some modifications, using annual data for the
period 1988-89 to 2011-12. Even though broad-based
structural reforms were initiated in 1991-92,
money market reforms started somewhat earlier with
the setting up of the Discount and Finance House of
India (DFHI) in 1988 followed by the deregulation of
call money rates in 1989. This period also broadly
covers two monetary policy frameworks: monetary
targeting which started in 1985-86 and the multiple
indicators approach since 1998-99. The weighted
average call rate (CALLRATE), which is the
operating target of monetary policy, was taken as
a proxy for the monetary policy rate. Following the
introduction of the full-fledged LAF in June 2000, the
weighted average call rate has generally hovered
around the effective policy rate, i.e., the repo rate
in the case of banking system liquidity deficit and
the reverse repo rate in the case of banking system
liquidity surplus. To the extent that changes in
banking system liquidity also reflect monetary policy
actions through direct instruments such as the CRR
or through indirect instruments such as OMOs,
LAF and the MSS, the call rate can be reasonably
expected to reflect the overall monetary policy
stance right through the period (Singh 2010).
5.28 The output gap (OUTPUTGAP) variable in
the equation was taken as the de-trended or the
cyclical component of the log of real GDP using HP
filter. The equation also included an ‘inflation gap’
variable instead of just the inflation rate, as proposed
by Zoli for non-inflation targeting countries. Even
though India is not an inflation-targeting country,
price stability (along with growth) has remained a
key objective of monetary policy and the Reserve
Bank provides indicative projections of inflation and
growth as a guide to such policy; these indicative
projections, set out at the beginning of the year
(usually in April), are reassessed periodically in
the light of evolving developments. Moreover, the emphasis between price stability and growth
objectives varies from year-to-year, depending upon
the evolving macroeconomic situation. Keeping this
in view, the inflation gap (INFLGAP) was defined
as the deviation of the year-on-year WPI inflation
rate from its (HP-filter-based) trend rate and was
incorporated in the equation.
5.29 In line with typical Taylor-rule specifications,
the contemporaneous output gap and inflation gap
were incorporated in the equation. The real primary
balance was replaced by the ratio of the Centre’s
Gross Fiscal Deficit to GDP (GFDR) (lagged one
period), not only to get a sense of the impact of
the overall net borrowing requirements on the call
rate but also because in India annual targets in the
Budget and the FRBM statements are specified in
terms of the fiscal deficit-GDP ratio (apart from the
revenue deficit/effective revenue deficit). Although
this specification is not a typical policy reaction
function, as in vogue in many advanced countries, it
aims to capture some of the dynamics of the multiple
indicators approach1 to monetary policy formulation
that was adopted in India in the late 1990s.
5.30 All the variables were found to be stationary
as corroborated by both the ADF and KPSS tests.
Granger Causality F-tests showed that over the
period 1988-89 to 2011-12 the fiscal deficit to GDP
ratio uni-directionally caused a change in the call
rate (at one lag, lag length being decided on the
basis of Schwarz information criterion) (Table 5.1).
This showed that past values of the fiscal deficit-
GDP ratio have tended to influence the call rate (or
the monetary policy rate).
Table 5.1: Granger Causality Test |
Null Hypothesis: |
F-Statistic |
Prob. |
GFDR does not Granger Cause CALLRATE |
3.90 |
0.06 |
CALLRATE does not Granger Cause GFDR |
0.57 |
0.46 |
5.31 Next, the call rate was regressed on its lag,
the output gap, the inflation gap and the lagged GFDGDP
ratio. Two dummy variables were included to
take cognisance of year-specific outliers; DUM1
for the year 1995-96 took into account the sharp
increase in the call rate following the temporarily
stressed domestic liquidity conditions as a result of
the RBI’s operations in the foreign exchange market
to stem volatility; and DUM2 captured the sizeble
easing of domestic liquidity conditions during the
years 1996-97 (that reflected the base effect of the
previous year’s forex market operations) and 2008-
09 to 2011-12 (that largely resulted from the policy
responses to the global financial crisis as well as
sovereign debt crisis). The results of the estimation
are set out below:
5.32 The Adjusted R-square value indicates good
explanatory power of the model, especially in the
emerging market context. All the coefficients of the
independent variables, viz., lagged call rate, inflation
gap, output gap and fiscal deficit-GDP ratio were
found to be statistically significant, individually as
well as jointly, and had the expected signs. Statistical
tests (CUSUM and CUSUM squares) confirmed the
stability of the parameters in the estimated equation,
as depicted in Chart V.5.
5.33 In the estimated equation, the
contemporaneous coefficients of output gap and
inflation gap were both positive, and the magnitude
of the latter was greater than that of the former
indicating greater sensitivities of monetary policy to
inflation outcomes. The estimated coefficient also
indicates that, on average, a one percentage point increase in the GFD-GDP ratio leads to a direct
increase of 0.72 percentage point in the call rate, with
a one-period lag, in addition to the indirect impact of
the increase in the fiscal deficit on the call rate that
may be felt via increases in the inflation rate and
the output gap. The positive relation between the
call rate and the GFD-GDP ratio is along expected
lines since a higher fiscal deficit would tend to put
pressure on the level of lendable resources, which
in turn, would impact money market liquidity. In this
context, it may be pointed out that since the share of
capital expenditure in budgetary expenditures has
generally declined over the years, the impact of the
fiscal deficit on the potential output growth rate may
have been somewhat muted, amplifying the output
gap. The negative coefficient of DUM2 underlines
the significance of liquidity enhancing measures by
the Reserve Bank generally in the aftermath of the
global financial as well as sovereign debt crises.
5.34 The results (i.e. the size of the coefficients of
the inflation gap and output gap) need to be viewed
in light of the fact that the specification is not that
of a typical monetary policy reaction function as it
is augmented by the inclusion of a fiscal variable.
Moreover, as the equation is estimated using ordinary
least squares, it may be viewed as an approximation in the light of more advanced estimation techniques
being used in the literature. Notwithstanding these
issues, from the monetary policy perspective, this
exercise suggests that the fiscal context matters for
the conduct of monetary policy in economies like
India.
III. Institutional Arrangements Relating to Debt
and Cash Management – Quo Vadis?
5.35 The Reserve Bank is the debt and cash
manager of the central government by statute
(RBI Act). The Reserve Bank also manages the
debt and cash of the state governments by mutual
agreement, as provided in the same Act. The issue
of separating monetary and debt management and,
more specifically, of taking the debt management
function out of the Reserve Bank has been
intensively debated in official forums at least since
the mid-1990s, with forceful arguments from both
sides (Box V.1). The recent global financial crisis led
to a re-think to the debate.
Pre-Global Crisis Philosophy
5.36 The treatment of public debt management
as a separate macroeconomic policy with its own
objectives and instruments and not merely as an extension of monetary and fiscal policy generally
began in the 1980s, mainly because the trade-offs
between the three policies began to be increasingly
felt (Togo, 2007). While this change in thinking was
triggered by the pernicious effects of fiscal activism
of the previous decades on inflation and fiscal
sustainability, it was facilitated by the development
and liberalisation of financial markets (Hoogduin et
al., 2010).
Box V.1
Evolution of Views on Institutional Arrangements for the Separation of Debt and Monetary
Management in India
The policy stance on the issue of separation of debt and
monetary management has evolved over the years, in tandem
with institutional, macroeconomic and financial developments.
In particular, the advent of wide-ranging structural reforms
in 1991-92, fiscal consolidation and the transition from an
administered to a market-oriented price discovery mechanism
for government securities were important initiatives that
impacted the interaction of monetary and debt management.
The Committee on Capital Account Convertibility, 1996
(Chairman: Shri S.S. Tarapore) was perhaps the first official
committee set up in India in the post-reforms period to
specifically recommend the separation of monetary and debt
management and the setting up of an Office of Public Debt by
the government.
In March 1997, automatic monetisation of the central
government’s budget deficit through the issue of ad hoc
treasury bills was abolished and a system of Ways and Means
Advances was put in place. This provided greater headroom to
monetary policy.
An internal Working Group of the RBI, which submitted
its Report in December 1997, also suggested that the two
functions be separated and that debt management should be
taken over by an independent corporation as a wholly-owned
subsidiary of the RBI under the Companies Act.
In June 2000, a full-fledged Liquidity Adjustment Facility put in
place by the RBI emerged as the principal operating instrument
of monetary policy. This provided greater flexibility in operating
monetary policy.
The RBI Annual Report 2000-01 stated, “The separation of the
functions of debt management and monetary management is
regarded as a desirable medium-term objective, conditional
upon development of the government securities market, durable
fiscal correction and an enabling legislative framework…The
Reserve Bank has proposed amendments to the Reserve Bank
of India Act, 1934 which would take away the mandatory nature
of management of public debt by the Reserve Bank and vest
the discretion with the central government to undertake the
management of the public debt either by itself or to assign it
to some other independent body, if it so desires.” (Paragraph
11.25).
The RBI’s Annual Policy Statement 2001-02 mentioned “…
while no view was taken on the details of implementation,
a decision to separate the two functions was considered
desirable in principle..….[O]nce legislative actions with regard
to Fiscal Responsibility Bill and amendments with regard to the
Reserve Bank of India Act are accomplished, it is proposed to
take up with the government the feasibility of and further steps
for separation of government debt management function from
RBI.” (Paragraph 90)
An internal Expert Group of the Ministry of Finance, 2001
(Chairman: Shri A. Virmani) recommended a two-stage
process to separate the two functions, viz., setting up a
centralised middle office in the Ministry of Finance to develop
a comprehensive risk management framework and then
establishing an autonomous Public Debt Office.
The Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management (FRBM)
Act that came into force in July 2004 provided for a mandated
and time-bound reduction in the fiscal deficit and revenue
deficit of the central government. It also provided for prohibiting
participation of the Reserve Bank in the primary market
for government securities with effect from April 2006. This,
combined with the institution of LAF in 2000 and the auction-based
mechanism for selling government securities in the
primary market put in place in the early 1990s, considerably
reduced the conflict of interest between debt management and
monetary management, even though both remained under the
purview of the RBI.
In the context of the FRBM Act, the Annual Policy Statement
of the RBI for the year 2005-06 indicated a re-orientation of
government debt management operations while simultaneously
strengthening monetary operations within the Reserve Bank
in order to move towards a functional separation of the debt
management and monetary operations. Towards this objective,
the Financial Markets Department (FMD) was constituted
in the RBI on July 6, 2005 to provide an integrated market
interface for the Reserve Bank and to bring about integration
in the Bank’s conduct of monetary operations. The FMD is
functionally separate from the Internal Debt Management
Department of the RBI.
The Committee on Fuller Capital Account Convertibility July
2006 (Chairman: Shri S.S. Tarapore) recommended the setting
up of an Office of Public Debt to operate independently outside
the RBI for effective functional separation, enabling more
efficient debt management as also monetary management.
The Union Budget 2007-08 announced, “World over, debt
management is distinct from monetary management. The
establishment of a Debt Management Office (DMO) in the
government has been advocated for quite some time. The
fiscal consolidation achieved so far has encouraged us to take
the first step. Accordingly, I propose to set up an autonomous
DMO and, in the first phase, a Middle Office will be set up to
facilitate the transition to a full-fledged DMO.” (Budget Speech,
Paragraph 106).
Subsequently, the Ministry of Finance, Government of India,
set up an Internal Working Group on Debt Management, 2008
(Chairman: Dr. Jahangir Aziz) to analyse how best to establish
a DMO. Highlighting internationally accepted best practices (citing, inter alia, the guidelines on public debt management
issued by the IMF and the World Bank in 2003) that debt
management should be disaggregated from monetary policy
and taken out of the realm of the central bank, the Working
Group recommended the establishment of a statutory body
(the National Treasury Management Agency) to perform debt
and cash management of the central and state governments in
India. The Working Group provided the following rationale for a
separate debt management agency:
-
Important gains would be achieved by consolidating the
debt management function and the consequent unification
of related information in one agency instead of it being
dispersed across several departments, as is the case in
several emerging market countries including India, that
obfuscate lines of action and accountability.
-
A conflict of interest becomes manifest if the central bank
also manages government debt in that it could be tempted
to keep interest rates relatively low to minimise the cost of
debt, even in the face of inflationary pressures. A conflict
of interest can also occur since the central bank, as the
regulator and supervisor of the banking system, has an
incentive to mandate that banks hold a large amount of
government securities.
-
A conflict of interest could arise if the central bank which
owns/administers the operating system of the government
securities market is also a participant in the market.
The Chairman of the Committee on Financial Sector
Assessment (CFSA), 2009, Dr. Rakesh Mohan, concurred with
the proposal to set up a Middle Office, which is akin to the
role of the DMO in the US Treasury, but personally viewed that
setting up an independent DMO and the decision about the
complete separation of debt management from the Reserve
Bank needs to be revisited on several grounds, such as:
-
Even a combined (Centre and States) fiscal deficit of 6
per cent of GDP, as envisaged under Fiscal Responsibility
Legislations, would be among the highest among the major
economies and, combined with an overall debt-GDP ratio
of over 80 per cent, would necessitate maintaining overall
consistency between fiscal and monetary management in
the future.
-
A reduction in the SLR would be conditional upon further
reduction in the combined fiscal deficit and, until then,
monetary management, debt management and bank
regulation would continue to remain interlinked.
-
In the context of volatile capital flows, the forex market
operations of the RBI would be necessary on a fairly
continuous basis. The concomitant sterilization of these
operations through the MSS and their harmonisation
with the market borrowing programme of the government
would be difficult if the debt management operations are
separated out of the RBI.
-
Since 70 per cent of the banking assets relate to public
sector banks, setting up a DMO in the Ministry of Finance
may result in a conflict between the government’s role as a
debt manager and its status as the owner of a substantial
portion of the banking sector.
-
There is a need to ensure that further deepening of the
government securities market (which is, in turn, necessary
for debt management) is undertaken along with the
maintenance of monetary and financial stability.
-
There is a need to harmonise the market borrowing
programmes of the central and state governments.
Moreover, it may not be appropriate for a central
government authority to also undertake state government
debt management.
-
While setting up a DMO in the Ministry of Finance would
facilitate an integrated approach to overall (external and
internal) debt management policy, the Reserve Bank could
continue to conduct all market borrowing operations as
the agent of the government, in a manner very similar to
the functions of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York on
behalf of the US Treasury.
-
It has always been difficult to set up new government
authorities. Due to government rules on service, these
institutions have usually been staffed by officers on
deputation from different government departments, which
makes it difficult to develop appropriate expertise.
-
The RBI is able to handle debt management operations
because of the large size of its staff and expertise developed
in managing regulation and supervision of banks, money
market operations and debt market operations. The staff of
the DMO will need to be conversant with financial markets
and also be able to interact continuously with market
players. Moreover, technical infrastructure for, inter alia,
issuance and trading, would have to be set up, which would
involve avoidable expense.
The Financial Sector Legislative Reforms Commission
(FSLRC), which was constituted by the Government of India
in March 2011 to review and recast the legal and institutional
structures of the Indian financial sector in line with the
contemporary requirements of the sector, in its Approach
Paper of October 2012, observed that public debt management
requires specialized investment banking capability. The
FSLRC endorsed the view of several expert committees that
a professional debt management agency should undertake
this function because (i) unifying information on onshore
and offshore liabilities of the government that is, at present,
fragmented across the RBI and Ministry of Finance, would lead
to more efficient debt management; and (ii) there is a conflict
of objectives of the RBI that is required to manage public debt
and maintain price stability. FSLRC also proposed to integrate
the tasks of cash management and obtain a comprehensive
picture of contingent liabilities of the government into a new
debt management law.
5.37 The classic conflict between monetary policy
and debt management policy related to the decision
on setting the policy interest rate. Similarly, the
conflict between fiscal policy and debt management
policy related to the choice of keeping debt-servicing
costs low (and hence meeting deficit targets) over the
short term (which generally fell within the electoral
cycle) or over the medium/long term. Separation of
the policies was expected to avoid such conflicts
and improve policy credibility. Accordingly,
countries such as New Zealand, Belgium, France,
Ireland, Portugal, Sweden, Denmark and the United
Kingdom decided to decentralise debt management
to varying extents.
5.38 It was also recognised that the efficacy of
policy decentralisation and its credibility depended
on (i) the Tinbergen rule, i.e., the availability of as
many independent policy instruments as there were
objectives, a requirement that is difficult to meet in
practice; and (ii) the consistency of the overall policy
mix. Policy co-ordination, thus, became necessary
to get the ‘desired’ policy mix. Fiscal Responsibility
Legislations and the Stability and Growth Pact in the
euro area that provided for deficit and/or debt ceilings
are examples of such co-ordination mechanisms.
5.39 This kind of separation of policies was
also considered desirable by the IMF and World
Bank, as reflected in the guidelines on public
debt management issued by them in 2003 and,
in particular, “….where the level of financial
development allows, there should be a separation
of debt management and monetary policy objectives
and accountabilities.” (Guideline 1.3). The same
Guideline also emphasised, “Debt managers,
fiscal policy advisors, and central bankers should share an understanding of the objectives of debt
management, fiscal, and monetary policies given
the interdependencies between their different policy
instruments” and “debt management, fiscal, and
monetary authorities should share information on
the government’s current and future liquidity needs.”
5.40 The recommended separation of the two
functions conditional upon the level of financial
development is important. As Blommenstein and
Turner (2011) explain, when monetary policy and
debt management frameworks become more
sophisticated, the central bank is able to influence
the spectrum of interest rates by acting only in the
very short end of the inter-bank market. With the
development of the local capital market, the central
bank’s role in developing the government securities
market becomes smaller. With the principal objective
of public debt management being to minimise
the risk-adjusted cost of long-term market-based
funding, the separation of the two functions then
becomes desirable as well as pragmatic.
Post-Crisis Experience: What has changed?
5.41 The perception about government debt
management changed in the context of the global
financial crisis. A Study Group (Chairman: Mr.
Paul Fisher) in May 2011, commissioned by
the Committee on the Global Financial System,
observed that the strength of the interactions
between sovereign debt management, monetary
policy and financial stability have increased in the
aftermath of the global financial crisis on account
of (i) a sharp increase in government deficit
and debt, reflecting fiscal stimulus programmes
to support economic recovery. In addition, the
average maturity of outstanding debt has declined
in a number of advanced economies; (ii) the use of
unconventional monetary policy, mainly in the form
of large-scale purchases of government securities of
varying residual maturities by central bank, thereby
blurring the zones of operation of the monetary
authority and the debt manager; (iii) the imposition
of new prudential liquidity requirements that have
increased the demand by banks and financial institutions for government securities, even as the
riskiness of government securities has increased in
some countries; and (iv) an increase in the foreign
ownership of government debt, facilitated by the
general process of liberalisation and globalisation.
5.42 As a consequence, decisions regarding
maturity, indexation and issuances as part of
sovereign debt management (SDM), which earlier
had limited impact on other policy areas, have begun
to significantly affect monetary policy and financial
stability.
Impact of Debt Management on Financial Stability
5.43 An increase in the share of short-term debt
(which cannot be easily inflated away, unlike long-term
debt) leads to an increase in refinancing and
rollover risks, particularly when investors (mostly
banks) hold only a small portion of government bonds
in their portfolios to maturity. This, in turn, sets off
systemic and financial stability risks. The problems
get amplified when the level of debt itself evokes
fiscal sustainability concerns. Foreign ownership
of government debt results in rapid transmission
of overseas shocks to the domestic G-Sec market
which can result in mark-to-market (MTM) losses
to the investors. Issuances of sovereign bonds in
foreign currencies expose governments to currency
mismatches between their domestic currency
denominated assets and partly foreign currency
denominated liabilities that have financial stability
implications.
Impact of Debt Management on Monetary Policy
5.44 An increase in short-term debt issuance
results in more intensive participation by the
government in the money market, which is the
operating area for monetary policy. This can interfere
with the setting of policy (short-term) interest
rates. Moreover, since central banks purchased
government bonds as part of their monetary policy
response to the financial crisis, the impact of debt
management on monetary policy was also felt at the
longer end of the market. This apart, a high level
of debt that triggers sovereign risk concerns (as in the case of some euro area countries) can dilute
the eligibility of government bonds as collateral
in monetary policy operations and, thus, impede
monetary policy transmission.
5.45 In this context, the Fisher Study Group
(2011) observed that the separation of sovereign
debt management (SDM) from other policy
functions is generally underscored in economies
with deep financial markets. This is in contrast with
the practice in developing economies, where the
central bank may issue securities for sterilisation
purposes or may manage the government’s debt
and cash balances, wherein policy co-ordination or
debt management by the central bank has generally
been the norm. The Study Group did not detect
substantive impediments engendered by the extant
arrangements for operational independence of
SDM and monetary policy functions. Altering such
arrangements, in the opinion of the Study Group
would be prone to risk. Rather, the Group felt that
in the present milieu, or where financial systems are
still developing, it would be useful if debt managers
took a broad view of cost and risk and central banks
kept abreast of SDM activities.
5.46 Recent experience has corroborated that
medium-term strategic outcomes for the maturity
structure and risk characteristics of outstanding
debt matter for financial stability. In this context,
the Study Group observed,“This underscores the
importance of close communication among the
relevant agencies, yet with each agency maintaining
independence and accountability for its respective
role. Such an approach is consistent with Principle
6 from the Stockholm Principles: Guiding principles
for managing sovereign risk and high levels of public
debt, which were recently promulgated by debt
managers and central bankers from 33 advanced
and emerging market economies.”
5.47 It is evident that the Fisher Study Group
(2011) and the Stockholm Principles (2010) have
stopped short of recommending the separation of
debt management out of the central bank. Even the
guidelines on public debt management issued by the
IMF-World Bank in 2003 (i.e., in the pre-crisis period) had recommended this separation conditional on
the level of financial development in the economy.
The difference between the two sets of views is
the recognition now of the closer inter-linkages
between government debt management, monetary
policy and financial stability and the concomitant
enhanced emphasis on close communication
between debt managers and central banks, even
while each agency maintains its independence and
accountability.
5.48 A similar case is made by Blommenstein
and Turner (2011). They argue that while policy
responses to the global financial crisis have led
to some blurring of the lines between public debt
management and monetary policy and that the
conventional microeconomic approach to debt
management is likely to conflict with macroeconomic
considerations, they caution against drawing any
implications for changing the extant responsibilities
of central bankers, debt managers and fiscal
authorities, which have the (proven) advantage
of assigning clear accountabilities and precluding
myopic policies. They indicate that any contemplated
change in the existing arrangements would,
however, benefit from a fuller understanding of and
consensus on the macroeconomics of government
debt management and the recognition about political
or institutional constraints as well as appropriate
governance mechanisms.
5.49 A different case is, however, made by
Goodhart (2010), who observes, “but now many
countries face the prospect of sharply rising
debt levels, to a point that may, once more,
test the confidence of market participants. Debt
management is again becoming a critical element
in the overall conduct of policy, as events in Greece
have evidenced. Debt management can no longer
be viewed as a routine function which can be
delegated to a separate, independent body. Instead,
such management lies at the cross-roads between
monetary policies (both inflation targets and
systemic stability) and fiscal policy. When markets
get difficult, and government bond markets are likely
to do so, the need is to combine an overall fiscal
strategy with high-calibre market tactics. The latter is what Central Banks have as their metier. During
the coming epoch of Central Banking, they should
be encouraged to revert to their role of managing
the National Debt.”
The Indian Case
5.50 Governor Subbarao (May 2011) has argued
that while the progress towards fiscal consolidation
and institutional developments in the pre-crisis
years indicated prospective efficiency gains from
separating out debt management from the central
bank to a DMO, in the post-crisis scenario, there is
a need to reconsider the content and pace of this
process. In this context, it is worth reiterating that the
RBI’s record of public debt management has been
impressive. As Governor Subbarao stated, “With the
average maturity of government debt at around 10
years, India has one of the longest maturity profiles
in the world, which proved to be a source of major
strength and comfort during the crisis.”
5.51 The Reserve Bank’s deft handling of debt
management operations during 2008-09 and 2009-
10, when the Indian economy faced the indirect
effects of the global financial crisis, has vindicated
its past record. In fact, by synchronising liquidity
management operations with those of exchange
rate management and non-disruptive internal debt
management operations, the RBI was able to
ensure that appropriate liquidity was maintained in
the system so that all legitimate requirements of
credit were met, particularly for productive purposes,
consistent with the objective of price and financial
stability. The liquidity injection efforts of the Reserve
Bank, despite being large, could be achieved without
compromising either on the eligible counterparties or
on the asset quality in the Reserve Bank’s balance
sheet, in contrast to many other central banks.
5.52 Liquidity expansion achieved through
unwinding (redemption, buy-back and de-sequestration)
of MSS and reduction in reserve
requirements (CRR) ensured that the Reserve Bank’s
balance sheet did not expand, again unlike in several
other central banks. In addition, auction-based
open market purchases of government securities were launched in February 2009 for more effective
liquidity management and the smooth conduct of
the government market borrowing programme. This
synchronisation of liquidity management, exchange
rate management and internal debt management,
particularly during periods of stress, was immensely
facilitated because these operations were housed
within the same organisation, even as monetary and
debt management remained functionally separate.
5.53 More generally, given the magnitude of the
government borrowing programme in India, debt
management becomes part of overall macroeconomic
management, rather than an exercise in resource
mobilisation. Consequently, central banks, which
have the overall perception, necessary expertise
and instruments, are better placed to conduct debt
management rather than a DMO with a limited
mandate. If, on the other hand, debt management
were to be shifted out of the central bank, conflict
resolution would become even more difficult as the
central bank would be expected to manage market
volatility and market expectations emanating from
the government borrowing programme. Finally, as
argued by the Chairman of the CFSA, the need to
harmonise the market borrowing programme of the
state governments – given its magnitude – with that of
the Centre and the political economy considerations
of the Indian federal structure, weakens the case for
separating out the debt management function from
the central bank.
5.54 Going forward, therefore, there is perhaps
a need to reconsider the proposed separation of
debt management out of the Reserve Bank at this
stage. Instead, the expertise at the Middle Office
that has already been set up in the Ministry of
Finance may be suitably enhanced to deal with the
post-crisis challenges that have been highlighted by
international experience and the research literature.
There is also a need for close co-operation between
the RBI and the Middle Office in matters relating to
debt management.
Cash Management
5.55 In recent years, the importance of sound
cash management, viz., managing the timing and volume of the government’s short-term cash
inflows and outflows in a cost-effective manner that
minimises various risks, such as operational, credit
and market risks, is increasingly being recognised.
Governments have been, accordingly, developing
a more sophisticated cash management function,
and, particularly in advanced economies, the trend
has been towards transiting from relatively passive
to more active cash management. Active cash
management aims at minimising idle cash balances
in the Treasury Single Account (TSA) maintained with
the central bank and maximising returns on excess
balances in the main treasury operational account
held at the central bank. Active cash management
involves financial market intervention by the
government cash manager (which could also be the
central bank) with the aim of smoothing the daily
mismatches in net cash flows and adding flexibility
to the ways in which the timing of government
cash inflows and outflows can be matched. Central
government cash management operations in India
too have undergone substantial reforms since the
mid-1990s (Box V.2).
5.56 The Government of India’s Internal Working
Group on Debt Management, 2008 (Chairman: Dr.
Jahangir Aziz) underscored the close relationship
between cash management and monetary policy
given that large inflows and outflows of cash to/from
government accounts can have a significant impact
on the money market. Further, treasury bills, which
are the usual instrument for cash management,
were observed to be a potential source of (i)
additional volatility in short-term interest rates
and (ii) interference with the signalling impact of
monetary policy. The Working Group also observed
that government cash management in India was
largely passive due to “a lack of end-day balance
management, presence of surplus funds in the form
of idle balances, and delay in the remit of cash
balance information to the Budget Division.”
5.57 The policy conflict and the passive nature
of cash management were stated to make a case
for moving government cash management to the
National Treasury Management Agency (NTMA).
International experience, however, revealed that government cash management usually migrates
to a debt management office at a later stage than
debt management, particularly because of the
daily and dynamic nature of the function. In this
context, observing that “cash management by the
NTMA may be difficult in the short-term because it
is operationally intensive, requires more staff and
close co-ordination between different agencies and
systems”, the Working Group recommended that
the present arrangements for government cash
management in India may be maintained in the
short-term and this function should gradually transit
to the NTMA over the medium-term.
Box V.2
Central Government Cash Management in India
The existing cash management operations of the
government are being undertaken through a two-tier
system, with commercial banks acting as the first tier and the
Reserve Bank [Central Accounts Section (CAS), Nagpur]
forming the second tier of the system. The arrangement
works through a system of accredited commercial banks
(accredited by Comptroller and Auditor General of
Accounts) with which different departments/ministries of the
Government of India maintain their accounts. All receipts
of the department/ministry are credited to the account
maintained by the accredited bank and the concerned bank,
in turn, is required to transfer them to the Treasury Single
Account (TSA) of the Government of India maintained at
CAS, Nagpur. Cash receipts are credited the same day,
while receipts by cheque are credited based on T+1 in case
of electronic mode, T+3 for locations (where the branch is
within the clearing zone) and T+5 (for outside locations).
In terms of the Second Supplementary Agreement signed
by the Reserve Bank and the Government of India on
March 6, 1997, automatic monetisation of the government’s
deficit was discontinued and replaced by a scheme of Ways
and Means Advances (WMA) and Overdraft (OD) to meet
the short-term funding requirements of the government,
effective April 1, 1997. If the cash balance of the government
slides below the minimum cash balance that it is required to
be maintained on any day (`100 million on any day, except
for every Friday, March 31 and June 30 when it is `1 billion),
a short-term advance is automatically extended by the
Reserve Bank to the government under its WMA facility, up
to a pre-announced limit that is usually fixed on a half-yearly
basis, to restore the cash balance to the minimum stipulated level. The advances under the WMA system are extended
at a mutually agreed rate of interest, currently at the Repo
Rate, and have to be repaid in full by the government within
three months. The Reserve Bank also provides an OD
facility to the government under which additional advances,
over and above the WMA limit, are made available at a
higher interest rate, which is currently at the Repo Rate plus
2 percentage points. The government is not allowed to be in
OD at a stretch for more than 10 consecutive working days.
Conversely, upto 2003-04, whenever the accounts of the
government showed a surplus position, funds in excess of
the minimum stipulated cash balances were automatically
invested in central government dated securities made
available by the Reserve Bank from its own portfolio. With
the depletion of government securities from the Reserve
Bank’s portfolio due to its sterilisation operations, the
Reserve Bank, in consultation with the government, placed
a limit on the investment of the surplus balance of the
Government of India. The ceiling is subject to the availability
of securities in the Reserve Bank’s portfolio after meeting
the requirement of securities arising from the Bank’s
monetary policy operations under the Liquidity Adjustment
Facility (LAF). The government surplus balance in excess
of the limit is kept as an idle cash balance with the Reserve
Bank at CAS, Nagpur and does not earn any interest.
Besides using treasury bills, the central government
introduced cash management bills (CMBs) in 2010-11
for cash management purposes. CMBs are non-standard
maturity instruments with all generic characteristics of
Treasury Bills. A large volume of CMBs were issued during
2011-12.
5.58 While government cash management would
continue to be vested with the RBI for some time,
further reforms are being contemplated. As the
Working Group on Operating Procedure of Monetary
Policy, 2011 (Chairman: Shri Deepak Mohanty)
observed, “Given the impact that government
cash balances have on liquidity management,
there is a need for closer co-ordination between
the RBI and the fiscal authority. In this context, the
Group understands that the issue of auctioning of
government cash balances is under consideration of
the Government and the RBI. The Group, therefore,
recommends that a scheme of auctioning of Government surplus cash balances at the discretion
of the RBI be put in place in consultation with the
Government to address a major source of volatility
in frictional liquidity in the system.”
Box V.3
Conflicts between Government Cash Management and Liquidity Management
Strains can emerge between cash management and
liquidity management if the government invests its surplus
cash balance in a market that is characterised by surplus
liquidity and the central bank does not have adequate
securities in its portfolio to mop up the excess liquidity or
the central bank is forced to issue its own securities (e.g.,
central bank bills) with implications for the central bank
balance sheet and the availability of surplus for transfer
to the government. Effective co-ordination between cash
management and monetary policy would involve the parking
of the idle surplus cash balance with the central bank, which
facilitates passive sterilisation of liquidity.
If the government is in cash deficit while the market is in
a surplus mode and the central bank and the government
use two different instruments (but of similar maturities) for
liquidity management and cash management, respectively,
market liquidity may get fragmented, thereby increasing
the illiquidity premium. For example, before 2004, Croatia’s
Ministry of Finance and the central bank each issued their
own bills. For similar maturity bills, the discount for T-bills
was about 8 per cent, while the discount for Central Bank
(CB) bills was only 1 per cent (Mu, 2006).
To avoid market fragmentation, a more appropriate option
would be to use add-ons to treasury bill auctions, as the
appropriate instrument for monetary policy implementation
(World Bank and International Monetary Fund, 2001).
Alternatively, or as complement, reissuance of existing
government dated securities issued earlier under the market
borrowing program can be considered if surplus liquidity is
perceived to be of a more durable nature. To avoid confusion
among the market participants, transparency needs to
be ensured by announcing the amount of add-ons by the
central bank for each treasury bill auction. Further, explicit
and well-defined arrangements should be made to ensure
that the proceeds from the sale of securities issued for the
purpose of liquidity management should not be available for
the financing of government expenditure but would remain
impounded in the central bank. Whether there should be
a cost-sharing agreement or whether the government will
meet the expenditure out of its budgetary resources would
need to be clearly specified. The exceptional circumstances
under which government balances could be utilised to
finance the fisc also need to be specified.
Many countries have issued government securities in the
past in place of central bank securities for the purpose
of liquidity management. These countries include Brazil
(since 2002), India (under MSS since 2004; the exceptional
circumstances under which sequestered government
balances could be utilised to finance the fisc was specified in 2008-09), Mexico, Croatia and Macedonia. In the UK,
the DMO and the Bank of England have agreed to such an
arrangement (although it has not been drawn on) (Williams,
2010). This process is reversed in Mozambique as the
central bank issues central bank bills from its own balance
sheet, but some of the stock can be hypothecated to the
government. In New Zealand, the central bank can issue
Treasury Bills at its own discretion (within a framework
agreed on with the Treasury) with the proceeds directly
passed to the government’s account. Cross-country
experiences indicate that these arrangements have not
worked satisfactorily in some countries, as the government
may not always be willing to issue additional Treasury Bills
for monetary policy purposes.
An alternative option would be for the central bank and the
Treasury to issue securities of different maturities. While the
central bank can issue short-term papers to absorb liquidity,
the Treasury may issue dated securities to fund its deficit.
In that event, the government may not have any cash
management tool to fund temporary liquidity mismatches.
In China and Indonesia, for example, the money market is
dominated by CB bills and the near absence of Treasury
Bills (Williams, 2010). The option of issuing short- and long-term
securities at low costs presumes the development
of a wide, deep and liquid government securities market.
Nonetheless, the conflict cannot be entirely avoided if
the residual maturity of government securities declines
to that of primary issuance of CB bills leading to market
fragmentation.
The government’s borrowing from the central bank can
also conflict with the central bank’s liquidity absorption
operations when the market operates in a surplus
mode. The government can modulate the auction size of
Treasury Bills or issue cash management bills to fund its
temporary cash mismatch. Hence, the policy option for
the central bank would be to use the same instrument
for liquidity management as used by the government for
its cash management operations, share information with
the government on its financing plan and, accordingly,
modulate the amount of Treasury Bills to be issued for the
purpose of liquidity absorption.
Cash Management and Volatility of Government Cash
Balances
One indicator of the successful co-ordination between cash
and liquidity management could be the ability of the DMO
and the central bank to limit the volatility of the government
balance at the central bank.
In the UK, the outstanding daily balance varied significantly
prior to the transfer in 2000 of the government’s day-to-day
sterling cash management from the Bank of England to the
DMO, which is an Executive agency of the Treasury. After
the transfer, borrowing from the Bank of England under the
‘Ways and Means’ facility was not used to facilitate day-to-day cash management and the balance was stable at
around £13.4 billion until the facility was repaid during 2008
(Cross et al., 2010). At the end of December 2008, at the
height of the global financial crisis, HM Treasury borrowed
temporarily from the Bank of England.
In the euro area, government deposits, aggregated at the
euro area level, have been the most volatile autonomous
factor, causing a large part of the errors in the forecast of
liquidity needs. In 2006, the highest volatility of government
deposits was experienced in Italy, followed by Spain, Ireland and Greece. Among these countries, debt management in
Italy and Spain are conducted departmentally within the
Ministry of Finance (MoF). In Greece, debt management
is conducted by an executive agency of the MoF, while
Ireland has a statutory DMO. In Belgium, Germany, France,
Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Austria, Portugal and
Finland, the volatility of government deposits is low. Among
these countries, while Austria, Germany and Portugal
have statutory DMOs, in Belgium, France, Luxembourg,
Netherlands and Finland, the DMOs are located in the
MoF. While countries that established statutory DMOs
(viz., Austria, Ireland, Portugal, Sweden, Germany,
Hungary, Slovakia and Ireland) are part of the European
Union, not all euro area countries have statutory DMOs/
independent agencies. Furthermore, the performance of
cash management by the DMO appears to be independent
of the institutional structure of debt management.
5.59 Even on the proposed auctioning of
government cash balances, more intensive co-ordination
between the government and the RBI may
be necessary not only because surplus balances of
the government with the Reserve Bank effectively
act as a (very useful) instrument of liquidity
management, but also because inter-institutional
conflicts can potentially be exacerbated, as shown
by international experience (Box V.3).
5.60 While the views from the government side
seem to favour the retention of cash management
with the RBI over the short-term, international
experience and the imperatives of liquidity
management in an emerging market country like
India, underscore the need for close co-ordination
between the RBI and the government on this matter,
as in the case of debt management.
IV. Concluding Observations
5.61 Fiscal-monetary policy dynamics in India
have changed significantly since the initiation of
reforms. While the Agreement on Ways and Means Advances (1997) has precluded the automatic
monetisation of fiscal deficits and the adverse fallout
of financial repression, the implementation of the
FRBM Act has taken this forward by prohibiting
the participation of the RBI in the primary market
for government securities and, more generally,
by placing a timeline on the reduction in fiscal
imbalances. Similarly, the institution of a full-fledged
LAF in June 2000 and the Market Stabilisation
Scheme in April 2004 have added to the traditional
arsenal of monetary policy instruments, such as
Open Market Operations and the CRR, to deal with
pressures emanating domestically (including the
fiscal side) as also from inherently volatile capital
flows. Following these institutional arrangements
on both the fiscal and monetary sides, the general
reduction in fiscal imbalances until 2007-08 was
accompanied by robust growth, moderate inflation
and lower order of volatility in the call money rate,
even as capital inflows increased sharply. The
challenges to fiscal-monetary co-ordination have,
however, become more complex in the aftermath of
the global financial crisis and the euro area crisis, as
it is being felt that central banks may henceforth have
to, at least partially, grapple with financial stability
and sovereign debt sustainability apart from being
exclusively responsible for price stability (Subbarao,
2012).
5.62 At the same time, with the liberalisation of
financial markets, the use of a plethora of policy
instruments (sometimes unconventional) and
taking cognisance of the increasingly important role
played by expectations, the interaction between
macroeconomic, including monetary and fiscal
variables has become complex. Nevertheless, the
empirical exercise conducted in this chapter showed
that the increase in fiscal deficit tends to put upward
pressure on the monetary policy rate, though with
some lag, even after controlling for the output gap
and inflation gap. In this context, a durable and
qualitatively superior correction in fiscal imbalances
would provide more headroom to monetary policy
to address growth and price stability objectives over
the medium-term.
5.63 The thinking on institutional arrangements for
the debt and cash management of the government
has also been subject to fresh debate in the context of the global financial crisis. With the intertwining
of debt management not only with monetary policy
but also with the maintenance of financial stability,
as revealed by international experience, the move
to separate government debt management from
the central bank has been questioned in several
forums. The lessons of the crisis clearly emphasise
the need for closer co-ordination between debt/cash
and monetary management. Moreover, the large
volume of central government market borrowings
would pose challenges to monetary management,
especially if private investment demand picks up.
Keeping in view the emerging economic situation
and the lessons of the global financial crisis, the
institutional arrangements for government debt
management in India over the medium-term would
require the continued involvement of the central
bank coupled with more intensive co-ordination with
the government.
|