The Economic Crisis and The State of Economics edited by
Rober Skidelsky and Christian Westerlind Wigstrom,
Palgrave-Macmillan, The United States of America, 2010. US$
55, pp 123.
‘…Good economists are scarce because the gift of using ‘vigilant
observation’ to choose good models, although it does not require a
highly specialized intellectual technique, appears to be a very rare
one...’
J M Keynes
The Telegraph from London reported on November 5, 2008 “…
during a briefing by academics at the London School of Economics
on the turmoil on the international markets the British Queen asked:
‘Why did nobody notice it ?’...” ‘..if these things were so large how
come everyone missed it...” These questions have been harping in the
minds of millions across the globe. A sense that the economists failed
to see the financial crisis brewing has led to soul searching among
many economists around the world, ever since the global financial
crises exploded. While some did warn that home prices were forming
a bubble, others confess to a widespread failure to predict the damage
the bubble would cause when it burst. Some economists are arguing
that a free-market bias in the profession, coupled with outmoded
and simplistic analytical tools, blinded to the danger. Dahlem report
condemned as growing reliance over the past three decades on
mathematical models that improperly assume markets and economies
are inherently stable, and which disregard influences like differences
in the way various economic players make decisions, revise their
forecasting methods and are influenced by social factors. There are
strong views that standard analysis also failed, in part, because of the
widespread use of new financial products that were poorly understood,
and because economists did not firmly grasp the workings of the
increasingly interconnected global financial system. Allen F (2009)
is of the opinion that ‘…economists used mathematical models that
failed to account for the critical roles that banks and other financial
institutions play in the economy…’ Further, he stated that they
simply didn’t believe the banks were important. Likewise, the global
financial crises, not only kicked up a lot of debate on the international
financial crisis per se, there are stronger views on market economy
stating as ‘moral crisis of capitalism’ and others often compared the
crises with the ‘Great Depression’. Predictably scores of conferences,
symposiums were conducted by different forums across the world to
seek explanations. This book is an outcome of collection of papers
presented in one such symposium organised in February 2009, partly
inspired by the general dissatisfaction with the silence of economics
profession on the causes of and the remedies for current economic
distress. The participants in the symposium were world reknown
economists, who came out with divergent views not only on the
causes of crises but also on the very subject ‘economics’. This book
is neatly edited and presented with all the conference papers in the
form of separate chapters.
The book is extremely interesting to read, scintillating and
thought provoking as well. There are ten chapters in all, which the
editors have aptly grouped under three broad heads, viz., Part I : Risk
and Uncertainty in Economics, Part II : Macro-Economics and the
Current Crisis and Part III: Models, Metaphors and Morals. Besides
the above, the editors eminently summarized the entire presentations
of papers and the discussion in the conference in the form of Chapter
1: Introduction. According to the editors, the three main themes
emerged from the papers and the discussions that followed are ‘the
question of whether future events are a matter of uncertainty rather
than risk; the impact of global macroeconomic imbalances; and the
role of economic models. These three main themes clearly emerges
out of the papers presented.
Paul Davidson in his paper ‘Risk and Uncertainty’ strongly
advocates a view of the future as irreducibly uncertain. Unlike in the
“hard sciences” such as physics or astronomy, in economics, there is
no foundation on which to base any probabilities about future events.
While astronomers can be reasonably confident that a planet will
appear in a predicted place at a predicted time the same cannot be said
about many subjects of interest to economists. Probabilities calculated
on past and current market data cannot be taken to hold about future
events since, as he argues, there is no way of knowing what social
and economic events will occur in the future. Thus, the future is not
“ergodic” - it is not predetermined. Yet, the ergodic axiom is at the
heart of key theories such as the efficient-market hypothesis which
states that markets determine price of the assets correctly based on
all available past and present information. Without the possibility of
assigning actuarial probabilities to future events, the value of assets
cannot be efficiently established. In effect, the efficient-market
hypothesis assumes that all uncertainty can be reduced to calculable
risk. The failure to recognize this fallacy has led to the bankruptcy
of major financial institutions such as AIG as well as a false sense of
security which paved the way for panic once the foundations trembled.
Therefore, Davidson makes a case for the introduction of a “market
maker” an institution that takes up responsibility for keeping the
market liquid in the face of unforeseeable events, in order to lessen
the effects of uncertainty. Sujoy Mukerji in his paper “Ambiguity
and Economic Activity Implications for the Current Crisis in Credit
Markets” reinforces Davidson’s view on irreducible uncertainty as
an explanation for the crisis. In situations of uncertainty it is often
the case that the decision maker’s knowledge about the probability
of contingent events is consistent with more than one possibility.
Under such conditions it is rational not to act. In financial markets this
leads to a situation in which more ambiguity results in less trade and
lending. In the words of the author : “…the uncertainty is triggered
by unusual events and untested financial innovations that lead agents
to question their worldview...” In the sense that, rather subjecting
investments to incalculable risks no investments are made at all and
instead, people hoard cash - an idea conforming to “Keynes’s liquidity
preference theory”. Therefore, the author concludes that the present
crisis can be understood as having erupted because of increasing
uncertainty amidst rapid financial innovation.Significantly, this also
corroborates an idea related to the discussion in Richard Bronk’s
chapter : Models and Metaphors. At some point investors and banks
withdrew their capital and credit, leaving consumers and companies
in lurch and ultimately themselves too. This suggests that a policy
promoting transparency and other uncertainty-reducing objectives
could mitigate the financial downturn and ease credit markets.
Therefore, we are in need of qualitative rather than quantitative easing.
Marc Potters, on the other hand, in his chapter on ‘Lessons from
Finance’ did not strongly dismiss the ability of economic modeling
to assign accurately probabilities to future events. He opines that,
the future is not exclusively characterised by irreducible uncertainty.
Potters further argues that, rather than facing a principal problem
with uncertainty, influential pricing models have typically relied
on assumptions too simple to have any relation to the reality they
seek to predict. For instance, the Gaussian process assumed in the
Black- Scholes option pricing model imply a disregard for the relative
frequency of extreme fluctuations observed in the empirical data. In
contrast to the assumptions of this model, volatility is not constant.
The invalidity of these assumptions implies that there can be no zerorisk
options as the model predicts. In other words, “option trading
involves some irreducible risk.” Moreover, conventional wisdom
in mathematical finance treats prices as “god-given,” yet feedback
loops indicate that this is fundamentally wrong. Large purchases of
assets increase their price thereby prompting further purchases, or
conversely decreasing prices result in investors selling thereby further
lowering the price. In effect, the financial crisis can be explained by
means of such a positive feedback loop. Under such circumstances
the degree of correlation among instruments changes, however, such
a consideration seldom included in financial mathematical models.
In practice, mathematical tractability and methodological consistency
have made these models attractive, despite their flaws.Significantly,
Potters also cautioned stating that ‘diversified portfolios do not
reduce risk as soon price movements are correlated’. However, if
the models were better understood and improved there is scope for
modeling to reduce the degree of uncertainty in the economy. The
problem is that a lot of people can make huge amounts of money
by not understanding the models they are using. This draws similar
opinions of Christopher Bliss in his chapter ‘Globalisation and the
Current Crisis’ who emphasised on asymmetric information. He
blamed bankers provide credit to investment projects they have only
very limited information about. Rating agencies and diversification
of asset portfolios are intended to reduce the risk associated with
asymmetric information, yet the rating agencies have incentives to
award higher ratings than deserved. Thus, according to Bliss, “market
function poorly, if they function at all, in situations characterized by
asymmetric information” and this problem is exacerbated when the
distinction between investment and retail banks is blurred and “safe”
deposits end up being used for speculation. It isSignificant to note
that, once the bubble bursts the crisis migrates quickly from finance
to the real economy. However, asymmetric information only explains
the speculative side of the crisis and does not explain how consumers
in the West could enjoy low inflation, cheap money and high profits at
the same time, all of these fuelled an unprecedented growth in credit.
Bliss argues further, that competition from East Asia, predominantly
China, was responsible for the present crisis. A Chinese “saving glut”
in the form of enormous investments in American Treasury Bills kept
the Chinese currency artificially low and made Chinese companies
super competitive. Cheap imports kept prices low while cheap
Chinese labor stifled the increase in Western real wages. In effect, the
resulting imbalances led to a situation in which East Asia financed
Western current account deficits. Vijay Joshi in his paper titled ‘Global
Imbalances’ takes a similar stand but of the view that the origins of the
Asian saving glut by referring to two projects; the creation of foreign
currency reserves as a precautionary buffer, the value of which the
East Asian countries understood after the 1997 financial crisis: and the
policy decision of these states to pursue export-led growth as a means
to economic development. Both of these missions were facilitated
by keeping their own currencies low relative to the reserve currency,
i.e. the dollar. Further, this was achieved by investing heavily in the
American credit markets. The ensuing macroeconomic imbalances
were not sustainable in the long run. Joshi further argued that if the
American house prices had not fallen, an adjustment process would
have started with a fall of the dollar. As a suggestion, Joshi advised
that in order to forestall similar bubbles appearing in future, central
banks, must look beyond consumer price indices as key indicators
of the health of the economy and need to look at asset and credit
price movements too. He also called for strengthening of key financial
institutions such as the IMF to prevent the creation of unsustainable
imbalances on an international level. The world needs a “neutral”
reserve currency and agreements on exchange rate regimes. Although
macroeconomic theory cannot be blamed for global imbalances, it
shows weakness in its inability to foresee these consequences. In part,
this weakness stems from reliance on inappropriate models.
John Kay in his chapter “Knowledge in Economics” emphasized
that ‘the test of an economic model is whether it is useful rather than
whether it is true’. He stated that one should not be concerned about
whether the efficient-market theory is true or not and in fact, he said
it is neither. Markets are often efficient but economists take this to
mean that they are always efficient. Information is included in prices
but it is not necessarily correctly weighted. The same goes for views
on risk as well. The ‘theory of subjective expected utility’ is neither
true nor false. Economic theories are metaphors and models and not
realistic descriptions. We need to be able to choose when to use which
metaphor. “The skill of the economist is in deciding which of many
incommensurable models one should apply in a particular context.”
Keynesian uncertainty which considers confidence, narratives and
degrees of belief in those narratives has all but become extinct and
yet Keynes’s perception of risk is no less important than the dominant
classical risk paradigm. He advised that economists need to be more
eclectic in the set of models they use. Otherwise will end up in the
situation described by Charles Goodhart in his chapter ‘Macro-
Economic Failures’ which describes how Dynamic Stochastic General
Equilibrium (DSGE) models work well in good times when default
rates on loans are low but badly in bad times. In part, he attributes
this weakness to the transversality condition which stipulates that an
economic agent has used all his resources and paid all his debts by the
time he dies. Further, he observed, that it hardly corresponds to the
reality. He underscored that amongst economists, a flawed but rigorous
theory often beats a correct but literary exposition and this has led to
an over confidence in markets based on rigorous but incorrect theories
such as the efficient market theory. However, there is a large difference
between what academic economists think and what businessmen do.
Given that economists and financial practionars accept that prices can
move away from fundamentals, it is absurd to count on the efficient
‘market theory’. Consequently, our standard macroeconomic models
which virtually everybody has been using, tell us absolutely nothing
about our present problems. This was also the strongest contest
by Richard Bronk’s paper : Models and Metaphors. Despite rapid
innovation which imparted dynamism and uncertainty, economists and
the businessmen rely heavily on equilibrium models. He concluded
with the remarks that world as we see it is to some extent, a creation of
our minds. Likewise models that we use structures the way we analyze
and interpret what we observe. In simple words ‘ones perspective
affects one’s view’ the tendency of the contemporary models to treat
uncertainty as risk has had huge consequences for the world economy
into crisis. This is similar to what Davidson and Mukherjee also stated.
Thus, Bronk concluded that there was something absurd in relying
so completely on risk models based on past data when bankers going
ahead with innovating newer products on weekly basis.
Lord Meghnad Desai in his Chapter : ‘Hayek : Another Perspective’
suggested that we should look at the ideas of Hayek to get better inkling
of the unfolding of recent events. Hayek combined Walras and Money to
explain business cycles. Credit creation by the banking system produces
overinvestment in relation to voluntary saving. The overinvestment
can be kept going only at the cost of increasing inflation. In such a
situation any increase in interest rates forces the banks stop lending
and cut down the existing loan sanctions. Which in turn makes the
investment projects to collapse and the economy contracts. According
to Hayek, as pointed out by Desai, there should not be build up of the
credit by the banks at thefirst count. Desai pointed out further, Hayek
was trying to talk about a crisis in terms of the banking system being
the principal source of trouble. The resent crisis was much in line with
what was visualized by Hayek long back. He suggest that there are
more models than just the Walrasian and Keynesian. Even in the case
of Keynes, there used to be multiple models out of Keynes, more than
we have today. Therefore, he suggests that it is time for practioners and
thinkers to dig out and ponder over Hayek’s philosophy.
The last chapter titled ‘Economics and Morals’ by Robert Skidelsky
is very interesting to read and it traces the subject ‘Economics’ from
the days of F Y Edgeworth 1881 who wrote that the first principle
of economics is that every agent is actuated by only ‘self interest’.
With varied definition of economics coming into existence Skidelsky
argued that what was mentioned as self interest by Edgeworth is
interpreted as ‘egoism’ according to him. Egoism remain implicit in
the method of economics, even if it no longer features explicit as a
first premise and it permeates the whole range of human purposes
right upto ‘spiritual’. In the sense, economists tend to treat all ends as
‘measureable’ and unfortunately assess them along single dimension.
In the process the diversity of human goods reduced to a series of
benefits of varying degrees of magnitude. In this context, he stated
Robbins is disingenuous in claiming that economics has ‘outgrown its
hedonistic origins’. However maintained that ‘…the Pig-Philosophy
may have proved all-embracing, but pig-philosophy it remains…’.
Ultimately the Author is of the view that the economic approach
cannot be valid as a general theory of human behavior.
In sum, the book is extremely interesting and a necessity for
reading by all students of economics, professional economists and
practicing policy makers. Those who believe strongly on the power
and utility of models and those who strongly question the utility of
such propositions, both need to read and understand where the fault
lies. The book as s whole is scintillating and thought provoking. I
must quote ‘…the beauty of General Theory of Employment, Interest
and Money was that it was ‘general’ enough to accommodate a
variety of “models” applicable to different states of expectations…’.
Therefore, it is absolutely necessary to choose the right models to
the right situation rather than rejecting the usefulness of models in
macroeconomics and finance.
Given their pre-eminence position in the field of economics, the
authors could have made more explicit suggestions/ precautions as to
how to prevent such crises of monstrous magnitude in future as that
would help for the readers and policy makers to take precaution.
A Karunagaran*
* Shri A. Karunagaran is Assistant Adviser in the Department of Economic and
Policy Research of the Bank.
|