Sarat Dhal1
This study evaluates the industry effects of monetary transmission mechanism in line
with the literature on disaggregated approach to policy transmission mechanism. The study
uses vector auto regression (VAR) model and monthly data from April 1993 to October 2011
pertaining to output growth of five use-based industries, call money rate and WPI inflation rate
for evaluating the transmission mechanism. The generalised accumulated impulse response
analysis from the VAR model showed that following a tight monetary policy shock, the
output growth could be affected more for capital goods and consumer durables than basic,
intermediate and consumer non-durable goods. Intermediate and consumer non-durable goods
could show a relatively moderate transient response and transmission lag could be evident
for the consumer non-durable goods. However, relatively wide asymptotic standard error
bands associated with the impulse responses could be reflecting uncertainty in the impact of
transmission mechanism.
JEL classification : E52, L60
Keywords : Monetary policy, industry effects, vector auto regression
Introduction
In recent years, trends in the growth of industrial production in
the Indian context have given rise to various concerns, notwithstanding
the discussion over data quality and turbulent period of the global
crisis. Should the industry sector be accorded policy attention by the
authorities, especially from the perspective of monetary policy? How
does monetary policy affect the industry sector? Answers to these
questions, prima facie, cannot overlook some stylised facts. In the
year 2011-12, the industry sector, comprising mining, manufacturing,
and electricity, gas and water supply, accounted for 18.3 per cent of GDP at factor cost at current prices, as compared with the shares of
agriculture and services sectors at 17.2 per cent and 64.5 per cent,
respectively. However, the industry sector played a dominant role in
the Indian economy in various other ways including investment (or
capital formation) activities, economy-wide gross output or aggregate
economic transaction, inter-sectoral intermediate demand, merchandise
trade, employment and bank credit in the organised sector. Firstly, the
national accounts statistics (NAS) for 2010-11 showed that the industry
sector accounted for 41.0 per cent of economy-wide gross domestic
capital formation, closer to services sector’s share 51.0 per cent and
substantially higher than the agriculture sector’s share 8.0 per cent.
Secondly, the Input-Output transaction Table 2006-07 showed that the
secondary sector led by industries accounted for 40 per cent of economywide
gross output or economic transaction as compared with the shares
of 47 per cent and 13 per cent for services sector and ‘agriculture and
allied activities’, respectively. The secondary sector accounted for the
bulk 58 per cent of aggregate inter-industry intermediate demand for
goods and services, reflecting its backward and forward linkages with
other sectors. Thirdly, according to the balance of payments (BOP)
accounts 2011-12, merchandise and invisibles items accounted for
58.5 per cent and 41.5 per cent of India’s exports of goods and services
in the current account, respectively. Exports of manufactured goods
accounted for the bulk of merchandise exports with a share of 61.3 per
cent. In 2011-12, imports of industrial inputs accounted for 51.0 per
cent of India’s total merchandise imports and 73.5 per cent and 89.9
per cent of non-oil imports and non-oil and non-gold-silver imports,
respectively. Fourthly, according to the NSSO Report on employment
and unemployment survey 2009-10, there were 545 persons for every
1000 persons employed in non-agricultural activities. The industry sector
accounted for 22 per cent of employment in the non-agricultural sector.
Fifthly, industry sector comprising small, medium and large enterprises
accounted for 45.8 per cent of gross non-food credit, leaving 12.2 per cent
for agriculture and 42.0 per cent for other sectors, respectively. Finally,
from the perspective of business cycle, a principal component analysis
of GDP in terms of growth rate of broad sectors such as agriculture,
industry and services reveals the crucial role of industry sector. The
first principal component based on ordinary correlations could be associated
with similar loadings (weights) to industry and services sectors (Annex 1).
The above stylised facts persuaded this study for analysis of
monetary transmission mechanism for India’s industry sector. At
this juncture, however, a mute question arises. Should the empirical
analysis be confined to monetary implications for the industry sector
at the aggregate level? This is an important issue because the industry
sector is heterogeneous in nature in terms of product composition
varying from salt and pepper to heavy transport machinery and
aeronautics, agro-based products to resource based minerals, metal
products and chemicals and used-based consumer durable and nondurable
goods to basic goods, capital goods and intermediate goods.
From this perspective, the study derives inspiration from the literature
on disaggregated monetary transmission mechanism. According to this
literature, it is important to understand how the effects of change in
policy instruments pass through the economy, which sectors respond
first to a policy innovation and whether the effects could be more
pronounced in some sectors than others. A comparison of the monetary
impact across different sectors may provide valuable information for
policy purposes (Ganley and Salmon, 1997). In the study, the analysis
is focused on monetary transmission mechanism for five use-based
industries. Using the standard VAR model and monthly data for the
sample period April 1993 to October 2011, the study finds that the
output growth response to monetary policy shock could be higher for
consumer durables and capital goods industries than basic, intermediate
and consumer non-durable goods. Intermediate goods industries could
exhibit a muted response whereas consumer non-durables could exhibit
moderate transitory response accompanied by lags in the transmission
mechanism. These findings are expected to provide crucial information
for policy purposes. The remainder of the paper is organised in five
sections comprising review of literature, methodology and data,
empirical findings and conclusion.
Section II
Review of Literature
The subject of monetary transmission mechanism has witnessed a
paradigm shift over the years. For the first three to four decades during
the post World War II period, economists adhered to the IS-LM type aggregate macroeconomic model for evaluating the role of monetary
policy in economic stabilisation through aggregate output growth and
price inflation. Within this framework, it was postulated that policy
induced changes in monetary variables could affect aggregate demand
and consequently, the growth of economy-wide measure of output such
as real gross domestic product and the inflation in the aggregate price
index. This characterisation of the monetary transmission mechanism
was later construed as a ‘black box’ view, as it did not tell about what
happened in the interim in the transmission of policy shocks to the real
economy (Bernanke and Gertler, 1995). Thus, the more recent literature
on monetary transmission mechanism has embraced disaggregated
analyses for a better understanding of how monetary variables affect
various components of aggregate demand such as consumption,
investment and trade and economic activities across firms, industries,
sectors and regions within and across the nations. Studies in this
tradition are inspired by the seminal works on asymmetric information,
market imperfection and moral hazard by Stiglitz and Weiss (1981)
and the credit channel comprising balance sheet channel (Bernake and
Gertler, 1995) and the bank lending channel (Kashyap etal.1993 and
Kashyap and Stein 1995). Also, several other studies emphasising on the
heterogeneous characteristics of producing sectors pertaining to product
composition, production technology reflecting upon the intensity of
labour and capital inputs, financial structure of firms, openness to trade,
wage contracts and flexibility in product prices have contributed to the
growth of disaggregate analysis of monetary transmission mechanism
[Ahmed (1987), Ahmed and Miller (1997), Angeloni, et al. (1995),
Bernanke and Blinder (1988), Bernanke and Gertler (1995), Dale and
Haldane (1995), David et al. (2000), Dedola and Lippi (2000), Ganley
(1996), Ganley and Salmon (1997), Gertler and Gilchrist (1994), Gaiotti
and Generale (2001), Hayo and Uhlenbrock (1999), Kandil (1991),
Kashyap et al. (1993), Kashyap and Stein (1995), Kretzmer (1989),
Loo and Lastrapes (1998), Shelley and Wallace (1998), Peersman
and Smets (2005)]. In the Indian context, studies in this tradition are
scarce. Dhal (2012) provided an analysis of regional aspect of monetary
transmission mechanism in terms of credit dispersion to states in the
Indian context. Theoretical and empirical studies on disaggregated
transmission mechanism focused on the industry sector provide various
perspectives as discussed briefly in the following.
Firstly, the credit channel of transmission mechanism provides an
explanation of differential effect of monetary transmission mechanism
for firms and industries. Bernanke and Gertler (1995) provided
explanation that monetary policy could affect the small firms differently
from the large firms. The credit channel perspective on firm size
implications for monetary transmission mechanism could be extended
to the industry level analysis. Illustratively, basic, capital and consumer
durable goods industries could be characterised with a concentration
of large firms whereas intermediate and consumer non-durable goods
could be characterised with several small firms. According to the
credit channel, financial structure or leverage structure of small firms
could be different from that of large firms. In this context, the financial
accelerator theory of the monetary transmission mechanism states that
asymmetric information between borrowers and lenders could give
rise to an external finance premium, which typically depends on the
net worth of the borrower. A borrower with higher net worth could
be capable of posting more collateral and thereby, reduce its cost of
external financing. As emphasised by Bernanke and Gertler (1989),
the dependence of the external finance premium on the net worth of
borrowers creates a “financial accelerator” propagation mechanism.
A policy tightening will not only increase the cost of capital through
the conventional interest rate channel, it will also lead to a fall in
collateral values and cash flow, which will tend to have a positive effect
on the external finance premium. Moreover, since collateral values
and cash flows are typically low in a recession, the sensitivity of the
external finance premium to changes in interest rates will be higher
in recessions. Small firms, due to limited access to capital market and
external borrowing, are likely to be more dependent on bank credit than
large firms. Therefore, monetary policy involving contractions in bank
credit and increased interest rate may affect expenditure by small firms
more than the large firms. However, an alternative perspective is also
maintained by several researchers. Due to large financing requirement
at medium and longer horizons for investment activity, large firms may
attach greater importance to credit and interest burden than smaller
firms.
Secondly, the capital-labour intensity of production provides
another explanation (Hayo and Uhlenbrock, 1999, Berument etal.,
2004, Ganley and Salmon, 1997). This perspective derives from Tobin’s
(1960) work relating to money in the neoclassical growth model. In
Tobin’s model, real money balance was postulated to affect capitallabour
intensity in production, and thus, output growth. Deriving from
this hypothesis, researchers argue that capital goods industries are likely
to be associated with longer gestation lags, sufficiently large investment
requirement and larger amount of credit with longer-maturity and higher
interest rates than consumer goods. Thus, the causal nexus of monetary
variables such as credit and interest rates with consumer goods and
investment goods may not be similar. Berument etal. (2004) showed
that an increase in interest rates affected the capital-intensive sectors
more than labor-intensive ones. Similarly, Ganley and Salmon (1997)
in a study of the UK economy showed that manufacturing, construction,
distribution and transportation, exhibited the largest output responses to
a monetary shock. Financial services and utilities responded relatively
little to the monetary shock. The mining sector’s response was
somewhat erratic and ambiguous and the agricultural sector’s response
was insignificant.
Thirdly, there is an inventory adjustment perspective (Benito,
2002, Ehrmann and Ellison, 2002, Kashyap etal. 1994,Gertler and
Gilchrist,1994). According to Ehrmann and Ellison (2002), the
progress in production technology in terms of greater flexibility due
to just-in-time production, lean manufacturing and improved inventory
management enable firms to adjust their production levels more
quickly, easily and at lower cost. Greenspan (2001) recognised that new
technologies for supply-chain management and flexible manufacturing
imply that businesses can perceive imbalances in inventories at an early
age, virtually in real time, and can cut production promptly in response
to the developing signs of unintended inventory building. Kashyap etal
(1994) found for the US that the inventory investment of firms without
access to public bond markets was significantly liquidity-constrained
during the 1981-82 and 1974-75 recessions, in which tight money also
appeared to have played a role. Gertler and Gilchrist (1994) examined
movements in sales, inventories, and short-term debt for small and large manufacturing firms and confirmed that the effects of monetary
policy changes on small-firm variables were greater when the sector as
a whole was growing more slowly.
Fourthly, in terms of product characteristics, studies have examined
the sensitiveness of durable goods to monetary policy as compared with
non-durable goods (Mishkin 1976, Jung and Yun 2005, Haimowitz,
1996, Kretzmer,1989, Ganley and Salmon,1997, Hayo and Uhlenbrock,
2000 and Dedola and Lippi, 2000, Peersman and Smets,2002, Drake and
Fleissig, 2010, Erceg and Levin, 2002). Mishkin (1976) addressed the
neglected illiquid aspect of the consumer durable asset. He suggested
that increased consumer liabilities are a major deterrent to consumer
durable purchases and increased financial asset holdings a powerful
encouragement. Monetary policy was found to have a strong impact
on consumer durable expenditure through two additional channels of
monetary influence. One, monetary policy affects the price of assets
in the economy. Consumer financial asset holdings, thereby, affected
expenditure on durables. Two, past monetary policy will have affected
the cost and availability of credit, thus influencing the size of consumers’
debt holdings and hence consumer durable expenditure. Kretzmer
(1989) suggested that unanticipated money could more likely display
non-neutrality in the durable goods sector as agents spend unanticipated
increases in their money holdings on goods which provide consumption
services over time. Peersman and Smets (2002) showed the demand for
durable products, such as investment goods, much more affected by a
rise in the interest rate through the usual cost-of-capital channel than
the demand for non-durables.
Fifthly, some industries may be producing more tradable goods
than others catering to domestic demand. Here, the transmission
mechanism could be influenced by the openness of the economy through
monetary policy impact on exchange rate, capital flows and export and
import prices (Berument etal. 2007). In a study of European countries,
Llaudes (2007) found the tradable sector showing a higher degree of
responsiveness to monetary policy shocks than the non-tradable sector
and emphasised on the importance of industrial structure for the analysis
of monetary policy.
Section III
Methodology and Data
For the empirical analysis, we follow the literature and use
standard vector auto regression (VAR) model. Due to the popularity of
VAR model, we refrain from rehashing the model’s technical details.
However, it is useful to highlight some applied issues relating to the
VAR model for aggregated transmission mechanism as compared with
the disaggregated model.
Firstly, for the aggregate transmission mechanism, researchers
generally use a VAR model comprising three endogenous variables;
an indicator of output growth, aggregate price inflation and the
monetary policy variable, typically, the short-term interest rate. In
principle, a VAR model is a reduced form of a structural model and
residuals from the reduced form model cannot be considered as pure
innovations. Accordingly, a meaningful analysis of impulse response
and forecast error variance decomposition cannot be possible with a
reduced form VAR model. It is in this context that researchers rely
on orthogonalization of residuals from the reduced form VAR model.
Orthogonalized innovations have two principal advantages over nonorthogonal
ones: (i) because they are uncorrelated, it is very simple
to compute the variances of linear combinations of them, and (ii) it
can be rather misleading to examine a shock to a single variable in
isolation when historically it has always moved together with several
other variables. Orthogonalisation
takes this co-movement into account.
The greatest difficulty with orthogonalisation is that there are many
ways to accomplish
it, so the choice of one particular method is not
innocuous. Researchers, however, often rely on Choleski factorization
involving a lower triangular variance-covariance matrix of VAR
residuals for deriving orthogonal shocks to the endogenous variables.
The Choleski decomposition is sensitive to the ordering of variables
in the VAR model when residuals are correlated. Studies on standard
monetary transmission mechanism prefer output, inflation and interest
rate variables appearing in order. In this way, the orthogonal innovations
are justified with a structural identification of shocks to variables based
on macroeconomic postulates such as technology shock driving output growth, Philips curve describing inflation and output relationship and
a monetary policy reaction function associated with output growth and
inflation. In the case of disaggregated model involving more than three
variables and more than one sectoral output indicators in particular,
structural identification of shocks becomes extremely complicated and
the straightforward Choleski factorization may not be meaningful.
Illustratively, for a VAR model with seven variables comprising interest
rate, inflation, and output growth of five use-based industries, the
ordering choice becomes complicated with respect to which industry
sector should precede or follow other sectors. On the statistical ground,
one could find a solution through Granger’s causality among the output
indicators. However, such causal ordering may not be consistent with
the real world and the underlying technological relationship among
producing sectors. In this context, we followed Pesaran and Shin
(1998) who suggested that the generalized impulse response analysis,
which is free from ordering of variables in the model, could provide a
meaningful alternative to impulse response analysis.
Secondly, a peculiar feature of time series models such as the VAR
pertains to its sensitivity to measurement of variables, data frequency,
and the sample period. In the Indian context, monetary policy works
through both quantity (liquidity management) and interest rate channels.
Both effects are expected to affect the interbank call money rate in the
same direction. Illustratively, a tight liquidity and an increase in the
short-term policy rate such as the repo rate are expected to push up
the call money rate and vice versa for easy liquidity and decline in
the repo rate. For this purpose, we use monthly data for the weighted
average interbank call money rate as the policy variable. The aggregate
price variable is measured by year-on-year WPI inflation rate based
on monthly data2. Similarly, the monthly data on output variables are
used for deriving annualised or year-on-year growth rate of seasonally
adjusted index of industrial production for five use-based industries.
There are two principal reasons for using output growth and inflation
rate variables. First, there is an information perspective relating to economic agents’ consumption, investment and production decisions
and expectation formation process. The official source in India like the
Central Statistical office releases monthly data on price and production
indices in levels as well as year-on-year percentage increases. However,
the year-on-year percentage increase in WPI index, i.e., inflation rate
and the year-on-year percentage increase in industrial output indices
or growth rates contribute to the headline news. From this perspective,
it makes sense to emphasise that economic agents’ behavior and
expectations could be influenced by information that is available,
interpreted and understood. Secondly, the rate variables enable us to
work with a VAR model comprising stationary variables. In our case,
we found the variables stationary based on ADF and PP unit root tests.
The empirical exercise with level variables (after long transformation
of the price and output indices) will have to contend with non-stationary
variables and require vector error correction and co-integration (VECM)
model. However, the VECM model may involve multiple long-run cointegrating
relationships among the variables, requiring identification of
the multiple equilibrium trajectories in line with theoretical postulates,
which may not be unique. Thus, it is useful to consider a VAR of
stationary variables when the purpose is to understand the dynamic
interaction among the variables. Moreover, the VAR model is also
capable of reflecting upon the short-run and medium-longer horizon
responses of variables to various types of shocks.
Thirdly, for a VAR model, the common lag length for the endogenous
variables assumes critical importance. In this context, empirical studies
often have to contend with alternative scenarios deriving from different
lag selection criteria. Like other studies, we also faced difficulties in this
regard. Some lag selection criteria like Schwartz Information Criterion
(SIC) and Hannan and Quinn (HQ) criteria show lower lags (in our case
2 to 3 months) while others including Likelihood ratio(LR), adjusted
LR and Akaike’s Final prediction Error (FPE) show higher lags (in our
case 13 months). A lower lag length, however, could not ensure VAR
residuals free from serial autocorrelation problem, especially, of first
order which is a serious problem for statistical modeling. According
to Lutkepohl etal. (2006), the lower lag length in this context could be
inadequate to capture the underlying dynamic interaction among the variables in the VAR model. On the other hand, a model with a higher
lag length, though appropriate to capture the underlying dynamic
interaction among the variables, could suffer from over parameterisation
and efficiency. Nevertheless, most of the empirical studies in the
transmission mechanism literature prefer full lag length, i.e., 4 to 5 lags
for quarterly data and 12 to 13 lags for monthly data. Thus, in our study
based on monthly data, we preferred 13 lags for the models in line with
AIC and the empirical tradition.
Fourthly, the period-by-period impulse responses may appear
obscure and lack smoothness due to large number of lags and high
frequency monthly data. In this context, given the purpose of assessing
the total impact of monetary policy shocks on output growth and inflation
over different shorter and medium term horizons, an alternative approach
entails accumulated impulse responses over different forecast horizon
for the VAR model (Lutkepohl, 1990). We examined the cumulative
impulse response over the time horizon spanning 1 to 60 months (five
year) as this is consistent with the business cycle literature which
maintains a typical business cycle spanning a period 2 to 5 years.
Section IV
Empirical Findings
For the empirical analysis, we adopted a structured approach by
estimating the VAR model with alternative combinations of endogenous
variables and some exogenous variables in order to provide robustness
to the findings. Before moving to the empirical findings, we bring
some further facts about the use-based industries in order to facilitate
the analysis and interpretation of the industry effects of monetary
transmission mechanism.
Firstly, the weights assigned to different use-based industries and
the product compositions within each industry group provide some
interesting insights. In the construction of index of industrial production,
the highest weight is given to basic goods (46 per cent), followed by
consumer non-durables (21 per cent), intermediate goods (16 per cent),
capital goods (9 per cent) and consumer durables (8 per cent). Annex
2 shows top fifteen products in each user-industry group along with
their weights. The distribution of weights reflects the concentration of activities across the industry groups. Basic goods and consumer durables
sectors show higher concentration of weights. This is reflected in top
fifteen items accounted for 82 per cent, and 90 per cent of the respective
sector’s weight whereas these figures stood at 64 per cent, 55 per cent
and 66 per cent, respectively for capital goods, intermediate goods and
consumer non-durables (Annex 2). In the basic goods group, two most
important items were mining minerals (31 per cent) and electricity (23
per cent) – the utility sector mostly under the public sector, accounting
for more than fifty per cent of the basic goods sector and a fifth of the
total industry sector’s weight.
Secondly, the growth dynamics of use-based industries showed
that during the sample period the mean growth rate was highest for
the consumer durables followed by capital goods, intermediate goods,
consumer non-durables and basic goods (Table 1). In terms of volatility,
i.e., standard deviation of growth rate, capital goods were most volatile
followed by consumer durables, consumer non-durables, intermediate
goods and basic goods. The volatility in industry output growth was
also corroborated by maximum and minimum growth rates, reflecting
sharper fluctuations in capital goods and consumer durables than other
sectors.
Table 1: Summary Statistics of Industry Growth Rate |
|
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
ZQS |
Sector Weight |
46 |
9 |
16 |
8 |
21 |
100 |
Mean |
5.88 |
11.70 |
7.19 |
14.40 |
6.16 |
7.50 |
Median |
5.62 |
9.89 |
6.68 |
13.65 |
5.63 |
7.10 |
Maximum |
15.21 |
62.15 |
27.08 |
56.63 |
33.82 |
20.40 |
Minimum |
-2.18 |
-26.58 |
-7.72 |
-17.76 |
-20.75 |
-7.25 |
Std. Dev. |
3.46 |
15.40 |
5.51 |
11.97 |
6.86 |
4.58 |
Weighted contribution to overall Industry sector’s growth |
36 |
14 |
15 |
17 |
18 |
100 |
Third, the weighted contribution of use-based industries to the
overall industry sector’s growth provides another interesting insight. The contributions of capital goods and consumer durables to the
industry sector’s growth were higher than their weights, unlike basic
goods, intermediate goods, and consumer non-durables. The weighted
contribution of use-based industries to overall industry sector’s growth
turned out almost evenly distributed when we considered three groups,
i.e., i) basic goods, (ii) capital goods and consumer durables and (iii)
intermediate and consumer non-durables.
IV.1 The Aggregate Approach
Beginning with the aggregate analysis, we worked with a VAR
model comprising variables, namely, the growth rate of general index
of industrial production, the WPI inflation, the interest rate, and the
interest rate (the call money rate). The accumulated generalised
impulse responses of output growth and WPI inflation rates to one
standard deviation shock to call money rate are shown in Annex 3. It
was evident that a tight money policy through a positive one standard
deviation shock to the call money rate led a decline in output growth
and inflation rates. The impact was found moderate for the first six
months and accentuating thereafter to reach a cumulative peak around
4 year horizon. The negative impact on the inflation rate occurred
with a lag of 3-months but the output growth responded quickly in
this manner after one month. Overall, however, responses of inflation
rate and output growth appeared similar over medium term horizon. A
critical perspective derives from the standard error bands associated
with the impulses responses. The standard error bands associated with
impulses responses of output growth and inflation variables turned out
wider especially over the medium horizon, suggesting the uncertainty
over the impact of policy shock. As we shall see later, this finding also
held for the disaggregated VAR models. In this context, it is useful to
consider the suggestions of Lutkepohl (1990): despite the substantial
estimation uncertainty, impulse responses with expected sign are useful
for qualitative analysis. Large estimation uncertainty is the price that
has to be paid in VAR analysis for not forcing possibly false a priori
structure on the system.
IV.2 Disaggregated Models
Moving to the disaggregated model, we considered first the VAR
model (Model 1) comprising six variables, the interest rate and the
output growth rates of five use-based industries. The impulse responses
of sectoral output growth to call money rate shock is shown in Annex
4 and summarised in Table 2. Here, a couple of interesting insights
emerged. One, a decline in the output growth following the tight money
policy was associated with basic, capital, intermediate and consumer
durable goods. However, consumer non-durables showed a transmission
lag as the decline in output growth occurred after 8 months. Two,
different sectors showed different peaks and maximum adverse impact
due to the tight money policy shock. The maximum adverse impact was
observed for the capital goods followed by consumer durables, basic
goods, consumer non-durables and intermediate goods. Three, the peak
period of cumulative maximum adverse impact (after which the policy
shock faded away with no adverse impact) occurred over the period
of 3-year horizon for consumer durables, followed by capital goods
(2-years) and basic goods (one and half year). Intermediate goods and
consumer durables were associated with moderate impact for shorter
horizon of about a year.
Table 2: Impact of One Standard deviation Shock to Call Rate: Accumulated Responses of Output growth (Model without Inflation Rate) |
Period |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
1 |
-0.31 |
-0.81 |
-0.12 |
-0.07 |
0.26 |
6 |
-0.76 |
-6.15 |
-0.37 |
-5.36 |
1.77 |
7 |
-1.17 |
-7.09 |
-0.35 |
-7.53 |
2.20 |
8 |
-1.46 |
-8.19 |
-0.26 |
-9.28 |
2.48 |
10 |
-2.08 |
-11.69 |
-0.61 |
-11.62 |
1.31 |
12 |
-2.66 |
-15.40 |
-0.15 |
-14.19 |
0.54 |
13 |
-2.54 |
-17.07 |
0.18 |
-14.70 |
-0.37 |
18 |
-3.29 |
-23.73 |
1.82 |
-16.81 |
-1.96 |
20 |
-3.21 |
-25.71 |
2.48 |
-16.55 |
-2.40 |
25 |
-3.08 |
-27.29 |
3.70 |
-16.70 |
-1.78 |
37 |
-1.80 |
-25.57 |
3.14 |
-18.91 |
0.56 |
60 |
-1.35 |
-21.06 |
5.45 |
-15.37 |
1.24 |
Generalised Impulse |
IV.2.1 Model with Aggregate Price Inflation
In the Model 1, we did not include the inflation rate. However,
monetary policy can affect inflation expectation and consequently,
aggregate demand and supply conditions and real activity. Thus,
we moved to the VAR model (Model 2) with WPI inflation as an
endogenous variable in addition to the interest rate and sectoral
output growth variables. The impulse responses of sectoral output
in response to tight money policy shock are shown in Annex 5 and
summarised in Table 3.
Table 3: Impact of One Standard deviation Shock to Call Rate: Accumulated Responses of Output growth and inflation rate
(Model with WPI Inflation Rate as an endogenous variable) |
Period |
ZINF |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
1 |
0.00 |
-0.37 |
-0.82 |
-0.09 |
0.05 |
0.17 |
8 |
-1.73 |
-2.25 |
-7.88 |
-0.94 |
-10.23 |
2.28 |
12 |
-3.47 |
-4.18 |
-14.93 |
-1.55 |
-16.91 |
-0.09 |
31 |
-8.64 |
-8.81 |
-29.16 |
-2.77 |
-32.02 |
-4.50 |
33 |
-8.78 |
-8.95 |
-29.39 |
-3.40 |
-33.54 |
-4.30 |
38 |
-8.88 |
-8.58 |
-30.44 |
-4.56 |
-35.54 |
-4.15 |
40 |
-8.83 |
-8.52 |
-30.00 |
-4.82 |
-35.85 |
-3.99 |
41 |
-8.77 |
-8.49 |
-29.98 |
-4.78 |
-36.06 |
-3.77 |
60 |
-8.76 |
-8.05 |
-23.94 |
-2.91 |
-31.60 |
-2.38 |
Generalised Impulse |
The empirical findings from the Model 2 show some similarity
as well as some notable departures from the Model 1. One, basic
goods, capital goods, consumer durables and intermediate goods
showed a decline in output growth following tight money policy
shock while consumer non-durables showed a transmission lag.
Moreover, consumer durables and capital goods were affected more
than the three other sectors. Two, a comparison of the Model 2 (with
inflation) with the Model 1 (without inflation) showed that all five
use-based industries witnessed an accentuation of the maximum
adverse impact on output growth due to tight money policy shock
in the presence of inflation variable. Three, some sectors witnessed
a significant increase in the time horizon for the adverse output effect; from 18 months (Model 1) to 33 months (Model 2) for basic
goods and from 10 months to 40 months for the intermediate goods
sector. Similarly, consumer non-durables also showed an increase
in the time horizon of declining output response from one year
(between 8-20 months) to two year horizon (between 8-31 months).
Four, consumer durables witnessed maximum impact followed by
capital goods in Model 2 unlike the capital goods being impacted
more than consumer durables in the Model 1.
IV.2.2 Model with Exogenous Supply Shocks
In the Indian context, the sharp fluctuation in inflation condition
often occurs due to supply shocks arising from the movement in
the prices of oil and food commodities. Empirical studies generally
consider such supply shocks as exogenous in nature as they could
not be affected by policy intervention. From this perspective, we
estimated VAR model (Model 3) with oil price inflation and food price
inflation as exogenous variables. The impulse responses of sectoral
output growth to call money rate shock are summarised in Annex 6 and
Table 4. A couple of notable findings emerged from the comparison of
Model 3 with Model 2. One, all sectors witnessed a moderation in the
maximum adverse output effect due to tight money policy shock in the
presence of oil price and food price inflation variables. This suggested
that supply shocks may not accelerate the monetary impact on real
activity. Two, at the same time, Model 3 showed consumer durables
with higher impact than capital goods, similar to Model 2. However,
the difference between the magnitudes of maximum impact for these
two sectors in Model 3 was significantly higher than the Model 2. In
other words, a model without controlling for supply shocks could show
some overreaction in the growth response of capital goods to policy
shock. This is a critical finding because capital goods have implications
for overall capacity building and long-run growth trajectory of the
economy.
Table 4: Impact of One Standard deviation Shock to Call Rate: Accumulated Responses of Output growth and inflation rate
(Model with Exogenous Oil and Food Inflation) |
Period |
ZINF |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
1 |
-0.02 |
-0.36 |
-0.65 |
-0.15 |
0.02 |
0.20 |
8 |
-2.09 |
-1.89 |
-4.78 |
-0.50 |
-9.74 |
2.34 |
9 |
-2.49 |
-2.24 |
-5.78 |
-0.55 |
-11.32 |
1.56 |
12 |
-3.65 |
-3.49 |
-9.51 |
-0.25 |
-15.08 |
-0.08 |
24 |
-6.95 |
-6.27 |
-18.55 |
1.29 |
-21.68 |
-5.00 |
33 |
-8.67 |
-7.09 |
-16.88 |
-1.75 |
-27.33 |
-5.09 |
37 |
-8.64 |
-6.72 |
-15.07 |
-2.56 |
-28.22 |
-5.23 |
40 |
-8.30 |
-6.57 |
-13.53 |
-2.92 |
-27.94 |
-5.25 |
60 |
-7.70 |
-6.69 |
-14.37 |
-1.43 |
-23.73 |
-6.19 |
Generalised Impulse |
IV.2.3 Model with Core (Manufacturing) Inflation
An alternative perspective to account for supply shocks entails a
model with core inflation without the presence of exogenous supply
shocks. Thus, we experimented with the VAR model (Model 4) with
manufacturing price inflation as endogenous variable rather than
aggregate price inflation as in the Model 3. The impulse response
analysis arising from Model 4 is provided in Annex 7 and in Table 5.
Here again the common finding was that the impact of tight money
policy shock on output growth of capital goods and consumer durables
in Model 4 turned out to be higher than Model 3. On other hand, the
impact was more or less similar for basic goods and intermediate goods
but consumer non-durables showed a lower response in Model 4 than
Model 3.
Table 5: Impact of One Standard deviation Shock to Call Rate: Accumulated Responses of Output growth and Inflation rate
(Model with Manufacturing Inflation as Endogenous Variable) |
Period |
ZMNF |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
1 |
-0.02 |
-0.25 |
-0.93 |
-0.02 |
-0.12 |
0.15 |
8 |
-1.31 |
-1.19 |
-7.76 |
0.45 |
-9.46 |
2.38 |
13 |
-3.18 |
-2.52 |
-16.34 |
0.65 |
-15.35 |
-0.43 |
29 |
-7.57 |
-6.48 |
-30.06 |
-1.27 |
-28.73 |
-3.22 |
38 |
-8.45 |
-6.50 |
-34.14 |
-2.73 |
-33.18 |
-2.56 |
40 |
-8.42 |
-6.53 |
-33.87 |
-2.84 |
-33.56 |
-2.24 |
42 |
-8.37 |
-6.52 |
-33.75 |
-2.75 |
-33.85 |
-1.91 |
60 |
-8.70 |
-6.88 |
-31.42 |
-1.70 |
-33.49 |
-1.50 |
Generalised Impulse |
IV.2.4 Model with Exogenous Real Exchange Rate Variation
The empirical exercises in the above could be consistent with
a closed economy approach to transmission mechanism. However,
the Indian economy has witnessed significant integration with the
world economy due to trade and capital flows reflecting the impact of
reform, the increasing competitiveness of industries in their pursuit
of internationalisation and the stronger economic growth prospect.
According to macroeconomics literature, the open economy aspects
of transmission mechanism could be captured through the role of
exchange rate, which determines exports and imports and thus,
aggregate economic activity. Here, the argument could arise whether
to consider nominal or real exchange rate as exogenous or endogenous
variable in the VAR model. In this regard, empirical studies consider
the assumptions relating to a relatively small open economy, exchange
rate regime, central bank intervention in the foreign exchange market
and external integration in terms of a country’s share in global trade and
capital flows. Since our focus is on monetary transmission mechanism
and the robustness of empirical findings, we consider a VAR model
(Model 5) with annual variation in multiple currency trade weighted
real exchange rate as an exogenous variable along with the endogenous
variables in line with the Model 4. Taking further clue that REER
information is available with a lag of one to two months, we consider one-month lag of year-on-year variation in the real exchange rate. The
impulse responses arising from the Model 5 are shown in Annex 8 and
Table 6. The findings from the Model 5 are notable when compared with
Model 4. Though with the presence of real exchange rate variation, all
sectors witnesses a strengthening of monetary impact, capital goods,
intermediate goods and consumer non-durables show a significantly
higher impact of tight policy in Model 5 than in Model 4.
Table 6: Impact of One Standard deviation Shock to Call Rate: Accumulated Responses of Output growth and Inflation rate
(Model with Exogenous Real Exchange rate variation) |
Period |
ZMNF |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
1 |
-0.02 |
-0.24 |
-0.95 |
-0.02 |
-0.10 |
0.11 |
8 |
-1.31 |
-1.10 |
-8.20 |
0.48 |
-8.94 |
1.55 |
12 |
-2.74 |
-2.20 |
-16.52 |
0.64 |
-12.41 |
-2.80 |
24 |
-5.80 |
-5.67 |
-37.23 |
-1.19 |
-21.23 |
-9.25 |
29 |
-6.87 |
-6.81 |
-44.23 |
-3.32 |
-28.30 |
-9.40 |
35 |
-7.88 |
-7.44 |
-50.57 |
-4.77 |
-35.81 |
-8.05 |
39 |
-8.17 |
-7.34 |
-52.56 |
-4.47 |
-37.86 |
-6.70 |
51 |
-8.36 |
-7.20 |
-47.01 |
-1.92 |
-39.47 |
-2.33 |
60 |
-8.99 |
-7.04 |
-40.30 |
-1.07 |
-38.77 |
-0.85 |
Generalised Impulse |
IV.2.5 Impact of the Global Crisis
A viewpoint may arise that last four to five years could be construed
as a special situation attributable to the global crisis period, necessitating
rapid policy response to tackle the adverse conditions. In this context,
we evaluated a VAR model (Model 3) with sample period April 1993 to
March 2008, excluding the global crisis period. The impulse responses
of the use-based industries to tight monetary policy shock are shown
in Annex 9 and Table 7. It was evident that the crisis did not affect the
underlying nature of transmission mechanism in terms of maximum
impact of tight monetary policy shock on the output growth of capital
goods and consumer durables. However, the magnitude of impact
showed a softening during the crisis. Also, there was some evidence on
the faster pace of transmission mechanism in terms of time period for
the maximum impact across the sectors.
IV.2.6 Variance Decomposition Analysis
The forecast error variance decomposition showed the findings
more or less similar to the impulse response analysis, albeit with some
marginal difference. Illustratively, Table 8 provides of the Forecast Error
Variance Decomposition (FEVD) analysis for the Model 4. The impact
of call money rate shock in explaining total variation of output growth
in the medium term (between 12-36 months) was highest for consumer
durables, followed by basic goods, capital goods, consumer non-durables
and intermediate goods. This finding also extended to other models.
A notable finding here was that the inter-industry interaction, comprising
own and other sectors’ contributions, accounting for more than threefourth
of total variation of output growth for the use-based industries.
Illustratively, over 36 months, own lags reflecting the persistence of the
sector accounted for 30 per cent and the lags of other sectors accounted
for 58 per cent of total variation in the output growth of capital goods
sector.
Table 7: Global Crisis and the Impact of One Standard
deviation Shock to Call Rate: Accumulated Responses of
Output growth and Inflation rate |
|
Period with the Global Crisis |
Period without Global Crisis |
Model 1 |
Model 2 |
Model 3 |
Model 4 |
Model 1 |
Model 2 |
Model 3 |
Model 4 |
Basic Goods |
-9.0 |
-7.1 |
-6.9 |
-7.4 |
-10.3 |
-9.1 |
-7.4 |
-9.1 |
(33) |
(33) |
(60) |
(35) |
(33) |
(26) |
(41) |
(41) |
Capital
Goods |
-30.4 |
-18.6 |
-34.1 |
-52.6 |
-62.0 |
-26.6 |
-37.6 |
-61.5 |
(38) |
(24) |
(38) |
(39) |
(60) |
(60) |
(60) |
(60) |
Intermediate
goods |
-4.8 |
-2.9 |
-2.8 |
-4.8 |
-12.8 |
-7.9 |
-8.8 |
-12.0 |
(40) |
(40) |
(40) |
(35) |
(44) |
(34) |
(40) |
(42) |
Consumer
durables |
-36.1 |
-28.2 |
-33.9 |
-39.5 |
-58.1 |
-27.5 |
-35.3 |
-47.3 |
(41) |
(37) |
(42) |
(51) |
(60) |
(33) |
(60) |
(47) |
Consumer
non-durables |
-4.5 |
-6.2 |
-3.2 |
-9.4 |
-13.4 |
-9.3 |
-9.6 |
-16.0 |
(31) |
(60) |
(29) |
(29) |
(60) |
(29) |
(60) |
(60) |
Figures indicate maximum impact in terms of cumulative impulse response to one standard deviation shock to call money rate. Figures in bracket indicate the period taken to reach maximum impact. |
Table 8: Generalised Forecast Error Variance Decomposition Analysis |
Horizon |
CALL |
ZINF |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
0 |
0.05 |
0.00 |
1.00 |
0.03 |
0.06 |
0.06 |
0.00 |
6 |
0.09 |
0.01 |
0.80 |
0.03 |
0.18 |
0.07 |
0.05 |
12 |
0.15 |
0.02 |
0.69 |
0.03 |
0.15 |
0.08 |
0.09 |
24 |
0.18 |
0.10 |
0.49 |
0.03 |
0.11 |
0.13 |
0.10 |
36 |
0.18 |
0.10 |
0.45 |
0.04 |
0.11 |
0.13 |
0.11 |
48 |
0.17 |
0.10 |
0.44 |
0.04 |
0.11 |
0.14 |
0.11 |
60 |
0.17 |
0.10 |
0.44 |
0.04 |
0.11 |
0.14 |
0.11 |
Horizon |
CALL |
ZINF |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
0 |
0.01 |
0.00 |
0.03 |
1.00 |
0.02 |
0.03 |
0.00 |
6 |
0.07 |
0.06 |
0.13 |
0.71 |
0.13 |
0.12 |
0.04 |
12 |
0.12 |
0.14 |
0.11 |
0.47 |
0.12 |
0.14 |
0.13 |
24 |
0.12 |
0.15 |
0.09 |
0.33 |
0.09 |
0.14 |
0.22 |
36 |
0.12 |
0.15 |
0.09 |
0.31 |
0.09 |
0.15 |
0.23 |
48 |
0.11 |
0.15 |
0.10 |
0.30 |
0.10 |
0.15 |
0.22 |
60 |
0.11 |
0.15 |
0.11 |
0.30 |
0.10 |
0.15 |
0.21 |
Horizon |
CALL |
ZINF |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
0 |
0.00 |
0.00 |
0.06 |
0.02 |
1.00 |
0.13 |
0.00 |
6 |
0.01 |
0.02 |
0.09 |
0.04 |
0.92 |
0.09 |
0.02 |
12 |
0.01 |
0.02 |
0.10 |
0.04 |
0.86 |
0.09 |
0.04 |
24 |
0.01 |
0.08 |
0.09 |
0.07 |
0.71 |
0.15 |
0.06 |
36 |
0.03 |
0.09 |
0.10 |
0.07 |
0.66 |
0.14 |
0.07 |
48 |
0.03 |
0.09 |
0.11 |
0.07 |
0.62 |
0.13 |
0.09 |
60 |
0.03 |
0.09 |
0.11 |
0.07 |
0.61 |
0.13 |
0.09 |
Horizon |
CALL |
ZINF |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
0 |
0.00 |
0.00 |
0.06 |
0.03 |
0.13 |
1.00 |
0.00 |
6 |
0.10 |
0.02 |
0.08 |
0.04 |
0.25 |
0.77 |
0.03 |
12 |
0.16 |
0.03 |
0.13 |
0.06 |
0.24 |
0.65 |
0.04 |
24 |
0.18 |
0.06 |
0.12 |
0.05 |
0.22 |
0.58 |
0.05 |
36 |
0.20 |
0.06 |
0.12 |
0.05 |
0.21 |
0.55 |
0.05 |
48 |
0.19 |
0.06 |
0.13 |
0.05 |
0.21 |
0.54 |
0.05 |
60 |
0.19 |
0.06 |
0.13 |
0.05 |
0.21 |
0.53 |
0.05 |
Horizon |
CALL |
ZINF |
ZBGS |
ZKGS |
ZIGS |
ZCDGS |
ZCNDGS |
0 |
0.00 |
0.00 |
0.00 |
0.00 |
0.00 |
0.00 |
1.00 |
6 |
0.03 |
0.03 |
0.03 |
0.02 |
0.03 |
0.03 |
0.85 |
12 |
0.07 |
0.05 |
0.06 |
0.02 |
0.05 |
0.04 |
0.72 |
24 |
0.08 |
0.10 |
0.07 |
0.05 |
0.06 |
0.08 |
0.58 |
36 |
0.08 |
0.10 |
0.07 |
0.05 |
0.06 |
0.10 |
0.57 |
48 |
0.08 |
0.10 |
0.07 |
0.05 |
0.07 |
0.10 |
0.56 |
60 |
0.08 |
0.10 |
0.07 |
0.05 |
0.07 |
0.10 |
0.55 |
Section V
Conclusion
In this study, we examined how monetary policy shock impinges
on the output growth of five use-based industries such as basic goods,
capital goods, intermediate goods, consumer durables, and consumer
non-durable goods. The empirical findings from the VAR model with
alternative combinations of variables brought to the fore a common
perspective. Monetary policy could affect capital goods and consumer
durables more than other three used-based industries. In some cases,
basic goods also showed a response similar to durables and capital
goods. Intermediate goods and consumer non-durables showed moderate
response to policy shock, and the latter was also associated with a
lag in transmission effect. The supply side factors affecting inflation
through oil and food prices could play a role in determining the output
cost of disinflation. Empirical findings suggested that without supply
shocks, the impulse response of output and inflation to monetary policy
could be overestimated. The industry effects of monetary transmission
mechanism could also be different for an open economy with exogenous
fluctuation in real exchange rate. These findings provide insights about
how monetary policy affects consumption and investment demands and
thereby, the economic growth and inflation. It is expected that these
findings could find useful for policy analysis in the Indian context. For
further research, policy analysis would benefit from studies focused on
disaggregate approach to transmission mechanism based on corporate
balance sheets across different industries and sectors.
References
Ahmed, S. (1987). “Wage Stickiness and the Non-Neutrality of Money:
A Cross-Industry Analysis.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 20.
Ahmed, H. and S.M. Miller (1997). “Monetary and Exchange Rate
Policy in Multisectoral Economies.” Journal of Economics and
Business, 49.
Angeloni, I., A. Kashyap and B. Mojon (2003). Monetary Policy
Transmission in the Euro Area. Cambridge University Press.
Ball, Laurence and David Romer (1990). “Real Rigidities and the Non-
Neutrality of Money.” Review of Economic Studies, 57.
Barro, R.J. (1977). “Unanticipated Money Growth and Unemployment
in the United States.” American Economic Review, 67(2).
———. (1981). “Unanticipated Money, Output, and the Price Level in
the United States.” in R. Barro (ed.), Money, Expectations and Business
Cycles. New York: Academic Press.
Benito, A. (2002). “Financial pressure, monetary policy effects and
inventory adjustment by UK and Spanish firms.” BANCO DE ESPAÑA/
DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N.0223
Bernanke, B. and M. Gertler (1995). “Inside the Black Box: The Credit
Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 9.
Bernanke, B.S. and A.S. Blinder (1988). “Credit, Money and Aggregate
Demand.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 78.
Bernanke, Ben S. and Alan S. Blinder (1992). “The Federal Funds Rate
and the Channels of Monetary Transmission.” American Economic
Review, 82(4).
Bernanke, B.S. and M. Gertler (1995). “Inside the Black Box: The
Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 9.
Berument, H., N.B. Ceylan and E.M. Yucel (2004). “The Differential
Sectoral Effects of Policy Shocks: Evidence from Turkey.” Working
Paper No. 0703, Bilkent University, Department of Economics.
Berument, H., N. Konac and O. Senay (2007). “Openness and the
Effectiveness of Monetary Policy: A Cross-country Analysis.” International Economic Journal, 21(4).
Blinder, A. and Mankiw, N.G. Jan. (1984). “Aggregation and
Stabilization Policy in a Multicontract Economy.” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 13(1).
Dale, S. and A.G. Haldane (1995). “Interest Rates and the Channels
of Monetary Transmission: Some Sectoral Estimates.” European
Economic Review, 39.
David, I.C., J.J. Durand and N. Payelle (2000). “The Heterogeneous
Effects of Monetary Policy in the Euro Area: A Sectoral Approach.”
France: University of Rennes.
Dedola, L. and F. Lippi (2000). “The Monetary Transmission
Mechanism: Evidence from the Industries of five OECD Countries.” Temi di discussione 389, Bank of Italy.
Dhal, S. (2012). “A Disaggregated Monetary Transmission Mechanism:
Evidence from Dispersion of bank Credit to Indian States.” in the Regional Economy of India: Growth and Finance, edited by Deepak
Mohanty, Academic Foundation and RBI.
Drake, L. and Adrian R. Fleissig (2010). “Substitution between
monetary assets and consumer goods: New evidence on the monetary
transmission mechanism.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 34.
Duca, J.V. and D.D. VanHoose (1990). “Optimal Monetary Policy in
a Multisectoral Economy with an Economy-wide Money Market.” Journal of Economics and Business, 42(4).
Edwards, S. (1989a). “Openness, Outward Orientation, Trade
Liberalization and Economic Performance in Developing Countries.” NBER Working Paper No. 2908.
———. (1989b). “Exchange Controls, Devaluations and Real Exchange
Rates: the Latin American Experience.” Economic Development and
Cultural Change, 37(3).
Ehrmann, M. and M. Ellison (2002). “The Changing Response of US
Industry to Monetary Policy.” CEPR Papers. UK.
Enders, W. and B. Falk (1984). “A Microeconomic Test of Money
Neutrality.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 66(4).
Erceg, C. and A. Levin (2002). “Optimal Monetary Policy with Durable
and Non-Durable Goods.” ECB Working Paper No. 179.
Farès, J. and S. Gabriel (2001). “The Monetary Transmission Mechanism
at the Sectoral Level.” Bank of Canada Working Paper 2001-27.
Fiorentini, R. and R. Tamborini (2001). “The Monetary Transmission
Mechanism in Italy: the Credit Channel and a Missing Ring.” Giornale
degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, 60(1).
Franco, Francesco and Thomas Philippon (2004). “Firms and Aggregate
Dynamics.” Manuscript. New York University.
Gaiotti, E.G. and A. Generale (2001). “Does Monetary Policy have
Asymmetric Effects? A Look at the Investment Decisions of Italian
Firms.” European Central Bank Working Paper Series 110.
Ganley, J. and C. Salmon (1997). “The Industrial Impact of Monetary
Policy Transmission: the Case of Italy.” Temi di discussione, 430, Bank
of Italy.
Gauger, J. (1988). “Disaggregate Level Evidence on Monetary
Neutrality.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 70(4).
Gauger, J. and W. Enders (1989). “Money Neutrality at Aggregate and
Sectoral Levels.” Southern. Economic Journal, 55.
Gerlach, S. and F. Smets (1995). “The Monetary Transmission
Mechanism: Evidence from the G-7 Countries.” CEPR Discussion
Paper 1219.
Gertler, M. and S. Gilchrist (1993). “The Role of Credit Market
Imperfections in the Monetary Transmission Mechanism: Argument
and Review.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 95(1).
Gertler, M. and S. Gilchrist (1994). “Monetary Policy, Business Cycles
and the Behavior of Small Manufacturing Firms.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 109(2).
Greenspan, A. (2001). “Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan-
Federal Reserve Board’s semi-annual monetary policy report to the
Congress Before the Committee on Financial Services”, U.S. House of
Representatives July 18, 2001.
Guiso, L., A. Kashyap, F. Panetta and D. Terlizzese (1999). “Will a
Common European Monetary Policy have Asymmetric Effects?” Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Hayo, B. and B. Uhlenbrock (1999). “Industry Effects of Monetary
Policy in Germany.” Center for European Integration Studies Working
Paper No. B 14.
Jung, Y and T. Yun (2005). “Monetary policy, inventory dynamics and
price setting behavior.” Federal Reserve Bank Sanfransisco Working
Paper 2006-02.
Kandil, M. (1991). “Variations in the Response of Real Output to
Aggregate Demand Shocks: A Cross Industry Analysis.” Review of
Economics and Statistics, 73.
Kashyap, A.K. and J. Stein (1994). “Monetary Policy and Bank
Lending.” in N.G. Mankiew (ed.), Monetary Policy. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press.
————. (2000). “What do a Million Observations on Banks say
about the Transmission of Monetary Policy?” American Economic
Review, 90(3).
Kashyap, A.K. and J.C. Stein (1995). “The Impact of Monetary Policy
on Bank Balance Sheets.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy, 42.
Kashyap, A.K., J. Stein and D.W. Wilcox (1993). “Monetary Policy
and Credit Conditions: Evidence from the Composition of External
Finance.” American Economic Review, 83(1).
Kim, S. (1999). “Do Monetary Policy Shocks Matter in the G-7
Countries? Using Common Identifying Assumptions about Monetary
Policy Across Countries.” Journal of International Economics, 48(2).
Kretzmer, P.E. (1989). “The Cross-Industry Effects of Unanticipated
Money in an Equilibrium Business Cycle Model.” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 23.
Lastrapes, William D. (2006). “Inflation and the Distribution of Relative
Prices: The Role of Productivity and Money Supply Shocks.” Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking, 38(8).
Linde, J. (2003). “Comment on the Output Composition Puzzle: A
Difference in the Monetary Transmission Mechanism in the Euro Area
and U.S.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 35.
Llaudes, R. (2007). “Monetary Policy Shocks in a Two-Sector Open
Economy: An Empirical Study.” European Central Bank Working
Paper Series No 799.
Loo, C.M. and W.D. Lastrapes (1998). “Identifying the Effects of Money
Supply Shocks on Industry-Level Output.” Journal of Macroeconomics,
20(3).
Lutkepohl, H. (1990). “Asymptotic Distributions of Impulse Response
Functions and Forecast Error Variance Decompositions of Vector
Autoregressive Models.” Review of Economics and Statistics,72(1)
Lütkepohl, H. and D. S. Poskitt (1991). “Estimating Orthogonal Impulse
Responses via Vector Autoregressive Models.” Econometric Theory,
7(4).
Lütkepohl, H. R. BrÄuggemann and P. Saikkonen (2006). “Residual
Autocorrelation Testing for Vector Error Correction Models.” Journal
of Econometrics, 134.
Lütkepohl, H (2006). Vector Autoregressive Models, in T.C. Mills &
K. Patterson (Eds.), Palgrave Handbook of Econometrics, Volume 1,
Econometric Theory, Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan, 2006, 477-
510.
Mishkin, F. (1976). “Illiquidity, Consumer durable expenditure and
Monetary Policy.” American Economic Review, 66(4)
Pesaran, H. Hashem, and Y. Shin (1998). “Generalized impulse response
analysis in linear multivariate models.” Economics Letters, 58: 17–29
Peersman, G. and F. Smets (2001). “The Monetary Transmission
Mechanism in the Euro Area: More Evidence from VAR Analysis.” European Central Bank Working Paper No.91.
————. (2002). “The Industry Effects of Monetary Policy in the
Euro Area.” European Central Bank, Working Paper No.165.
————. (2005). “The Industry Effects of Monetary Policy in Euro
Area.” Economic Journal, 115(503): 319-342
Ramaswamy, R. and T. Sloek (1997). “The Real Effects of Monetary
Policy in the European Union: What Are the Differences.” IMF Working
Paper No.160. Washington: IMF.
Shelley, G.L. and F. H. Wallace (1998). “Tests of the Money-Output
Relation Using Disaggregated Data.” The Quarterly Review of
Economics and Finance, 38(4).
Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss (1981). “Credit Rationing in Markets with
Imperfect Information.” American Economic Review, 71: 393-410.
Taylor, L.L. and M.K. Yucel (1996). “The Policy Sensitivity of Industries
and Regions.” Working Paper No.12. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
Waller, C.J. (1992). “The Choice of Conservative Central Banker in a
Multisectoral Economy.” American Economic Review, 82(4).
Annex 1: Principal Component Analysis (PCA) of Broad GDP
Components:
Agriculture, Industry and Services Sectors
Ordinary Correlation Based PCA |
Eigen values: (Sum = 3, Average = 1) |
Number |
Value |
Difference |
Proportion |
Cumulative Value |
1 |
1.444435 |
0.465440 |
0.4815 |
1.444435 |
2 |
0.978995 |
0.402424 |
0.3263 |
2.423430 |
3 |
0.576570 |
--- |
0.1922 |
3.000000 |
Eigenvectors (loadings): |
Variable |
PC 1 |
PC 2 |
PC 3 |
|
XGAGS |
0.283025 |
0.937788 |
0.201121 |
|
XGINDS |
0.658422 |
-0.342452 |
0.670229 |
|
XGSRVS |
0.697408 |
-0.057269 |
-0.714383 |
|
Ordinary correlations: |
|
XGAGS |
XGINDS |
XGSRVS |
|
XGAGS |
1.000000 |
|
|
|
XGINDS |
0.032489 |
1.000000 |
|
|
XGSRVS |
0.149690 |
0.406406 |
1.000000 |
|
Ordinary (uncentered) Correlation Based PCA |
Eigen values: (Sum = 3, Average = 1) |
Number |
Value |
Difference |
Proportion |
Cumulative Value |
Cumulative Proportion |
1 |
2.256865 |
1.601170 |
0.7523 |
2.256865 |
0.7523 |
2 |
0.655696 |
0.568257 |
0.2186 |
2.912561 |
0.9709 |
3 |
0.087439 |
--- |
0.0291 |
3.000000 |
1.0000 |
Eigenvectors (loadings): |
Variable |
PC 1 |
PC 2 |
PC 3 |
|
|
XGAGS |
0.464988 |
0.883436 |
0.057677 |
|
|
XGINDS |
0.620079 |
-0.371487 |
0.691013 |
|
|
XGSRVS |
0.631893 |
-0.285548 |
-0.720537 |
|
|
Ordinary (uncentered) correlations: |
|
XGAGS |
XGINDS |
XGSRVS |
|
|
XGAGS |
1.000000 |
|
|
|
|
XGINDS |
0.439016 |
1.000000 |
|
|
|
XGSRVS |
0.494075 |
0.910311 |
1.000000 |
|
|
Annex 2: Major Product Items in Use-based Industries |
Basic goods |
Capital goods |
Intermediate goods |
Consumer durables |
Consumer
non-durabels |
products |
weight |
products |
weight |
products |
weight |
products |
weight |
products |
weight |
Minerals |
141.6 |
Com-
mercial
Vehicles |
19.3 |
Cotton
yarn |
15.1 |
Passenger
Cars |
19.7 |
Antibiotics |
23.8 |
Electricity |
103.2 |
Boilers |
4.0 |
LPG |
11.2 |
Gems & Jewellery |
17.7 |
Apparels |
20.3 |
Cement |
24.1 |
Tractors |
3.8 |
Non-cot- ton yarn |
7.1 |
Motor Cycles |
9.5 |
sugar |
15.2 |
Diesel |
21.1 |
Three- Wheelers |
3.3 |
Fasteners |
5.7 |
Colour TV |
3.8 |
Newspa- pers |
10.1 |
H R Coils |
13.0 |
Refractory
Bricks |
3.2 |
Petrol |
5.6 |
Glazed /
Ceramic
Tiles |
3.6 |
grey cloth |
9.1 |
Plates |
12.5 |
Grinding Wheels |
2.9 |
Synthetic yarn |
5.5 |
Air Condi- tioner |
2.9 |
Cigarettes |
8.7 |
Sponge
iron |
10.0 |
Engines |
2.9 |
Steel
Structures |
5.5 |
Woollen
Carpets |
2.6 |
Cotton
cloth |
8.0 |
Bars &
Rods |
9.8 |
Plastic
Machinery |
2.6 |
Naphtha |
5.4 |
Wood
Furniture |
2.4 |
Leather
Garments |
7.5 |
Carbon
steel |
7.8 |
Trans-
formers |
2.4 |
Block
Board |
5.1 |
Tyre,
Truck/
Bus |
2.4 |
Rice |
6.6 |
Urea |
6.4 |
Computers |
2.3 |
Purified
acid |
4.2 |
Telephone
Instru-
ments
Including
Mobile |
2.2 |
Tea |
6.5 |
Stainless/
alloy steel |
6.4 |
Earth
Moving
Machinery |
2.3 |
Furnace
Oil |
3.9 |
Scooter
and Mo-
peds |
2.1 |
Pens of All
Kind |
5.9 |
Ferro
manga-
nese |
6.4 |
Switch-
gears |
2.2 |
Bearings
(Ball/
Roller) |
3.4 |
Pressure
Cooker |
2.1 |
Milk,
Skimmed,
Pasteurised |
5.7 |
CR Sheets |
5.6 |
Conductor,
Alumin-
ium |
2.0 |
Polypro-
pylene |
3.0 |
Tyre, Car/
Cab |
2.0 |
Razor/
Safety
Blades |
5.3 |
Copper
and Prod-
ucts |
5.5 |
Air & Gas
Compres-
sors |
1.9 |
Industrial
Alcohol |
2.6 |
PVC Pipes
and Tubes |
1.9 |
Biri |
5.1 |
Stampings
& Forg-
ings |
4.9 |
Textile
Machinery |
1.7 |
Glass
Bottles |
2.6 |
Marble
Tiles/
Slabs |
1.2 |
Non-cotton
cloth |
3.9 |
sub-total |
378.2 |
sub-total |
56.8 |
sub-total |
85.9 |
sub-total |
76.2 |
sub-total |
141.7 |
All |
456.8 |
All |
88.3 |
All |
156.9 |
All |
84.6 |
All |
213.5 |
|