I am highly honoured to have been asked to be the latest in a very distinguished
list of C. D. Deshmukh lecturers. My predecessors are a kind of Who’s Who of
international finance: Michel Camdessus, Gerry Corrigan, Eddie George and others.
Clearly, to mark the new Millennium, you have decided to go downmarket!
I was last in India, in both Mumbai and Chennai almost exactly two years ago. I
spoke at a CII conference in Chennai with Mr Narasimham, who was at that time engaged
in preparing his second report on the Indian financial system. We orchestrated between
us an interesting debate on the lessons which India might draw from the Far Eastern
crisis of 1997.
But, in truth, it was then too early to reach a considered view. The dramatic collapses
of confidence in Thailand, Korea, Indonesia and elsewhere were far too recent. And
indeed in retrospect it can be seen that we were only halfway through the story.
The Russian collapse was yet to come, as was the dramatic intervention by the Hong
Kong Monetary Authority to combat speculation in the Hong Kong currency and equity
markets. Still in the future, too, was the collapse of Long Term Capital Management,
in September 1998, which showed that threats to the stability of the financial system
could arise from the activities of unregulated hedge funds as well as from regulated
banks.
These were highly unusual events. Indeed the risk model operated by LTCM told its
managers that the market price movements which occurred on two days in late August
were events which should have occurred only once in every 80 trillion years. This
may tell you something important about their risk model. But there is no denying
that there were some highly unusual price changes which took everyone by surprise.
Indeed financial markets remained very turbulent right up to the end of 1998. And
that turbulence particularly affected developing countries. For a time there was
a very marked flight to what were perceived to be safer assets and instruments,
especially government bonds in developed countries. The average spread on emerging
market bonds, which averaged 500 basis points in the first half of 1997, was around
1175 basis points in the last quarter of 1998. It was conventional wisdom in the
City of London and on Wall Street at that time that emerging markets would be closed
to new borrowers for years to come. More than one investment bank in London took
the axe to its emerging markets department, and everyone at least did some rigorous
pruning.
It is clear now that some of these more extravagant forecasts were well wide of
the mark. Markets have been much calmer over the last twelve months than was foreseen,
and while life has remained difficult for borrowers in developing countries, spreads
have fallen back significantly, so that the average emerging market spread over
US Treasury bonds in the last quarter of 1999 was only about 850 basis points. This
is a welcome reduction for borrowers, but the spread remains considerably wider
than it was a couple of years ago.
And almost everywhere around the world equity markets had an annus mirabilis in
1999. The Dow Jones went up 25% during the year and the London FT-SE Index by 18%.
Even that dramatically good performance was outdone elsewhere. The Nikkei rose 37%
and the Korean market in Seoul rose 83% over the year. In Brazil, the BOVESPA index
rose 150% in local currency, while the BSE 30 here passed a more than respectable
rise of 64%.
So is all now well? Have we now recovered from what we can now see was a nasty bout
of the wobbles? Have we learnt all the lessons and taken the medicine to prevent
any recurrence? Can we now look back on the turbulence of 1997 and 1998, confident
in the knowledge that it couldn’t happen again?
You will detect from the tone of these rhetorical questions that I do not believe
the answer to all of them is yes.
I recognise that this is just the sort of time when people are least interested
in warning messages from financial regulators. But it is almost certainly the time
when they are most needed. Paul Volcker once said that the rôle of the central banker
was to take away the punchbowl just as the party was beginning to go with a swing.
Just in the same way, financial regulators are paid to be professional wet blankets,
to warn of troubles ahead at the moment when there is a risk that past problems
are fading in the memory.
So in these good times we need to shout louder to be heard. I do not mean that literally.
My aim today is to suggest that the general directions of change adopted by the
financial authorities in countries around the world in response to the market turbulence
of 1997 and 1998 are correct. But, even as recovery gathers pace and so one impetus
to reform weakens, reforms need to be pursued with more vigour than has been the
case hitherto. And that is true both internationally and at the level of the individual
country.
But rather than stay at the level of comfortable generality – hands up those
who are against prudence and good management – I will try to be a little more
specific, in three areas where further change is certainly needed:
-
|
First, the international financial architecture, where important reforms
have been made, but where the hard work of implementation still lies ahead;
|
-
|
Second, in international financial regulation, where there is more work to
do to ensure that the right incentives are in place for financial institutions in
developed and developing markets to manage their risks more effectively in future;
and
|
-
|
Third, in emerging market countries themselves, where there is a need for
more practical efforts to upgrade accounting and legal standards, and systems of
financial regulation, and of course to clean up the balance sheets of banking systems
which, in many cases, remain very fragile.
|
My emphasis will lie heavily on the financial system, and on the financial regulation
aspects of the problem, not on monetary or macro-economic policy. It is not because
I do not think important for countries to adopt sound macro-economic and monetary
policies – indeed it is an essential pre-requisite of a healthy financial
system that they do. But when the Financial Services Authority and the Bank of England
separated a couple of years ago I agreed with the Governor that I would keep out
of his garden if he kept out of mine. That has so far proved the basis of an excellent
relationship!
In the aftermath of the Asian crisis it seemed, for a time, that a kind of international
design competition had been launched, with the creative departments of every finance
ministry in the world (if that is not an oxymoron) putting forward their own ideas
for a new international financial architecture. There were a number of freelance
contributions, too, from academics and commentators around the globe.
Some argued for a new Bretton Woods settlement. Chintaman Deshmukh, who was present
at Bretton Woods himself, would have appreciated that. Others pressed the case for
a kind of world financial authority with the power to regulate all cross border
business, a Financial Services Authority on a universal scale.
These more extravagant ideas have not, in the event, commanded majority support.
And an evolutionary, pragmatic approach has been adopted. There are clear advantages
to proceeding in that way. It is far quicker, cheaper and more effective at international
level to adapt existing institutions than to set up new ones. And in my view the
key need was, rather than new architecture, enhanced plumbing: in other words better
linkages between the different international financial institutions and groupings
we already have. I will say more about this enhanced plumbing in a moment. But it
is important to recognise that there have been some structural changes of significance.
There is the establishment of the G20, which met for the first time in Berlin last
December, and of which India is of course an important member. It will be interesting
to see how the agenda of the G20 develops in the future and especially how it addresses
the main vulnerabilities affecting G20 economies and the global financial system.
I note that all ministers and governors of the G20 agreed in principle to the preparation
of Financial Sector Assessments, to be produced by the IMF and World Bank. I shall
say more about these Financial Sector Assessments in a moment.
We have also seen the establishment of the Financial Stability Forum which began
to meet last April. The Forum brings together, for the first time, supervisors and
their international groupings, (the Basel Committee, IOSCO and so forth) central
bankers and finance ministries, together with the IMF, the World Bank, the OECD
and the BIS. Representation, which initially was limited to the G7, now extends
to Australia, Netherlands, Hong Kong and Singapore. I would not be surprised if
its doors were opened even wider in the future.
The gap which the Forum is designed to fill was initially identified by our Chancellor
of the Exchequer, Gordon Brown, at the end of 1998. He pointed out that there was
no forum in which regulators, central banks and finance ministries came together
to look at financial crises, and indeed to try to share information which might
lead to better forecasting and conceivably prevention of future crises, together
with more financial stability. Hans Tietmeyer, then President of the Bundesbank,
was invited to examine this proposal in more detail, and the eventual composition
and remit of the Forum reflects his work.
I am one of the UK members of the Forum, which perhaps conditions me to regard it
as an important new initiative.
So far we have tried to do two things. First, to work towards developing a better
"early warning system" than was previously available. I do not underestimate the
difficulty of that task, and I am sure we will never be able to specify a list of
indicators which can be guaranteed to flash red at the sign of impending disaster.
But I cannot think it is anything other than useful for those of us who are closely
involved in supervising markets to exchange opinions and impressions of market developments,
in an attempt to scope out future shocks, and to think about how we would go about
responding to them should they occur.
Secondly, the Forum is trying to specify concrete actions in areas where progress
is needed. One of the three working groups set up by the Forum is focused on the
problems for financial stability created by highly leveraged institutions, including
both the impact of the LTCM affair, and also the various market episodes in 1998
in which hedge funds and other highly leveraged institutions are argued to have
played a potentially destabilising part. I am chairing that group, which includes
representatives from Hong Kong and Australia: we plan to report to the next meeting
of the Forum in Singapore at the end of next month.
So we are in the process of formulating our conclusions now, and I do not wish to
prejudge them today. But I can say that we have done some useful and original work
in looking at the details of particular episodes of market instability, and the
ways in which different types of institution interacted with each other during those
episodes. We shall publish that analysis, and a series of case studies on individual
countries and their experiences. I hope that the authorities in both developed and
developing countries will at the very least find the report a useful contribution
to their understanding of market dynamics.
Another group established by the Forum is looking at the particular rôle of offshore
financial centres, especially the availability of accurate data, compliance with
key standards, and sanctions for non-compliance. And a third group is examining
some of the issues surrounding short-term capital flows, that will undoubtedly be
of considerable interest to the Indian authorities, focusing on management of risks,
including debt; the volatility of capital flows; and capital controls. Again, these
reports are to be submitted to the next meeting of the Forum, and published soon
after.
It is of course too early to say how the Financial Stability Forum will develop.
But in my view it is potentially a very useful innovation. Clearly, if it develops
successfully, there will be a need to consider the balance of its membership, and
the case for including, in particular, other large developing economies among its
numbers. I should emphasise, though, that the working groups have already reached
out beyond the formal membership of the Forum to include representatives from countries
particularly affected by the problems under discussion.
But I think it likely that, in the future, these institutional developments will
be seen to be of less significance than a range of individually modest, but collectively
important enhancements to the systems of co-operation and co-ordination between
institutions. Before explaining those developments in a little more detail, I should
take a short step back, to explain how I see the theory of international financial
regulation, and how the practice today seems to fall sadly short.
In theory, financial regulation around the world is governed by standards set by
three main groups of regulators. For banking, it is the Basel Committee, set up
under the auspices of the BIS. For securities firms and markets it is the International
Organisation of Securities Commissions (IOSCO), and for insurance companies it is
the International Association of Insurance Supervisors (IAIS). The latter two are
more recent creations with a wide membership. The former is a much tighter grouping
of developed country supervisors only, but one which has earned considerable authority
around the globe, largely as a result of the quality of its output. In effect, it
also sets standards for countries outside its membership.
All three organisations have established principles of good regulatory practice,
to which most countries in the world are, at least nominally, signed up. These principles
describe the appropriate structures for regulation, with requirements for independence
from political interference, they set out an approach to capital, and many other
desirable features of a soundly regulated financial system. So far, so good.
But these principles do not appear to have been effective in preventing, or perhaps
more realistically mitigating, the effects of financial crises. And we can see from
the aftermath of the Asian crises that the Korean banking system was not adequately
capitalised in line with Basel principles, and in Indonesia and Thailand the available
capital was quickly wiped out by a wave of bad debts. Very significant recapitalisation
of those banking systems has been subsequently necessary – indeed it is a
process which remains to be completed. The sums of money involved are enormous.
It is estimated that the costs of the banking collapse in both Indonesia and Thailand
will amount to more than 40% of GDP, and around 15% in Korea. Should we therefore
conclude that the Basel capital standards, for example, set up in response to crises
of a similar order in Latin America in the 1980s, are hopelessly inadequate? I do
not think so. While there are many problems with the existing structure of the Basel
Capital Accord, which are being addressed currently, the better explanation seems
to be that banks in Asia were not being properly supervised in line with internationally
accepted best practice.
I do not have time today to go into detail on the ways in which the regulatory systems
fall short. But it is clear that many banks were in reality undercapitalised. Their
provisions for non-performing loans were inadequate. Their accounts lacked objectivity
and transparency and rules on connected lending were not effectively policed. They
also ran very significant and under-appreciated indirect currency risks through
their lending to companies who themselves were not adequately hedged.
Once currencies came under pressure, and inadequate external liquidity became the
issue, the opacity of local accounting standards, the insecure basis of provisioning
policies, uncertainties in enforcing collateral, dubious corporate governance and
the inability of central banks and supervisory authorities to impose discipline
were all important factors undermining confidence and aggravating the collapse.
Of course there were other factors that work in these crises, including unstable
macroeconomic policies and, perhaps, inappropriate incentives as lenders believed
they would be bailed out in the event of devaluation. But my focus, as I said at
the start, is on the regulatory dimension.
It seems clear, therefore, that there is a need to enhance supervision, particularly
in economies open to capital flows, and to strengthen their compliance with internationally
agreed best practices. I use compliance both in the sense of firms complying with
the standards set by their supervisors, and in the sense of those supervisors complying
with international standards. In practice, the second sense will embrace the first.
he traditional approach to compliance has been to assume that all members of a particular
club, such as Basel or IOSCO, would comply with the club’s rules, the supervisors
would bring to colleagues attention their own experiences of interpreting rules
and that informal contacts would provide a kind of peer review. This traditional
approach breaks down either when some members do not apply the rules (for example
in the financial crises of the 1990s I have described) or where there are marked
inconsistencies in the way countries apply them.
The groups of supervisors themselves do not have the basis on which to enforce rules
among their voluntary membership. The Basel Committee in particular has tried hard,
and with some success, to reach out beyond its membership, but of course it has
no firm mandate to do so.
So the last two years have seen a growing, albeit far from complete at this stage,
acceptance by supervisors and by the international financial community generally
that the standard setting rôle of international supervisory bodies needs to be complemented
by arrangements for assessing compliance with those standards. And these arrangements
need to go beyond peer review, which has been only modestly successful.
Instead, the necessary expertise, resources and willingness to pass judgement on
compliance with these standards are being put together by the IMF and the World
Bank. The IMF has a worldwide responsibility for economic surveillance, which –
surprisingly you may think – has only recently been extended to cover financial
systems in any depth. Both the Fund and the Bank have lending programmes designed
to help countries recover from or avoid financial crises and both institutions are
expanding their financial policy departments and enhancing their liaison with supervisors
in developed countries in particular, who have agreed to lend staff resources to
the international financial institutions to support this compliance assessment work.
In the case of banking supervision, arrangements are now moving forward, though
much work lies ahead in the practical application and there are some doubts about
whether the IFIs have the records they need to complete the job. The securities
and insurance areas are a little behind, as they discuss with the IFIs how best
the work should be done, and who should take the lead.
The Fund and the Bank have now completed around 30 country assessments of compliance
with the core principles of banking supervision, and more are planned. Increasingly
these assessments are being done within a much broader framework, known as the financial
sector assessment programme – a joint Fund/Bank collaboration effort based
on joint teams and drawing in supervisors from some national authorities, including
the FSA. Around a dozen FSAPs are underway or in preparation. I understand that
India is one of the countries currently discussing an assessment programme. The
Reserve Bank of India has already taken one important step in preparing a self-assessment
of its own compliance with Basel Core Principles, which it has also published on
the Internet. This is a commendable move, which other supervisors would do well
to follow.
The outcome of these assessments will be available to the authorities in the countries
concerned and to the senior management of the IFIs. There is no agreement, as yet,
on how much further to go. Some governments will no doubt choose to make public
the full assessment, though perhaps with the exclusion of sensitive information
about individual institutions. Other governments see difficulty in the Fund and
the Bank combining their rôle as confidential policy adviser with that of impartial
assessor. Squaring this circle may involve convincing reluctant governments that
it is in their longer term interests to be open about their financial sectors and
reform plans. My own view is that there should be a strong presumption in favour
of publication as you have done with your self-assessment. But of course the most
important thing is follow up. Compliance assessments should help national authorities
design and carry through programmes to strengthen their financial systems and those
programmes may well be given added credibility by being supported by international
assessments.
And supervisors in other markets will, I believe, increasingly use the Basel Core
Principles, and the Fund’s view of compliance with them, in assessing the health
of banks with branches in their jurisdictions.
So, to summarise a rather complex picture, I would maintain that we are in the midst
of a quiet revolution in international financial regulation. The main elements of
that quiet revolution are:
-
|
much more outreach for banking supervisors, above all to supervisors in emerging
markets;
|
-
|
increasing acceptance by all supervisors that core principles of supervision, rigorously
applied in all countries of the world, are essential;
|
-
|
increasing acceptance of the need for external monitoring to ensure compliance with
those core principles;
|
-
|
a willingness by supervisors to work much more closely than before with the financial
institutions as the leaders of that monitoring exercise;
|
-
|
greater willingness by supervisors to work more closely with each other across borders
and across traditional sectors of banking, securities and insurance;
|
-
|
a willingness by the Fund and the Bank to take on the rôle of monitoring and to
integrate financial sector surveillance and reconstruction much more closely into
their work; and
|
-
|
a desire by the international financial community to consider more carefully the
threats to financial stability, to put in place better incentives for avoiding such
crises, and to bring together the key government officials, supervisors, central
banks and the financial institutions, through the new Financial Stability Forum.
|
So what are the implications of this quiet revolution for emerging market countries?
My answer to that question must begin with an important disclaimer. I have never
run a financial system, or overseen one, in an emerging market. For a while in the
1970s, the United Kingdom seemed to be a disappearing market, but we have recovered
from that, and London is now the most international and sophisticated financial
market in the world. We also benefit from a very well capitalised banking system,
a traditionally open and competitive market, and a very well established set of
institutions, with a well developed tradition of leaving decisions on regulatory
matters to independent institutions insulated as far as possible from political
interference. I recognise that these features of the UK scene, which we tend to
take for granted, are luxuries in many emerging markets.
This is a roundabout way of saying that when I suggest what might need to be done
in emerging markets to enhance the strength of their financial systems, I am not
on the firmest of ground.
So with that disclaimer firmly before you, I will nonetheless hazard a few observations
which I hope may be helpful.
Perhaps the best place to start is with the markets themselves. Why have normal
market mechanisms not operated properly to weed out poorly performing institutions
and create a healthy competitive financial system? There are a number of potential
answers to that question. But factors which can encourage banks and other financial
institutions to take on too much risk, with the occasional panic when reality takes
hold, include:
-
|
excessive safety nets at the national level, including too extensive guarantees
to depositors, and a reluctance to take prompt action to deal with failing banks;
this is seen as leading to banks’ risk-taking being partly underwritten by the authorities;
|
-
|
excessive safety nets at international level, arising from large country rescue
packages, which can allow banks to enjoy returns higher than justified by the risks;
|
-
|
incentives, for example in the 1988 Basel Capital Accord, which may unduly encourage
short term capital flows; and
|
-
|
excessive reliance on banks for financial intermediation; and insufficient use of
other mechanisms, especially securities markets.
|
So it is important to ensure, for regulators to do their job effectively, that the
appropriate pre-conditions for effective banking supervision are in place. The Basel
Committee defined five pre-conditions for effective supervision in banking, and
I am sure that something very similar applies in the case of both investment and
insurance business. They are:
-
|
First, a reasonably stable macroeconomic environment (an easy thing to say, of course);
|
-
|
Second, a well developed public infrastructure for financial markets, particularly
including well specified accounting rules and implementation practices. I cannot
emphasise too strongly the importance of good accounting practices. Economically
sound financials are the cornerstone of any properly functioning market economy.
Without that, supervision and regulatory systems are houses built on shifting sands;
|
-
|
Third, effective market discipline through transparency and the avoidance as far
as possible of uncertain or implicit government guarantees;
|
-
|
Fourth, procedures for efficient resolution of problems in financial institutions;
and
|
-
|
Fifth, appropriate, and by that I mean limited, safety nets.
|
I would personally add that competition, particularly foreign competition, is another
important requirement for a healthy financial sector. It is worth noting that most
countries in Latin America, following their extensive banking crises in the early
1980s, opened up their financial systems and strengthened supervision, whereas many
countries in Asia have made it more difficult for foreign competition to enter,
thus closing off one important transmission mechanism for good management and new
techniques to strengthen the domestic financial sector. In South East Asia it is
ironic that the open trading policy so successfully pursued by many countries and
manufacturers, and which was celebrated in the so called East Asia miracle, were
not followed in financial services. Reform programmes in these countries now put
a welcome emphasis on opening trade in financial services and on the cross border
establishment of competing firms. There are important developments under way in
India which will open up important sectors here, notably insurance.
I would also add another linked point. Emerging markets would do well to broaden
their financial intermediation systems in future. There are clear advantages to
be had from avoiding excessive reliance on banks. Measures to promote domestic bond
markets are well worth considering. Of course low and stable inflation is an important
prerequisite, but there may be other tax and market infrastructure issues to consider
as well.
Beyond these pre-conditions, there is of course the need for appropriate regulatory
institutions, and for those institutions to be given the power and independence
to pursue the good principles of supervision which are available, in the well specified
form, from the international groupings of regulators. The appropriate institutional
arrangements will certainly vary, country by country, depending on the nature of
their public institutions, on the one hand, and on the structure of the financial
markets, on the other. In some cases it may be appropriate for banking, securities
and insurance supervision to be carried out separately. That may be so, for example,
where the sectoral divisions are enshrined in law, as has been the case until very
recently in the United States, for example.
In a country like the United Kingdom, where there are no impediments to banks owning
insurance companies, or vice versa, and where both can engage in securities business,
there is in my view a powerful case for a single regulatory institution, as we have
now established, following models pioneered in Scandinavia. We have since been followed
by Japan and Korea, among others.
And what of the rôle of the central bank? Here, again, I do not think that there
is a general answer, applicable at all times and in all countries. We have reached
the view that, in the UK’s circumstances, it makes sense to separate banking supervision
from the monetary authority. That is partly, indeed perhaps very largely, because
we believe that banking, securities and insurance supervision should be put together.
And securities supervision, particularly the investor protection dimensions, are
not the natural habitat of central banks. The government also took the view that
it would be easier for the Bank of England to establish its credibility as an independent
monetary institution if it were not at the same time engaged in the messy, and sometimes
mucky business of banking supervision! Bank failures there inevitably will be, even
in the best regulated market – perhaps particularly in the best regulated
market, I might add! (Since, following my earlier strictures about the rôle of markets,
a financial system in which bank failure was impossible would be highly unlikely
to be the most efficient and effective system available).
On the other hand, in countries where the central bank is well established as an
independent institution, and where the interplay between the banking system and
the government’s finances, perhaps because of state ownership, or state run programmes
of lending, is close, then one can see a stronger argument for central bank involvement
in banking supervision.
I think it is fair to say that, internationally, there is a modest trend towards
the separation of monetary and supervisory responsibilities, but that is certainly
not true everywhere, and a recent paper from some academic enthusiasts for merging
banking, securities and insurance supervision has argued that, in many developing
countries, the central bank remains the most appropriate home for prudential supervision.
I would re-emphasise that, in my view, independence and the ability to take unpopular
decisions and carry them through is far more important than the title of the institution,
or its relationship with the central bank or ministry of finance.
Lastly, and this is always a popular point to make to institutions responsible for
financial supervision, it is vital to have well staffed, well trained and well paid
financial regulators! It is a struggle, everywhere, to maintain a strong cadre of
regulators. While financial institutions complain about regulators, often rather
vociferously, they also show an enormous appetite for recruiting and employing their
staff. We find that the right structures and disciplines are created if the regulator
is as close as possible to the market place and, in particular, if the regulator
is paid for by financial institutions themselves. That is the case in London. It
does not resolve all funding problems, but it does mean that if we need to raise
more funds because market salaries are rising, then the institutions concerned can
understand the point, and indeed have the basis to contest it if it is wrong. So
I am strongly in favour of market based funding systems for regulators, which put
the incentives for economy and efficiency, on the one hand, and for maintaining
appropriate levels of expertise on the other, in the right place. It also has the
optical benefit of achieving a reduction in recorded levels of public expenditure,
something which ministries of finance around the world are devoted to achieving.
As I close, I will try briefly to summarise the argument I have attempted to make
this evening.
The financial market crises of 1997 and 1998 vividly illustrated the need for reform
in the international financial system. Much of the early debate around that reform
centred on proposals for a new international financial architecture, and for new
international institutions. Some have been disappointed that only modest institutional
changes – the establishment of the G20 and the Financial Stability Forum –
have been forthcoming and have, in my view wrongly, concluded that little has changed.
But my own analysis suggests that, below the parapet, so to speak, there are more
important and far reaching changes underway in the international financial plumbing
than has generally been perceived. Indeed it is arguable that those changes, taken
together, amount to a quiet revolution in international financial regulation with,
for the first time, the monitoring and compliance muscle of the international financial
institutions linked to the standard setting expertise of the regulatory clubs. Much
of the framework is now in place; a great deal of work and hard political decisions
lie ahead in making it a reality worldwide.
That new alliance, reinforced a by a renewed awareness around the world of the huge
public costs of financial system failures, should gradually create stronger pressures
on countries to engage in financial system reform and restructuring programmes.
It will create greater pressure, too, for implementation of the core principles
of good supervision, established by Basel, IOSCO and the IAIS. And it will throw
sharp focus on the nature of the national regulatory institutions in place, and
the status and quality of those institutions, which are responsible for promoting
and policing good practice.
There is no one simple institutional model which can be recommended for universal
application. And each country will wish to assess the pros and cons of different
structures, in the light of their own financial markets and political structures.
The developed countries offer a range of working models from which to choose. What
is crucial is to ensure that the regulatory institutions have the independence and
authority to take firm, sometimes unpopular decisions in a timely manner.
Finally, let me add one reality check. I do not think that all of this reform, all
this market surveillance, all this regulatory good practice, will produce a world
free of financial crises. Financial markets are inherently unstable. They are there
to manage and intermediate risk. They will go up and down, sometimes dramatically.
We should not try to prohibit this volatility. Of course we want to be in a position
where we can manage crises, and mitigate their worst effects. But a realistic aspiration
might be to design a system which will cope with three of the next five crises,
rather than five of the next three. Or to put it another way, if we over-control,
we will damage the economic utility of the very markets we are trying to develop.
So I wish you a volatile, but not too volatile, future.