PART TWO: THE WORKING AND OPERATIONS OF THE RESERVE BANK OF INDIA
III - MONETARY POLICY OPERATIONS
Monetary policy in 2011-12 had to address the risk of entrenchment of inflation pressures and unhinged inflation
expectations during the first half of the financial year and the significant slowdown in domestic growth even while
maintaining its anti-inflationary stance during the second half. Further, with the liquidity deficit remaining
above the comfort level due to a mix of structural and frictional factors, the Reserve Bank had to undertake active
liquidity management to inject durable primary liquidity. Thus in the evolving growth-inflation dynamics, the
monetary policy stance continued to be tight, up to mid-December 2011 but policy rates were kept at a pause mode
during the remainder of the year with cuts in cash reserve ratio and OMO operations for supporting liquidity.
During 2012-13 so far, on growing evidence of slowdown in the economy, the Reserve Bank using available space to
cut policy rates frontloaded the policy action in April 2012, but maintained status quo on rates in June and July
2012 as inflation concerns persisted. The SLR was reduced in July 2012, to provide liquidity to facilitate credit
availability to productive sectors.
III.1 The Reserve Bank’s monetary policy stance
till December 2011 was predominantly guided by
the objective of containing inflation and anchoring
inflation expectations. However, subsequently as
growth decelerated sharply the Reserve Bank had
to strike a balance between the objectives of growth
stabilisation and low and stable inflation. Liquidity
conditions mostly remained within the comfort zone
before turning tight during November 2011 - March
2012. Deficit liquidity conditions reflected
autonomous factors - both frictional and structural
– in the form of sharp turnaround in government
cash balances from deficit to surplus, the wedge
between the credit and deposit growth, rise in
currency in circulation, and drain of rupee liquidity
on account of the Reserve Bank’s forex market
intervention to stem excessive volatility in the rupee
exchange rate. The Reserve Bank responded with
large scale open market operations and CRR cuts
to offset the autonomous drain in liquidity. Reflecting
these initiatives, the liquidity deficit condition moved
back in the comfort zone in the Q2 of 2012-13 so
far (till August 13, 2012).
MONETARY POLICY OPERATIONS:
CONTEXT AND RATIONALE
III.2 Monetary policy at the beginning of 2011-12
faced the challenge of a high and persistent
inflation. There were signs of further accentuation
of the underlying inflationary pressures, posing the
risk of firming up inflation expectations further.
Monetary policy was, therefore, geared to ensure
containment of inflationary pressures, even if it
was at the cost of sacrificing some growth in the
short-run.
III.3 Headline WPI inflation during April-
November 2011 continued to remain at an elevated
level of 9.7 per cent on an average, significantly
above the comfort zone of the Reserve Bank. Nonfood
manufacturing inflation, as an indicator of
demand pressures, averaged at 7.7 per cent during
April-November 2011, as compared with around
4.0 per cent during the last six years. Enduring
non-food manufactured products inflation emanated
partly from persistent pricing power of producers, wherein they were able to pass on rising commodity
input prices and wage costs to consumers on the
back of strong demand.
III.4 In response to the prevailing inflationary
pressures and anticipated inflation trajectory during
April-November 2011, the Reserve Bank raised the
policy repo rate five times cumulatively by 175 basis
points, with the increase in May and July of the
order of 50 basis points each (Table III.1).
III.5 While inflation trajectory indicated some
softening of inflationary pressure by December
2011, there were signs of a marked deceleration
of domestic growth brought about by the combined
impact of a worsening global environment, the
cumulative impact of past monetary policy
tightening and domestic policy uncertainties. In the
light of these developments, the mid-quarter review
of December 2011 signalled a pause. In its
guidance, the Reserve Bank noted that in light of
the growing downside risks to growth, further monetary policy actions would be directed towards
a reversal in cycle. However, that was to be
contingent upon inflation remaining on its projected
downward trajectory.
Table III.1: Movements in Key Policy Variables |
(Per cent) |
Effective |
Repo Rate |
Cash Reserve Ratio |
Statutory Liquidity Ratio |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
May 3, 2011 |
7.25 |
6.00 |
24.00 |
|
(+0.50) |
|
|
June 16, 2011 |
7.50 |
6.00 |
24.00 |
|
(+0.25) |
|
|
July 26, 2011 |
8.00 |
6.00 |
24.00 |
|
(+0.50) |
|
|
September 16, 2011 |
8.25 |
6.00 |
24.00 |
|
(+0.25) |
|
|
October 25, 2011 |
8.50 |
6.00 |
24.00 |
|
(+0.25) |
|
|
January 28, 2012 |
8.50 |
5.50 |
24.00 |
|
|
(-0.50) |
|
March 10, 2012 |
8.50 |
4.75 |
24.00 |
|
|
(-0.75) |
|
April 17, 2012 |
8.00 |
4.75 |
24.00 |
|
(-0.50) |
|
|
June 18, 2012 |
8.00 |
4.75 |
24.00 |
August 11, 2012 |
8.00 |
4.75 |
23.00 |
|
|
|
(-1.00) |
Note: 1. Repo indicates injection of liquidity.
2. Figures in parentheses indicate change in policy rate in
percentage points. |
III.6 From the beginning of the fourth quarter of
2011-12, there were indications of a moderating
trend in inflation. However, during this period, the
risks to growth increased further resulting in a
downward projection of GDP growth for 2011-12
from 7.6 per cent to 7.0 per cent in the third quarter
review. A major concern faced by monetary policy
at this juncture was the overall liquidity deficit which
remained much beyond the comfort zone of the
Reserve Bank. Acknowledging that such structural
liquidity constraints in the economy, if not addressed,
could lead to disruption of credit flow and further
exacerbate growth risks, the Reserve Bank reduced
CRR in two steps effective January 28, 2012 and
March 10, 2012, by a cumulative 125 basis points
with the aim of injecting durable primary liquidity
into the system. The challenge for monetary policy
while undertaking measures aimed at active
liquidity intervention was that, inflation was still
above the comfort level despite some moderation
and there was significant amount of suppressed
inflation in the economy.
III.7 By April 2012, there was growing evidence
that the economy was slowing down more than
what was anticipated earlier. Considering the need
to support the growth impulses, the key policy repo
rate was reduced by 50 basis points to 8 per cent
on April 17, 2012. Even while reducing the policy
rate, the Reserve Bank noted that the risks to
inflation persisted in the form of high fiscal deficit
driven by revenue expenditure, lagged passthrough
of administered price increases, crude
price uncertainty and structural food demandsupply
imbalances. It was noted that these risks
could limit the scope for further reduction of rates.
III.8 A marked deterioration in global economic
and financial conditions coupled with significant
moderation in domestic growth raised several
deepening concerns in June 2012. Concomitantly, the headline inflation continued to be above levels
consistent with sustainable growth. The Reserve
Bank assessed that several factors were responsible
for the slowdown in activity, particularly in investment,
with the role of interest rates being relatively small.
Accordingly, it was viewed that further reduction in
the policy interest rate at that juncture, rather than
supporting growth, could exacerbate inflationary
pressures and accentuate macro-economic risks.
In view of these factors, the Reserve Bank decided
to keep the CRR as well as policy repo rate
unchanged in its mid-quarter monetary policy
review in June 2012.
III.9 At the current juncture, the global economy
is facing a synchronised slowdown, while domestic
macroeconomic situation, particularly slowdown in
growth and persistent inflation continues to raise
concerns. Against this backdrop, the stance of
monetary policy in July 2012 was shaped by
considerations of containing inflation and inflationary
expectations, supporting a sustainable growth path
over the medium-term and continuing to provide
liquidity to facilitate credit availability to productive
sectors. In line with this policy stance, the Reserve
Bank maintained a status quo on policy rates but
reduced the statutory liquidity ratio (SLR) of SCBs
from 24.0 per cent to 23.0 per cent of NDTL with
effect from the fortnight beginning August 11, 2012.
III.10 Going forward, reflecting the setback to the
global recovery and the resultant continuation of
easy global monetary conditions as also weather
related adversities in several parts of the world, the
outlook for food and commodity prices, especially
crude oil, has turned adverse. Risks to headline
inflation persist from suppressed inflation and
structural gaps between demand and supply of
food. Additional risks to food inflation have emerged
from the deficient and uneven monsoon. In turn,
persistent elevated headline inflation driven by food
and fuel price pressures carries the significant risk
of unhinging inflation expectations. Further, the
lowering of trend rate of growth in post crisis
scenario due to sustained deceleration in investment activities and supply bottlenecks on a variety of
fronts – infrastructure, energy, minerals and labour
- has added to risks of a pick-up in inflation in
response to even a moderate growth recovery.
Monetary policy in such a scenario has to maintain
a fine balance such that while addressing
short-term growth concerns, price stability is
maintained to ensure sustainable growth over the
medium-term.
New Operating Procedure of Monetary Policy
III.11 The Reserve Bank introduced a new
operating procedure of monetary policy in May
2011 to have an explicit operating target, a single
policy rate and a formal corridor system with a 100
bps spread on either side of the policy rate to
replace the earlier system of repo and reverse repo
as policy rates without having an explicit target and
a fixed-width formal corridor (Please see Box III.2
of Annual Report 2010-11 for details). Following
the implementation of the new operating procedure
of monetary policy, the call rate stabilised and
hovered within the fixed corridor barring a few
occasions when the call rate exceeded the upper
bound of the corridor owing to tightness of liquidity
on account of advance tax outflows (Chart III.1).
The implementation of new operating procedure has also led to a greater integration of financial
market, reflected in the call rate moving closely and
in tandem with other money market rates than
earlier. Debt market segment has also evidenced
a better transmission from the call rate with
increasing alignment between rates on debt market
instruments and call rate.
|
Performance of the Base Rate System
III.12 The Base Rate system, which replaced the
benchmark prime lending rate (BPLR) system
introduced in 2003, and became effective from July
2010, has contributed to improvement in the pricing
of loans, enhanced transparency in lending rates and improvement of the assessment of the
transmission of monetary policy (Box III.1). This
combined with freeing of interest rates on export
credit in foreign currency effective May 5, 2012 have
resulted in complete deregulation of interest rates
on lending by commercial banks.
Deregulation of the Savings Bank Deposit Rate
III.13 As proposed in the Second Quarter Review
of Monetary Policy 2010-11, a discussion paper on
deregulation of savings bank deposit rate was
prepared and placed on the Reserve Bank’s
website on April 28, 2011 for suggestions/feedback
from the general public. Based on the feedback received and after examining the pros and cons of
such deregulation, on balance, the Reserve Bank decided to deregulate the savings bank deposit
interest rate, effective October 25, 2011 (Box III.2).
Box III.1
Base Rate System: An Assessment
In order to address concerns posed by the non-transparent
BPLR system, the Base Rate system was introduced on the
recommendations of a Working Group (Chairman: Shri
Deepak Mohanty) (See Box III.1 of Annual Report 2010-11).
Since the inception of the Base Rate system, liquidity in the
financial system has remained in deficit mode. During this
period, banks have become by and large synchronous and
more responsive in their change of Base Rates to changes
in the policy rate by the Reserve Bank. This is evident from
the fact that as the Reserve Bank progressively increased its
Repo Rate, banks also increased their Base Rates. Initially,
i.e. during July – December 2010, the pace was slower as
the system had been migrating from surplus mode to a
deficit mode. Reflecting this, Base Rates increased, on
average, by 58 bps following the rise in Repo Rate by 75
bps. Thereafter, the momentum picked up and continued till
March 2011 (Table).
Thereafter, following gradual moderation in the growth of
economic activity and the resultant slowdown in the growth of
non-food credit, particularly during the second half of 2011-
12, the pace of increase in the Base Rate relative to that of the
Repo rate slowed down while the number of days taken to
raise the Base Rate also increased. Further, as the Reserve
Bank reduced its Repo Rate by 50 bps on April 17, 2012, 24
banks accounting for around 63 per cent of aggregate credit
reduced their Base Rates by, on average, 23 bps so far (till
July 2012). The pass-through of reduction in Repo Rate and
cumulative reduction in CRR to banks’ deposit and lending
rates was impacted by higher weighted average cost of
outstanding deposits, higher government borrowing, increase
in NPAs and sustained high inflation.
Overall, however, the transmission of monetary policy has
been strengthened under the Base Rate system as compared
with the BPLR system.
Table : Extent of Increase in both Deposit Rate and Base Rate and Time Taken by Public/Private Sector Banks |
Period (Month over Month) |
Change in Repo Rate (bps) |
Change in Cash Reserve Ratio (CRR) (bps) |
Change in Deposit Rate (bps) |
Average change in Base Rate (bps) |
Average no. of days taken to change the Base Rate* |
No. of Banks changed the Base Rate |
Share of Credit of banks that changed their Base Rate (%)# |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
Jul-Dec 10 |
75 |
- |
25-325 |
58 |
141 |
41 |
93.1 |
Dec10-Mar 11 |
50 |
- |
25-450 |
73 |
96 |
47 |
96.5 |
Mar-May 11 |
50 |
- |
10-275 |
55 |
85 |
38 |
89.0 |
May-Oct 11 |
125 |
- |
05-425 |
95 |
129 |
46 |
94.5 |
Oct 11-Mar 12 |
- |
-125 |
05-500 |
29 |
93 |
13 |
9.7 |
Mar-Jul 12 |
-50 |
- |
(-25)-(-400) |
-23 |
247 |
24 |
62.6 |
- : Indicates no change. * : Since the date of last change in Base Rate. # : As at end-point. |
Box III.2
Deregulation of Savings Bank Deposit Interest Rate – Rationale and Impact
The process of interest rate deregulation, which began in
the early 1990s, was largely completed by 1997. On the
liability side, apart from the interest rate on current account,
the only interest rate that continued to remain regulated was
the savings deposit interest rate until October 25, 2011. The
discussion paper on deregulation of savings bank deposit
rate delineated both the pros and cons of deregulation of
savings bank deposit rate as under:
Pros
a) Deregulation of the interest rate on savings deposit will
make the rate flexible along with other interest rates
depending on the market conditions.
b) Regulation of savings deposit interest rate not only
reduced its relative attractiveness, it also adversely
affected the transmission of monetary policy.
c) Savings deposits constitute a large proportion of total
deposits. However, owing to regulation of interest
rate, there was hardly any competition in this segment
with both banks and depositors acting passively. This
inhibited product innovations.
Cons
a) Savings deposits have been a source of cheap funds
for banks. In addition, banks treat a large portion of
savings deposits as ‘core’ deposits, which are used to
finance long-term assets. This, combined with skewed
distribution of savings deposits, often raised the
concern that deregulation might lead to an unhealthy
competition resulting in a large shift of deposits from
some banks exposing them to a serious risk of assetliability
mismatch.
b) Should unhealthy competition result in increase in
interest rate and the overall cost of funds, banks might
be discouraged from maintaining savings deposits with
small amounts due to the associated high transaction
costs.
c) In the event, if savings deposit interest rates decline
markedly, income flow to small savers/pensioners may
get affected adversely.
d) Following deregulation, some banks may introduce
some complex products, which may not be so easily
understood by savers. These strategies may result in
increase in the mis-selling of savings bank products.
Deregulation and its Impact
The discussion paper evoked wide-ranging responses
from a cross-section of stakeholders, ranging from the
suggestion that savings bank deposit interest rate should not be deregulated at all to the suggestion that it should
be deregulated completely. The Reserve Bank examined
the suggestions. On balance, it was felt that the time was
appropriate to move forward and complete the process of
deregulation of rupee interest rates. Accordingly, it was
decided to deregulate the savings bank deposit interest
rate effective October 25, 2011 (announced in the Second
Quarter Review of Monetary Policy 2011-12), subject to the
following two conditions:
-
First, each bank will have to offer a uniform interest
rate on savings bank balance up to `100 thousand,
irrespective of the amount in the account within this
limit.
-
Second, for savings bank balance over `100 thousand,
a bank may provide differential rates of interest, if
it so chooses. However, there should not be any
discrimination from customer to customer on interest
rates for similar amount.
Since the deregulation of savings deposit interest rate, five
private sector banks, ten foreign banks and one co-operative
bank have increased their savings deposit interest rate in
the range of 100-500 basis points during the period so far.
So far, none of the public sector banks has increased its
savings deposit interest rate.
Any unhealthy competition has not been seen amongst
banks so far. This is because 15 SCBs, which have raised
saving deposit rate, account for only 4.2 per cent of
aggregate deposits. However, these 15 banks witnessed
above-average growth in their savings deposits during the
period so far. As a result, the share of these banks to total
savings bank deposits of the banking system increased
from 1.8 per cent to 2.1 per cent in the post-deregulation
period so far up to July 2012 and their contribution to the
total growth of savings bank deposits stood at around 5 per
cent during this period.
With regard to both free and chargeable services as admissible
to savings bank account holders during the pre- and postderegulation
period, a quick survey of 11 banks comprising
public sector, private sector and foreign banks reveals that
banks that raised savings deposits interest rates have not
changed their non-interest charges during post-deregulation
period so far. However, in contrast, while two major private
sector banks have made upward revisions in their non-interest
charges, one public sector bank reduced such charges during
the post-deregulation period. Since majority of banks are yet
to change their savings deposits interest rates, the change in
non-interest charges is yet to gather momentum.
Box III.3
Bank Rate Alignment with the MSF Rate
Section 49 of the Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934 requires
the Reserve Bank to make public (from time to time) the
standard rate at which it is prepared to buy or re-discount bills
of exchange or other commercial papers eligible for purchase
under that Act. Since discounting/rediscounting by the
Reserve Bank has remained in disuse, the Bank Rate has not
been active. Moreover, even for the conduct of monetary
policy, instead of changing the Bank Rate, monetary policy
signalling was done through modulations in the reverse repo
rate and the repo rate under the Liquidity Adjustment Facility
(LAF) (till May 3, 2011) and the policy repo rate under the
revised operating procedure of monetary policy (from May 3,
2011 onwards). As a result, the Bank Rate had remained
unchanged at 6 per cent since April 2003. Under the revised operating procedure, the marginal standing facility (MSF),
instituted at 100 basis points above the policy repo rate,
serves the purpose of the Bank Rate. Being the discount rate,
the Bank Rate should technically be higher than the policy
repo rate. The Reserve Bank consulted various organisations/
stakeholders relying on the Bank Rate as a reference rate and
based on the feedback received, it was determined that the
Bank Rate should normally stay aligned to the MSF rate.
Accordingly, it was decided that with effect from the close of
business on February 13, 2012, the Bank Rate will stand
aligned with the MSF rate with the one-time technical
adjustment. All penal interest rates on shortfall in reserve
requirements, which are specifically linked to the Bank Rate,
also stand revised accordingly.
Bank Rate - One-time Technical Adjustment
III.14 Effective from February 13, 2012, the Bank
Rate has been aligned with the MSF rate through
a one-time technical adjustment (Box III.3). This
decision was based on a review of the relevance
of the Bank Rate in the context of the current
operating framework of monetary policy and it was
clarified that the one-time adjustment should not
be seen as a monetary policy action.
Liquidity Management
III.15 The Reserve Bank, like many other central
banks keeps the systemic liquidity in deficit mode in order to enhance the transmission of monetary
policy. Consistent with this objective, liquidity
conditions generally remained in deficit mode
throughout 2011-12. However, the deficit exceeded
the indicative comfort level of one per cent of net
demand and time liabilities (NDTL) of SCBs from
the beginning of November 2011 due to both
structural and frictional factors(Please see
discussion on liquidity conditions in Part II.3: Money
and Credit).
III.16 In order to ease the liquidity situation,
the Reserve Bank undertook several measures
(Box III.4).
Box III.4
Liquidity Management Operations
Liquidity conditions changed course significantly during
2011-12 on account of both structural and frictional factors.
Liquidity conditions remained in surplus mode during early
April 2011, turned into deficit but mostly remained within
comfort zone up to October and subsequently turned into
excessive deficit mode during the remainder of the year.
On April 8, 2011, the Reserve Bank had preemptively
extended the additional liquidity support to SCBs under the
LAF to the extent of up to one per cent of their NDTL till May
6, 2011. Moreover, the second LAF (SLAF) on a daily basis
was also extended, synchronously. Following the introduction
of MSF on May 9, 2011, as a part of the Modified Operating
Procedures of Monetary Policy announced in the Annual
Monetary Policy Statement 2011-12, the second LAF was
discontinued.
While repo auction under LAF continued to be conducted
between 9.30 am and 10.30 am, the Reserve Bank shifted
the reverse repo auction under LAF to the afternoon time
slot of 4.30 pm to 5.00 pm on all working days with effect
from August 16, 2011. The prime reason for shifting the
reverse repo window to the afternoon slot was to encourage
the market participants to trade amongst themselves and to
park any surplus with the Reserve Bank only after exhausting
all other avenues to deploy the funds in the money market.
Comfortable liquidity conditions during first half (H1) of 2011-
12 were reflected in the access to MSF only on two
occasions, viz., `1 billion on June 10 and `41.05 billion on
July 15, 2011.
During the second half (H2) of 2011-12, liquidity conditions
tightened reflecting the decline in the level of WMA/OD, rise in currency in circulation due to festive season currency
demand and forex market operations by the Reserve Bank.
As soon as the liquidity deficit exceeded the Reserve Bank’s
indicative comfort zone of (+/-) 1 per cent of NDTL from the
second week of November 2011, the Reserve Bank began
conducting OMO purchase auctions of Government securities
from November 24, 2011. Reflecting quarterly advance tax
outflows and forex market operations by the Reserve Bank,
the average daily net liquidity injection under the LAF
increased further to around `1,170 billion in December 2011
from around `920 billion in November 2011 (Chart 1). MSF
was availed on six occasions during December 2011.
With a view to providing flexibility to SCBs in their liquidity
management, the Reserve Bank conducted additional repo
operation under LAF on December 16, 2011, over and above
the existing LAF and MSF arrangements. Furthermore,
keeping in view the prevailing overall liquidity conditions, the
Reserve Bank permitted banks on December 21, 2011 to
avail funds on overnight basis under the MSF against their
excess SLR holdings in addition to the existing facility where
they were already allowed to avail themselves of funds on
overnight basis below the stipulated SLR, up to one per cent
of their respective NDTL.
As the liquidity stress persisted through January 2012 partly
reflecting forex market operations by the Reserve Bank, the
Reserve Bank reduced the CRR of scheduled banks by 50
bps to 5.5 per cent of their NDTL, effective January 28, 2012.
With a view to providing flexibility to market participants in
their liquidity management, the Reserve Bank re-introduced
additional Repo under LAF (second LAF Repo) on reporting
Fridays, effective February 10, 2012. The average daily LAF injection rose further to around `1,405 billion in February
2012 from around `1,290 billion in January 2012, partly
reflecting the build-up of the centre’s surplus balance.
Liquidity conditions tightened significantly during March
2012. The Reserve Bank pro-actively reduced the CRR by
75 bps effective March 10, 2012. The average daily net
outstanding LAF injection reached around `1,570 billion in
March 2012. The net liquidity injection through the LAF
escalated to an all-time high on March 30, 2012 (`2,028
billion) as banks tried to shore-up their balance sheets and
front-load cash reserves. Banks availed MSF on nine
occasions during the month.
With a view to providing flexibility to SCBs in their liquidity
management, the Reserve Bank conducted additional LAFRepo
on March 30, 2012, and LAF and MSF on March 31,
2012.
The liquidity conditions continued to remain in deficit mode
in April 2012, albeit, on a lower scale, reflecting seasonal
draw-down of government cash balances. Subsequently,
however, there has been an easing of the liquidity stress in
the system brought about by the Reserve Bank’s active
management of liquidity through LAF and OMOs. The
narrowing of the wedge between credit and deposit growth
rates also helped in restricting the liquidity deficit in the
situation. In order to provide greater liquidity cushion, the
Reserve Bank also undertook several measures. In April 2012,
the borrowing limit of SCBs under the MSF was raised from
one per cent to two per cent of their NDTL. Further, the eligible
limit of the Export Credit Refinance (ECR) facility for
scheduled banks (excluding RRBs) was enhanced from 15
per cent of the outstanding export credit eligible for refinance
to 50 per cent, effective fortnight beginning June 30, 2012.
This was estimated to provide additional liquidity support to
banks of over `300 billion. In response to suggestions
received from the market participants for extending the timings
of evening LAF, the Reserve Bank decided to conduct reverse
repo auction under LAF and MSF operation between 4.45
pm and 5.15 pm with effect from July 16, 2012. The statutory
liquidity ratio (SLR)of SCBs was reduced from 24.0 per cent
to 23.0 per cent of NDTL with effect from the fortnight
beginning August 11, 2012, with a view to providing additional
liquidity to facilitate credit availability to productive sectors.
This is expected to release additional liquidity to the tune of
`680 billion.
|
III.17 Reflecting these measures, combined with
decline in government cash balances, the liquidity
stress has eased in Q2 of 2012-13 so far (till August
13, 2012) and the extent of deficit has remained
close to the Reserve Bank’s comfort level of one
per cent of NDTL.
Overall Assessment
III.18 During April - November 2011, monetary
policy was directed towards ‘management of
inflation’ in response to an inflationary process that
remained at a level much above the comfort zone
of the Reserve Bank for almost two years. Monetary policy in this scenario was guided by the
consideration that persistent high inflation is
inimical to sustained long-run growth as it harms
both financial saving and investment by creating
uncertainty. Hence, the objective of regaining price
stability even at the cost of sacrificing some growth
in the short-run, gained precedence. Towards the
last quarter of the financial year, however, there
were strong signals of a slowdown in growth to
below post-crisis trend levels. Inflation started
moderating since December 2011. Keeping in view
the growth slowdown the Reserve Bank front
loaded the policy rate reduction in April 2012 and
adjusted the policy rates to levels consistent with the growth moderation. Nevertheless, with
significant risk of inflation persisting, monetary
policy had to maintain a fine balance between
supporting growth impulses while at the same time
anchoring inflation expectations and preventing
any resurgence in inflationary pressures. Monetary
policy, during the course of the year, also had to
address structural liquidity constraints and actively
manage liquidity to ensure that it remained in
moderate deficit, consistent with effective monetary
transmission. This further posed a challenge to
communication, in trying to distinguish between
liquidity easing measures from the monetary policy
stance. |