Dear friends,
I am honoured to be invited
to deliver the valedictory address at the 2006 FICCI-IBA Conference. I would
like to begin by complimenting the hosts for their choice of the theme: "Global
Banking: Paradigm Shift". Many distinguished speakers have participated
already in the deliberations and hence I will attempt a broader overview of
globalisation issues at the current juncture. My address is on "Globalisation,
Money and Finance – Uncertainties and Dilemmas". These are in the nature
of random thoughts - to provoke thinking and not to provide answers or practise
preaching.
Globalisation – Is There a Rethink?
In the recent period, a reassessment
of the costs and benefits associated with globalisation seems to be taking place.
Already, the share of the emerging countries in world exports has surged to
43 per cent from 20 per cent in 1970. Domestic structural reforms in the emerging
economies are unlocking the pent-up domestic demand and, in turn, enabling a
greater realisation of the huge potential for growth. So, what is causing the
rethink in both – the developed and the emerging economies? Several factors
seem to be at work.
Firstly, the traditional postulate
that the capital flows from the capital-surplus or developed countries to the
capital-scarce or developing countries, seems to have been disproved in recent
years. Today, we are confronted with the puzzle of capital flowing uphill (Prasad,
Rajan and Subramanian, 2006) that is, from the developing to the developed countries.
The world's largest economy, the United States, currently runs a current account
deficit, financed to a substantial extent by capital exports from the emerging
market economies.
Further, the level of financial
development per se does not seem to determine the direction of capital
flows. Prasad et al argue that the phenomenon mainly reflects the limited
absorption capacity of the developing countries in the context of relatively
lower financial development. However, this explanation can be turned around.
The US, which has perhaps the most well developed financial system, is currently
importing capital. As the developing countries catch up in terms of sophistication
and depth in their financial systems, would the pattern of capital flows change,
and how? In the interregnum, the export of capital from the developing to the
developed countries has no doubt revitalised global growth. But will this or
can this go on?
Secondly, in a globalising world,
the policy makers seem to be confronted with new realities, sometimes hard to
fully comprehend. In a way, the context in which monetary policy is set leads
to a confrontation with the impossible trinity – independent monetary policy,
open capital account and managed exchange rate. The theory holds that at best,
only two out of the three would be feasible. In practice, however, there is
a shift in preference away from the corner solution with respect to financial
imbalances. Currently, intermediate solutions, which were earlier regarded as
‘fuzzy’, are now becoming increasingly relevant. Moreover, in recognition of
the differences between trade and financial integration – first pointed out
by Jagdish Bhagwati – there is less certainty today about the corner solutions
than in the past.
Thirdly, at a practical level,
the recent experience seems to indicate that globalisation may have had accentuated
potential conflicts that can impact the fabric of our societies. Outsourcing
to low-wage countries to derive benefits of lower cost, has generated restiveness
in the labour markets of the advanced countries, particularly in the skilled
segment of tradable services that are more exposed to foreign competition. The
geographical fragmentation of production base has increasingly been used by
big firms as a bargaining tool with workers. Increased emigration from the developing
and emerging countries has depressed wages in the advanced economies and heightened
social tensions. In recent years, the contractionary effects of cooling of the
housing markets may also be building up further pressure against globalisation.
Fourthly, there are wide-spread
concerns about the gaps in international trade rules and regulations, the impasse
in multilateral trade negotiations and consequently, a rising number of regional
and bilateral trade arrangements which could rule out the use of the very policy
measures that were instrumental in the development of today’s mature economies
and late industrialisers.
Fifthly, the rapid pace of globalisation
in monetary and financial relationships has not been accompanied by an improvement
in the international financial architecture. The provision of liquidity to enable
the countries to weather payments difficulties has arguably been inadequate.
Managing financial crisis remains largely a national responsibility. As the
UNCTAD’s Trade and Development Report, 2006 has noted: ‘‘The bulk
of adjustment in case of external imbalances is often concentrated on a group
of developing and transition economies, despite the fact that the source of
such imbalances may occur in the developed world’’ (Overview, p. 38-39).
This seems to have provoked an accumulation of foreign exchange reserves in
the emerging countries.
In the wake of these developments,
there is a growing expression of heightened sensitivity to the costs associated
with globalisation. In the ultimate analysis, public policy has important role
in managing the costs and benefits of globalisation. When the going is good,
public policy is viewed with disfavour. In the face of adverse conditions, however,
public policy intervention is often the only sought-after solution. Accordingly,
it is the public policy which has the best chance of preserving the benefits
of globalisation and ensuring that these are widely shared so as to maintain
support for free trade and to stem protectionism, thereby providing globalisation
with the popular legitimacy which, at present, seems to be sometimes lacking.
"Making Globalisation Work" is the challenge for the policy makers
so that the benefits of globalisation are sufficiently shared and demonstrably
exceed the attendant costs. To quote Chairman Bernanke: ‘‘Further progress
in global economic integration should not be taken for granted…as in the past,
the social and political opposition to openness can be strong… much of it arises
because changes in the patterns of production are likely to threaten the livelihoods
of some workers and the profits of some firms…The natural reaction of those
so affected is to resist change, for example, by seeking the passage of protectionist
measures’’ (Jackson Hole, 2006).
Globalisation and Monetary Policy
While considerations relating to
maximising output and employment weigh as much upon monetary authorities as
maintaining price stability, particularly in the developing countries, domestic
inflation has increasingly become less sensitive to the domestic output gap
and potentially more sensitive to the world output gap. It is, therefore, necessary
for each country to take a holistic approach to the trinity of free flows of
capital, freely floating exchange rates and independent monetary policy. At
a practical policy level, the trinity can be regarded as implausible and difficult,
but manageable through intermediate solutions that adapt to the country-specific
situations. For monetary authorities, the new realities provide, perhaps, unknown
challenges in an uncertain future, heightening the dilemmas in policy-making.
Central banks are often concerned
with the stability / variability of inflation rather than the level of prices.
However, inflation processes have become highly unclear, with soaring commodity
prices co-existing with low consumer prices in an environment of high asset
prices. Amidst these uncertainties, central banks are faced with the need to
recognise the importance of inflation perceptions and inflation expectations
as distinct from inflation numbers. The distinction between inflationary expectations
and inflation perceptions in the context of inflation policy is also worth bearing
in mind. More often than not, the expected change rather than the actual change
in real interest rate, following a change in the policy rate, often drives the
actions of the economic agents. Thus, the ability to condition inflation expectations,
rather than the decisions on the policy rates, is of fundamental importance
to monetary policy making now. In this context, credible communication and creative
engagement with the market and economic agents has emerged as the critical channel
of monetary transmission as against the traditional channels.
The presence of administered interest
rates, even in segments of a financial system, could hold back appropriate adjustments
in real rates as a sequel to changes in the policy rates. What is surprising,
however, is that the financial market rates could also display such impervious
behaviour and thereby, act as the source of nominal rigidities in the economy.
The recent ‘conundrum’ in the financial markets a la Greenspan is a case
in point. As a result, long-term real rates in the financial markets have changed
but not in the desired direction, posing challenges to the effectiveness of
monetary policy even in a market-based system. Therefore, not only the change
in real rates but also the direction of change following changes in the policy
rates is important for the effectiveness of monetary policy.
In a relatively more stable economic
environment, the need, the extent and the duration of the policy interventions
becomes less and less. Central banks are now taking baby steps – sometimes more
frequent steps and at other times after a long gap, and in both directions –
to respond to, what appear to be, ripples rather than huge waves in the sea
of economic activity. For instance, what is considered as a ‘neutral rate’ of
interest, in the present period, appears to be much lower compared to several
years before. The issue of significance here is whether the neutral rate in
respect of the emerging market economies, which has been coming down in tandem
with global rates, will tend to be distinctly higher than in the developed economies.
If so, how much higher would be appropriate?
Even a moderate inflation rate
poses a dilemma in an increasingly open- economy framework. If the domestic
inflation rate of an economy, however low it may be, is higher than the average
inflation rate of its trading partners, it puts pressure on the exchange rate.
In this context, the question of simultaneous balance of the internal and external
sectors becomes a major issue. The conduct of monetary policy inevitably involves
a careful judgment on the relative weights assigned to the domestic and the
global factors and constant reassessment of these in response to evolving circumstances.
In a dynamic setting, when the
financial markets are continually evolving, and payment systems and technology
are changing rapidly, one may not find a clear-cut evidence of stability in
monetary rules and intermediate targeting. In such circumstances, monetary authorities
are being constrained to look at all relevant indicators, following a menu or
a ‘check list’ approach. Discerning news from noise is a persistent dilemma
for conducting monetary policy.
Since external capital flows to
emerging economies cannot be easily predicted and can also reverse even in the
presence of sound fundamentals, monetary authorities have to make choices in
regard to exchange rate and monetary management, very often. The appropriate
management of monetary policy may require the monetary authorities to consider
offsetting the impact of foreign exchange market operations, partly or wholly,
so as to retain the intent of monetary policy. The monetary authority has to
decide on the extent of off-set as also the means of off-set – market based
or non-market based or a combination of the two.
Financial stability considerations
may require the use of interest rate tool, in conjunction with other prudential
measures. Some times, there could be even a trade-off between raising the short-term
interest rate and tightening of prudential norms, if the risks are perceived
to originate from certain segments of the market. The highly leveraged lending
operations in the backdrop of asset-price bubbles might require adjustments
in the lending margins and risk-based capital requirements. An issue in this
regard is the extent to which these should be considered akin to the erstwhile
selective credit controls.
Globalisation and the Financial
Sector
The international financial
markets are currently dominated by private equity funds like hedge funds, which
are largely operating outside the ‘Know-your-customer’/ ‘Know-your-investor’
(KYC/KYI) norms. Hedge funds have long used arrangements that allow them to
execute trades with several dealers but there is now an increasing tendency
on their part to consolidate the clearing and settlement of their trades at
a single firm, the 'prime broker'. Prime brokerage poses some unique challenges
for the management of counterparty credit and operational risk.
It is commonly observed at the
global level that hedge funds are 'opaque' – that is, information about their
portfolios is typically limited and infrequently provided. The information a
fund provides may also vary considerably depending on whether the recipient
of the information is an investor, a counterparty, a regulatory authority, or
a general market participant. From a policy perspective, transparency to investors
is largely an issue of investor protection, which, in turn, depends on the nature
of investors. The need for counterparties to have adequate information is a
risk-management issue. Concerns about hedge fund opacity and possible liquidity
risk have motivated a range of proposals for regulatory authorities to create
and maintain a database of hedge fund positions.
There are some uncertainties
associated with the settling of trades in newer types of over-the-counter (OTC)
derivatives, particularly credit derivatives. As part of recent financial innovations,
the credit-derivative and structured-credit markets have grown rapidly during
the past few years, allowing dispersion of credit risk by financial players.
Perhaps, it is necessary to evolve mechanisms to ascertain the size and structure
of risk components, the scale and direction of risk transfers, and, therefore,
the distribution of risk within the economy.
In the recent years, the issue
of institutional mechanisms for the prevention and resolution of financial crises
at the multilateral level has assumed importance. On the question whether the
international financial architecture is now in a position to give comfort if
a country were to have a problem, there are four aspects. Firstly, undoubtedly,
the resilience of the world today and the private capital markets in particular,
has improved enormously since 1997. Macro-economic policies and approaches of
international financial institutions as well as the resilience of markets have
improved. Secondly, even though in terms of magnitude, the official/bilateral
flows of funds are miniscule, the very intent of such flows, guided by broader
societal consideration, gives them strength in the face of private flows. Thirdly,
as we are aware, risks are never eliminated but are only mitigated. The existing
international financial architecture is not adequate to prevent or mitigate
the domestic and external effects of financial crisis, particularly in large
economies like China and India. Fourthly, the impact of instability in times
of crisis appears largely to be borne by the home or domestic public sector
rather than the global private sector. Avoiding crisis is ultimately a national
responsibility. In such a milieu, the policy makers are often confronted with
competing positions and need to make choices in the face of daunting dilemmas.
Concluding Remarks
In a recent survey of the world
economy, The Economist (September 16, 2006) predicted that the emerging economies
are set to give the world economy its biggest boost since the industrial revolution.
A greater integration into the global system of production and trade, supported
by buoyant capital flows, is driving a widening wedge between the emerging and
the developed countries in terms of growth rates. Already accounting for more
than half of the world GDP, in purchasing power parity terms, they will raise
their share to two-thirds of the global output in 20 years' time. It took 50
years for Britain and America to double real income in the 19th century when
they were industrialising; China is achieving the same feat in nine years! Over
the next decade, almost a billion new consumers will enter the global marketplace,
providing an enduring stimulus to economic activity across the world.
In all humility, it needs to be
recognised that despite soaring economic growth, real per capita incomes and
therefore, standards of living in the developing countries remain well below
those in the developed countries. As the BRIC report of Goldman and Sachs (2003)
had thoughtfully projected, the average per capita income in America would still
be three or four times higher than in China even in 2040. The IMF has estimated
that if India's relative per capita income rises by under 2 per cent, it will
take more than a 100 years to close half the distance from the developed countries'
per capita income levels. If India's per capita income grows by three per cent
in real terms, it will still take 69 years to close half the gap. More important,
faster growth alone will not automatically eradicate poverty; it depends on
how inclusive that growth is and how the benefits of globalisation are shared.
The future will, in all likelihood,
call for some radical thinking, perhaps new vistas of development in operational
and institutional frameworks of monetary policy. So far, it is claimed, the
emerging economies have made the work of monetary authorities a lot easier than
before by subduing inflation - both commodity prices and wages - and have, in
fact, gifted credibility to monetary policy. Yet, the question that is often
asked is whether the emerging economies have facilitated holding of interest
rates at very low levels by the central banks in the developed countries. In
the face of the consequent build-up of liquidity, elevated asset prices and
soaring consumer indebtedness, is there a dark side to the future? The intellectual
edifice on which monetary policy is founded is rooted in the management of aggregate
demand. But a supply shock arising from globalisation can produce vastly different
growth-inflation outcomes, which monetary policy by itself is not fully equipped
to manage. Indeed, a question that has been asked in this context is whether
price stability is enough as a goal of monetary policy and how sacrosanct it
is when, for instance, central banks have to contend with financial imbalances
even if it means an overshooting of inflation targets.
In a FICCI-IBA Conference, it will
be remiss of me not to address the relationship between the real and the financial
sectors in India in the context of globalisation. Economists have for long recognised
the strong complementarities between the real and the financial sectors. Financial
development contributes to growth in either a supply-leading or a demand-following
sequence; that is, either the financial sector development creates the conditions
for growth or the growth generates demand for the financial services. It is
important to recognise that the financial sector in India is no longer a constraint
on growth and its strength and resilience are acknowledged, though improvements
need to take place. On the other hand, without the real sector development in
terms of the physical infrastructure and improvement in supply elasticities,
the financial sector can even misallocate resources, potentially generate bubbles
and possibly amplify the risks. Hence, public policy may have a crucial role
to play in ensuring a balanced reform in both the real and the financial sectors.
The criticality for the policy makers is not only to ensure that there are no
financial sector constraints on the real sector activity but also to assure
that the financial sector reforms have complementarity with the pace and process
of reform in the real sector in India, along with, no doubt, fiscal empowerment
– as consistently emphasised by the Reserve Bank.
Thank you.
* Valedictory address by Dr.
Y. V. Reddy, Governor, Reserve Bank of India at the FICCI-IBA Conference held
in Mumbai on September 28, 2006.