I. Introduction
I would like to thank the Indian
Banks Association and the Andhra Bank for inviting me to this Conference, which
has become an annual feature of the calendar for bankers and financial sector
professionals.
In view of the theme of the conference,
viz., 'Inclusive Growth – A New Challenge', I thought it would be appropriate
to place financial inclusion within the broad context of economic growth. There
is yet another motivation for choosing the theme. What is the big change that
has taken place in India since 2004? The Indian growth story has been steadily
coming of age and the performance of the Indian economy has attracted worldwide
attention. The Indian growth story is now mentioned in the same breath as that
of China. The economy has been averaging a growth rate of more than 8.0 per
cent during the last three years. The recently released numbers from CSO have
placed the first quarter growth (April to June, 2006) at 8.9 per cent, more
than the overall growth rate of 8.0 per cent reiterated recently by the Reserve
Bank in its Mid-Term Review.
On an earlier occasion in this
forum, in its earlier avatar as BECON in December 2002, I had noted the slow
growth of credit and taken to task that audience of bankers as ‘lazy bankers’
(Mohan, 2002). Fortunately, you seem to have taken this observation seriously
and non-food credit growth from 2002-03 to 2005-06 averaged 28.8 per cent. This
growth shows little sign of abating in the current year when it has recorded
a growth of over 30.0 percent. The growth in broad money since 2002-03 has averaged
16.2 per cent, which during the present year has been of the order of 19.0 per
cent. These trends signal further that India is on a high economic growth path
accompanied by financial deepening.
A new concern has emerged in the
process: that of financial inclusion. Moreover, the Government of India has
also expressed its explicit concern on the issue of overall inclusion in the
development process through its various initiatives such as the Rural Employment
Guarantee Scheme, the Bharat Nirman programme, the Sarva Shiksha Abhiyan,
and the like. A committee on financial inclusion (Chairman: Dr. C. Rangarajan)
has also been constituted by the Government of India in June 2006 to recommend
a strategy to achieve higher financial inclusion in the country.
Likewise, enabling access to a
greater number of the population to the structured and organised financial system
has explicitly been on the agenda of the Reserve Bank since 2004. Unlike several
central banks, which focus solely on inflation, many developed and emerging
economies, including ours, focus also on growth. There is currently a clear
perception that there are a vast number of people, potential entrepreneurs,
small enterprises and others, who are excluded from the financial sector, which
leads to their marginalisation and denial of opportunity for them to grow and
prosper. The Reserve Bank has therefore introduced various new measures to encourage
the expansion of financial coverage in the country. Not only is financial inclusion
essential because of its implications for the welfare of citizens but it needs
to be stressed that it has to be an explicit strategy for fostering faster economic
growth in a more inclusive fashion. It is in this context that I thought it
would be appropriate to place the strategy of financial inclusion in the wider
context of economic growth and financial deepening.
My ideas on this topic are organised
along the following lines. To begin with, I shall dwell upon the process of
growth and financial deepening in India. This will be followed by definitional
aspects and some evidence from the experience of other countries, with regard
to financial inclusion. Thereafter, the focus would be on interlinking the relevance
of financial inclusion in our economy, which has entered a high growth orbit,
with the rural economy. The penultimate section focuses on the role being played
by the Reserve Bank in this regard. My concluding thoughts would be in the nature
of issues that have a bearing on financial inclusion.
II. Economic Growth
The growth trend of the Indian
economy over the last few years appears to indicate the beginning of a new phase
of higher growth. From an average growth rate of around 6.0 per cent for a quarter
of a century, the growth rate has accelerated to 8.1 per cent over the last
few years. Along with declining population growth, this suggests high growth
in per capita income in excess of 6 per cent in recent years, and perhaps approaching
7 per cent, which would lead to doubling of per capita income every ten years.
Most importantly, the current growth process is not a flash in the pan and is
exhibiting signs of sustainability along with financial stability, notwithstanding
the pressures from unforeseen external shocks.
On the savings front, the increasing
trend in gross domestic saving as a proportion of GDP witnessed since the early
2000s has also continued unabated. The gross domestic savings rate has improved
from 23.6 per cent of GDP in 2001-02 to 29.1 per cent in 2004-05, led by a turnaround
of 4.2 per cent in public saving, from a dis-saving of 2.2 per cent of GDP in
2001-02 to a saving of 2.0 per cent in 2004-05, mainly reflecting the fiscal
consolidation process. Household savings continue to grow and increased corporate
savings reflect their healthy growth in profitability. The encouraging sign
of a pick up in investment has also strengthened unhindered. Along with the
improvements in savings and investment rates, there has also been a marked lowering
of inflation from 7.8 per cent in the 1990s to 4.7 per cent in recent years.
With such healthy increases in savings and investment rates financial intermediation
is assuming increasing importance (Annex Table 1).
Alongside these improvements
there has also been a resurgence of manufacturing activity. There had been noted
stagnation in manufacturing during 1997-2003. Overall industrial recovery set
in during 2002-03 and this has been sustained since then on the back of healthy
growth in domestic demand, along with that of exports supported by high world
economic growth, increasing capacity utilisation, augmentation of capacity,
and positive business and consumer confidence. But there is little evidence
of significant growth in manufacturing employment leading to emerging doubts
in the inclusive nature of this growth.
The current high industrial growth
is reflected in the acceleration in growth of bank credit in recent years. Average
growth in non-food credit between 1970 and 2000 had been 16.9 per cent, which
had been seen as evidence of finance led industrialisation by some (Bell, 2001).
In the period of industrial slowdown, 1998 to 2002, annual growth in non-food
credit had also slowed to 14.5 per cent - leading to my comment on "lazy
banking". In recent years, during 2002-03 to 2005-06, this growth has accelerated
significantly to 28.8 per cent, possibly signalling financial deepening of the
system.
Much of this recent expansion in
non-food credit has been fuelled by an increase in retail credit. During the
same period, 2002-03 to 2005-06 annual growth in retail credit was 46 per cent:
its share in overall bank credit consequently increased from 6.4 per cent in
1990-91 to 25.5 per cent in 2005-2006. Earlier, most of bank credit had gone
to the industrial corporate sector. Hence this shift to retail credit can also
be seen as a move toward financial deepening, and one that itself fuels industrial
and overall economic growth through expansion of greater demand for consumer
goods.
The high industrial growth is also
corroborated by the record of very healthy performance of the corporate sector,
which has recorded unusually high profit growth over the past three years: over
40 per cent growth in profit after tax for 11 successive quarters from Q3
2002-03 to Q1 2005-06. Although this growth has slowed somewhat in
the last four quarters, it continues to be high, between 25 and 35 per cent.
Corporate sector savings have grown from 4.4 per cent of GDP in 1999-2002 to
5.3 per cent in 2004-05. Hence, the probability of continued high corporate
growth in terms of output is made more likely by the availability of high retained
earnings, burgeoning valuations, and continued productivity growth.
All these developments point to
overall financial deepening but, once again, one has to ask the question whether
such performance extends to small and medium enterprises also and, whether there
has also been extension of financial intermediation for such enterprises, raising
issues of financial inclusion.
The high industrial and credit
growth of recent years has also been supported by high trade growth in both
merchandise goods and services. Merchandise exports have grown from 5.8 per
cent of GDP in 1990-91 to about 13.1 per cent in 2005-06; and gross invisible
receipts have grown from 2.4 per cent to 11.5 per cent of GDP. If we take gross
trade, the sum of both current account receipts and payments, as a proportion
of GDP as an index of the openness of the economy, this has increased from 19.2
per cent in 1990-91 to 49.5 per cent in 2005-06. Since all such receipts and
payments pass through the banking system, this increasing openness of the economy
has also added to financial deepening, while aiding the acceleration in economic
growth (Annex Table 2).
The high credit growth witnessed
in recent years has, however, not been matched by adequate deposit growth. The
growth in deposits since 2001-02 has been far lower than that required to support
overall credit expansion (Graph 1). Banks have been financing much of the incremental
credit expansion by unwinding their surplus investments in government securities.
What deposit growth that has been observed is, moreover, concentrated in the
larger cities: presumably it has been helped by the high corporate profitability
leading to high corporate cash balances. The trend therefore indicates that
while banks may have been proactive in credit deployment, their focus on deposit
mobilisation may have been less than adequate. The indication that deposit growth
in non metro areas has been slow could also mean that financial inclusion may
have suffered. We also need to understand that if deposit growth does not match
credit growth, excess demand would inevitably lead to increases in real interest
rates leading to further possibility of financial exclusion.
Graph 1: Growth in Aggregate Deposits
and Credit
Overall, it is clear from the recent
performance of the economy and that of the financial sector that a good deal
of financial sector growth has accompanied the recent acceleration of economic
growth. We also observe that a good part of credit growth has gone towards financing
consumption and housing which suggests widening of the financial system. But
deposit growth has been slow, particularly outside metro areas, leading to questions
concerning financial deepening and inclusion.
III. Financial Deepening
There is a general consensus among
economists that financial development spurs economic growth. Theoretically,
financial development creates enabling conditions for growth through either
a supply-leading (financial development spurs growth) or a demand-following
(growth generates demand for financial products) channel. A large body of empirical
research supports the view that development of the financial system contributes
to economic growth (Rajan and Zingales, 2003). Empirical evidence consistently
emphasises the nexus between finance and growth, though the issue of direction
of causality is more difficult to determine. At the cross-country level, evidence
indicates that various measures of financial development (including assets of
the financial intermediaries, liquid liabilities of financial institutions,
domestic credit to private sector, stock and bond market capitalisation) are
robustly and positively related to economic growth (King and Levine, 1993; Levine
and Zervos, 1998). Other studies establish a positive relationship between financial
development and growth at the industry level (Rajan and Zingales, 1998). Even
the recent endogenous growth literature, building on 'learning by doing' processes,
assigns a special role to finance (Aghion and Hewitt, 1998 and 2005).
A developed financial system broadens
access to funds; conversely, in an underdeveloped financial system, access to
funds is limited and people are constrained by the availability of their own
funds and have to resort to high cost informal sources such as money lenders.
Lower the availability of funds and higher their cost, fewer would be the economic
activities that can be financed and hence lower the resulting economic growth.
Some of the recent concerns on
financial inclusion have emanated from the results of the All-India Debt and
Investment Survey (AIDIS), 2002. Over a period of 40 years, the share of non-institutional
sources of credit in sources of credit for cultivator households had declined
sharply from about 93 per cent in 1951 to about 30 per cent in 1991, with the
share of money lenders having declined from 69.7 per cent to 17.5 per cent.
In 2002, the AIDIS revealed, however, that the share of money lenders had again
increased to 27 per cent, while that of non-institutional sources overall rose
to 39 per cent (Table 1). In other words, notwithstanding the outreach of banking,
the formal credit system has not been able to adequately penetrate the informal
financial markets; rather it seems to have shrunk in some respects in recent
years.
Coincidentally, it is also true
that the rate of agricultural growth during the last decade has slowed down
and it is particularly striking in respect of foodgrains production. Since the
green revolution, banks have been mainly focused on financing crop loans connected
largely with food grains. There is, therefore, reason to believe that financial
exclusion may actually have increased in the rural areas over the last 10-15
years.
Table 1: Relative Share of Borrowing
of Cultivator Households#
(per cent)
Sources of Credit
|
1951
|
1961
|
1971
|
1981
|
1991
|
2002$
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
7
|
Non-institutional
|
92.7
|
81.3
|
68.3
|
36.8
|
30.6
|
38.9
|
of which:
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Money lenders
|
69.7
|
49.2
|
36.1
|
16.1
|
17.5
|
26.8
|
Institutional
|
7.3
|
18.7
|
31.7
|
63.2
|
66.3
|
61.1
|
of which:
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Co-operative societies,
etc.
|
3.3
|
2.6
|
22.0
|
29.8
|
30.0
|
30.2
|
Commercial banks
|
0.9
|
0.6
|
2.4
|
28.8
|
35.2
|
26.3
|
Unspecified
|
-
|
-
|
-
|
-
|
3.1
|
-
|
Total
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
# : Borrowing refers to outstanding
cash dues.
$ : AIDIS, NSSO, 59th Round, 2003.
Source: All India Debt and Investment Surveys.
One of the key features of financial
deepening is that it accelerates economic growth through the expansion of access
to those who do not have adequate finance themselves. Typically, in an underdeveloped
financial system, it is the incumbents who have better access to financial services
through relationship banking. Moreover, incumbents also finance their growth
through internal resource generation. Thus, in an underdeveloped financial system,
growth is constrained to the expansion potential of incumbents. In mature financial
systems on the other hand, financial institutions develop appraisal techniques,
and information gathering and sharing mechanisms, which then enable banks to
even finance those activities or firms that are at the margin, thereby leading
to their growth-inducing productive activities in addition to the incumbents.
It is this availability of external finance to budding entrepreneurs and small
firms that enables new entry, while also providing competition to incumbents
and consequently encouraging entrepreneurship and productivity.
What has been the case in India?
As I mentioned earlier, the incredible corporate profit growth, in excess of
40 per cent for almost three years consecutively, would suggest that there should
have been massive new entry to whittle down profitability to more moderate levels.
This, however, does not seem to be the case on the ground yet with corporate
profitability still growing at an annual rate of around 35 per cent during April-June
2006. That entry of new firms has possibly been limited is also indicated by
the fact that among the different categories of credit growth, lending to SMEs
has been the lowest, though there are some signs of higher growth in recent
months.
There are, however, other signs
of financial deepening (Mohan, 2004). According to one indicator of financial
deepening, the ratio of bank assets to GDP, financial depth in India was among
the lowest in the world (Barth, Caprio and Levine, 2001). Comparable cross-country
data indicated that in 2001, this ratio, at 48 per cent for India, was lower
than those prevalent in Asian economies such as Indonesia (101 per cent), Korea
(98 per cent), Philippines (91 per cent), Malaysia (166 per cent) and much lower
than developed economies, such as UK (311 per cent), France (147 per cent) and
Germany (313 per cent). In India, while the ratio of bank assets to GDP has
increased significantly to a shade over 80 per cent in 2005-06 – obviously a
consequence of the high credit growth in recent years - it is still lower than
other emerging countries. In absolute terms, the annual expansion in non-food
credit has increased from Rs.64,302 crore in 2001-02 to Rs.3,54,193 crore in
2005-06, while retail credit has increased from around Rs.16,000 crore to Rs.1,09,129
crore. So, it needs to be recognised that financial deepening has been taking
place on an accelerated pace on a macro basis in recent years, that banking
productivity has improved significantly, and that bankers have clearly been
very busy.
Whereas banks have clearly taken
to heart my remarks on "lazy banking" on the asset creation side,
they have not matched this creditable performance on the liability side. Dare
I repeat the same expression!
An important question that arises
logically is: has commensurate financial deepening been taking place at the
micro-level? There is sufficient anecdotal evidence to suggest that the poor
or less well-off people find it difficult to open a bank account in any area
– rural, urban or semi-urban. Thus, not only is the common individual deprived
of access to banks for generating savings or availing credit, but so is the
financial system of resources commensurate with the burgeoning growth of incomes
all over the country. It is this very feature that the process of financial
inclusion seeks to address. This is an aspect to which I turn next.
IV. Financial Inclusion
I begin by looking at exactly the
opposite of financial inclusion, i.e., financial exclusion. Broadly defined,
financial exclusion signifies the lack of access by certain segments of the
society to appropriate, low-cost, fair and safe financial products and services
from mainstream providers. Financial exclusion is thus a key policy concern,
because the options for operating a household budget, or a micro/small enterprise,
without mainstream financial services can often be expensive. This process becomes
self-reinforcing and can often be an important factor in social exclusion, especially
for communities with limited access to financial products, particularly in rural
areas.
Two major factors have often been
cited as the consequences of financial exclusion. First, it complicates day-to-day
cash flow management - being financially excluded means households, and micro
and small enterprises deal entirely in cash and are susceptible to irregular
cash flows. Second, lack of financial planning and security in the absence of
access to bank accounts and other saving opportunities for people in the unorganised
sector limit their options for providing for themselves for their old age. From
the macroeconomic standpoint, being without formal savings can be problematic
in two respects. First, people who save by informal means rarely benefit from
the interest rate and tax advantages that people using formal methods of savings
enjoy. Second, informal saving channels are much less secure than formal saving
facilities. Those who can afford it least suffer the highest risk. The resultant
lack of savings and saving avenues means recourse to non-formal lenders, like
money lenders. This, in turn, could lead to two adverse consequences – a) exposure
to higher interest rates charged by formal lenders; and b) the inability of
customers to service the loans or to repay them. As loans from non-formal lenders
are often secured against the borrower’s property, this raises the problem of
inter-linkage between two apparently separate markets. Judged in this specific
context, financial exclusion is a serious concern among low-income households,
mainly located in rural areas.
Once access to financial institutions
improves, inclusion affords several benefits to the consumer, regulator and
the economy alike. Establishment of an account relationship can pave the way
for the customer to avail the benefits of a variety of financial products, which
are not only standardised, but are also provided by institutions that are regulated
and supervised by credible regulators, and are hence safer. The bank accounts
can also be used for multiple purposes, such as, making small value remittances
at low cost and making purchases on credit. Furthermore, the regulator benefits,
as the audit trail is available and transactions are conducted transparently
in a medium that can be monitored. The economy benefits, as greater financial
resources become transparently available for efficient intermediation and allocation,
for uses that have the highest returns. In other words, the single gateway of
a banking account can be used for several purposes and represents a beneficial
situation for all the economic units in the country.
In addition, I would like to flag
an important perspective. Improvements in rural infrastructure in terms of availability
of electricity, improvement in connectivity through provision of rural roads
and telecommunications, and construction of warehouses, are expected to lead
to better overall supply chain management, enhance productivity of physical
resources in the rural areas and greater addition in agriculture. These developments
would lead to much greater demand for banking activity in rural areas. The two-fold
implications of these developments for the banking sector are apparent. First,
with higher financing needs of such new activities vis-a-vis traditional
ones, the overall financing intensity of agriculture is likely to experience
a manifold rise. Second, along with growth in rural infrastructure, there is
also likely to be an increase in rural non-farm activities, such as repair activities,
education, housing, restaurants and medical services. These activities, both
traditional and emerging ventures, would be available for financing by the banking
sector.
Thus, as the economy begins to
grow rapidly, the rate of financial intermediation is expected to increase further.
In other words, the banking system will be expected to increasingly provide
larger quantum of funds to existing and emerging enterprises. And without adequate
deposit growth, however, credit expansion might not be sustainable over the
medium-term, without putting immense pressure on real interest rates and impacting
the overall stability of the financial system.
International Experience
Typically, countries with low levels
of income inequality tend to have lower levels of financial exclusion, while
high levels of exclusion are associated with the least equal ones. In Sweden,
for example, lower than two per cent of adults did not have an account in 2000
and in Germany, the figure was around three per cent (Kempson, 2006). In comparison,
less than four per cent of adults in Canada and five per cent in Belgium, lacked
a bank account (Buckland et al, 2005). Countries with high levels of inequality
record higher levels of banking exclusion. To illustrate, in Portugal, about
17 per cent of the adult population had no account of any kind in 2000 (Kempson,
2006).
The policy responses to such exclusion
have been varied (Box 1). In Sweden, for example, banks cannot refuse to open
a saving or deposit account under Section 2 of the Banking Business Act of 1987;
in France, Article 58 of the Banking Act, 1984 recognised the principle of the
right to a bank account; in the US, federal government introduced the Community
Reinvestment Act in 1997, partly in response to concerns about bank branch closures
in low-income neighbourhoods. Under this legislation, federal bank regulatory
agencies rate banks on their efforts to serve low-income communities. These
early legislations were designed to ensure access to a deposit account but did
not spell out the nature of banking services that should be on offer. Refinements
in this area have actually taken place in the latter half of the 1990s, resulting
partly from a wider concern regarding social exclusion (Caskey et al, 2006,
Kempson et al, 2000). It may, thus, be noted that financial inclusion is a concern
even in developed countries and legislative or regulatory measure to achieve
it are a common feature.
Box 1: Policy Response to Financial
Exclusion – Country Experiences
Two major kinds of policy responses
have been implemented by central banks in response to financial exclusion: codes
of practice and specific legislation. First, countries such as France and Belgium
have undertaken initiatives to committing banks to open an affordable account
with bare minimum facilities. Termed 'call deposit account' in Belgium, it offers
three basic types of transactions: money transfers, deposits and withdrawals,
and bank statements. However, individual banks may opt to offer other services
if they wish. In Germany, a voluntary code was introduced by the German Bankers
Association in 1996. This makes provision for an 'everyman' current account,
offering basic banking transactions, without an overdraft facility. Likewise,
access to basic banking in the United Kingdom and Australia has been achieved
through voluntary arrangements with banks and has not involved formal charters.
In the United Kingdom, for instance, a Banking Code has been drafted, which
requires banks to inform customers about their basic bank account and its suitability
for their needs. A Financial Inclusion Taskforce, instituted in April 2005,
monitors access to basic banking services.
Several countries have also introduced
specific legislation that gives both, a universal right to a bank account and,
spells out the precise nature of banking services to be provided. In France,
the law on exclusion of July 1998 reiterated the right to an account first set
out in the 1984 law and has since then simplified the process of exercising
the right to an account. In Belgium, a banking bill was enacted which has been
implemented since October 2003. In addition to setting out the minimum standards
for basic bank accounts, it also specifies the ceiling on charges and a minimum
number of free face-to-face transactions. In many ways, the policy response
in Canada combines the best of developments in other countries. The relevant
legislation, enacted in June 2001, requires all banks to provide accounts without
minimum opening balances to all Canadians, regardless of employment or credit
history, with minimum identification requirements. A Financial Consumer Agency
of Canada has been established to monitor whether financial institutions adhere
to their public commitments.
Sources:
Kempson, E. (2006). Policy Level
Response to Financial Exclusion in Developed Economies: Lessons for Developing
Countries, paper presented at the conference, Access to Finance: Building Inclusive
Financial Systems, World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Connolly, C., and K.Hajaj (2001).
Financial Services and Social Exclusion, Financial Services Consumer Policy
Center, University of New South Wales.
HM Treasury (1999). Access to Financial services. London: HM Treasury.
Present Situation in India
I would like to share with you
certain data that highlight my concern on financial exclusion. The share of
deposits and credit in rural and semi-urban areas is on the decline. In contrast,
the share in metropolitan areas is rising. The share of credit is lower than
that of deposits in all regions except metropolitan, implying that resources
get intermediated into metropolitan areas (Table 2). This in itself may not
necessarily be undesirable or unexpected if resources are being intermediated
to their best uses. However, they do provide some indication for concern and
for the need for more investigation.
Table 2: Spatial Distribution of
Banking Services
(Per cent)
|
Offices
|
|
Deposits
|
|
Credit
|
1969
|
1996
|
2005
|
1969
|
1996
|
2005
|
1969
|
1996
|
2005
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
7
|
8
|
9
|
10
|
Rural
|
22.2
|
51.2
|
45.7
|
6.4
|
14.4
|
12.2
|
3.3
|
11.4
|
9.5
|
Semi-urban
|
40.4
|
21.3
|
22.3
|
21.8
|
19.5
|
16.9
|
13.1
|
13.1
|
11.3
|
Urban
|
19.2
|
15.2
|
17.6
|
26.5
|
22.4
|
21.5
|
21.8
|
17.7
|
16.4
|
Metropolitan
|
18.2
|
12.3
|
14.4
|
45.3
|
43.7
|
49.4
|
61.8
|
57.8
|
62.7
|
Total
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
Source: Reserve Bank of
India
The total number of saving accounts,
considered to be a better indicator of banking penetration than other deposit
accounts, as per cent of number of households, was 137 in rural areas and 244
in the urban areas on the eve of reforms in 1991. By 2005, despite the reforms,
the differential continues to be similar. In the case of credit accounts, the
situation has deteriorated for rural households while showing significant improvement
in the urban areas (Table 3), corroborating the very significant increase in
retail credit.
Table 3: Number of Deposit and Credit
Accounts in Scheduled Commercial Banks
(Per cent of Number of Households)
|
|
1981
|
1991
|
1996
|
2001
|
2004
|
2005
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
7
|
8
|
Deposit Accounts
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Current Accounts
|
Rural
|
3.6
|
5.5
|
4.7
|
4.9
|
4.4
|
4.6
|
|
Urban
|
15.0
|
23.4
|
24.1
|
19.2
|
17.5
|
18.3
|
Savings Accounts
|
Rural
|
59.6
|
137.0
|
129.8
|
123.3
|
126.8
|
131.5
|
|
Urban
|
135.5
|
243.7
|
249.7
|
197.4
|
206.5
|
213.1
|
Current and Saving Accounts
|
Rural
|
63.2
|
142.6
|
134.5
|
128.2
|
131.1
|
136.1
|
|
Urban
|
150.5
|
267.2
|
273.7
|
216.6
|
224.0
|
231.4
|
Term Deposits Accounts
|
Rural
|
22.9
|
41.8
|
45.5
|
52.0
|
48.3
|
45.7
|
|
Urban
|
74.6
|
96.9
|
105.0
|
105.6
|
113.4
|
104.0
|
Total Deposits Accounts
|
Rural
|
86.1
|
184.4
|
180.0
|
180.1
|
179.4
|
181.8
|
|
Urban
|
225.1
|
364.1
|
378.7
|
322.2
|
337.4
|
335.4
|
Credit Accounts
|
Rural
|
18.0
|
44.3
|
36.0
|
26.5
|
28.7
|
32.2
|
|
Urban
|
15.1
|
29.9
|
27.1
|
28.4
|
42.5
|
50.2
|
Notes:
1. The census population groups
are 'rural' and 'urban', whereas the population groups used in BSR data are
'rural', 'semi-urban', 'urban' and 'metropolitan'. There is no unique relationship
between the two. For comparison purpose and simplicity, 'Rural' and 'Semi-Urban'
are taken as 'rural', and 'urban' and 'metropolitan' are combined as 'urban'.
2. For three new formed States,
number of households, in 1991 have been estimated based on 2001 data. Population
is as per 1981, 1991 and 2001 census. For 1996, 2004 and 2005 projected population
has been used, and rural and urban proportion of past census is applied.
Sources: 1.Reserve Bank
of India. 2. Census, 2001.
Total deposits, as per cent of
GDP, increased from 32.2 in 1991 to 47.1 in 2005 in rural areas and from 37.3
to 61.2 in urban areas. Similarly, credit extended, as per cent of GDP, increased
from 17.3 to 22.3 in rural and from 24.8 to 45.0 in urban areas (Table 4). In
terms of banking penetration, the number of deposit and credit accounts of scheduled
commercial banks as per cent of adult population are significantly lower in
the rural areas as compared with the urban areas (Table 5).
Table 4: Deposits and Credit Amounts
in Scheduled Commercial Banks
(per cent of GDP)
|
|
1981
|
1991
|
1996
|
2001
|
2005
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
7
|
Deposit Accounts
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1. Current Accounts
|
Rural
|
2.6
|
2.7
|
2.4
|
2.9
|
3.3
|
|
Urban
|
5.5
|
7.1
|
7.0
|
7.0
|
8.7
|
2. Savings Accounts
|
Rural
|
9.8
|
11.2
|
10.5
|
13.6
|
18.6
|
|
Urban
|
7.2
|
9.0
|
7.9
|
9.8
|
13.3
|
3. Current and Saving Accounts
|
Rural
|
12.4
|
13.9
|
12.8
|
16.4
|
21.9
|
(1 + 2)
|
Urban
|
12.7
|
16.1
|
14.9
|
16.8
|
22.0
|
4. Term Deposits Accounts
|
Rural
|
13.8
|
18.3
|
20.5
|
27.9
|
25.2
|
|
Urban
|
16.6
|
21.2
|
22.4
|
29.2
|
39.1
|
5. Total Deposits Accounts
|
Rural
|
26.3
|
32.2
|
33.3
|
44.4
|
47.1
|
(3 + 4)
|
Urban
|
29.3
|
37.3
|
37.3
|
46.0
|
61.2
|
6. Credit Accounts
|
Rural
|
13.0
|
17.3
|
14.4
|
15.8
|
22.3
|
|
Urban
|
20.0
|
24.8
|
25.5
|
31.1
|
45.0
|
Notes:
1. GDP at Market Prices (current
prices) is used. The rural and urban figures of GDP are based on ratio of monthly
per capita Total Consumer Expenditure, NSSO.
2. Same as in Table 3.
Source: Same as in Table 3.
Table 5: Number of Deposit and Credit
Accounts in Scheduled Commercial Banks
(per cent of Adult Population, Age
15+)
|
|
1981
|
1991
|
1996
|
2001
|
2005
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
7
|
Deposit Accounts
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Current Accounts
|
Rural
|
1.0
|
1.6
|
1.4
|
1.4
|
1.4
|
|
Urban
|
4.5
|
6.6
|
6.8
|
5.4
|
5.2
|
Savings Accounts
|
Rural
|
16.1
|
39.6
|
37.6
|
36.5
|
39.0
|
|
Urban
|
40.3
|
69.2
|
70.9
|
55.8
|
60.2
|
Current and Saving Accounts
|
Rural
|
17.1
|
41.3
|
38.9
|
38.0
|
40.3
|
|
Urban
|
44.8
|
75.8
|
77.7
|
61.2
|
65.4
|
Term Deposits Accounts
|
Rural
|
6.2
|
12.1
|
13.2
|
15.4
|
13.6
|
|
Urban
|
22.2
|
27.5
|
29.8
|
29.8
|
29.4
|
Total Deposits Accounts
|
Rural
|
23.3
|
53.4
|
52.1
|
53.4
|
53.9
|
|
Urban
|
67.0
|
103.4
|
107.5
|
91.0
|
94.7
|
Credit Accounts
|
Rural
|
4.9
|
7.7
|
8.0
|
7.9
|
9.5
|
|
Urban
|
4.5
|
12.8
|
10.4
|
8.0
|
14.2
|
Note: Same as in Table 3.
Source: Same as in Table 3.
Even in terms of financial widening,
the scope for improvement remains. In terms of regional dis-aggregation since
1991, population per bank office has increased in rural areas from 13,462 in
1991 to 16,650 in 2005 and, as expected, declined in the urban areas from 14,484
to 13,619 over the period. Three regions, North-Eastern, East and Central have
higher population per office than the all-India average and it has increased
significantly in the rural areas in 2005 over 1991 (Table 6). Consequently,
compared to an all-India average of 29.9 savings accounts per 100 persons in
1991, virtually all of the states in the Eastern and North-Eastern regions and
several pockets in the Central region had figures lower than this average. In
the rural areas, Northern and Southern region are above the all-India average
while in the urban areas, Northern and Western region dominate. In terms of
number of credit accounts per 100 persons, the Southern States, both in rural
and urban areas perform above the all-India average.
Table 6: Regional Level Indicators
of Scheduled Commercial Banks
|
1991
|
2005
|
|
1991
|
2005
|
|
1991
|
2005
|
Total
|
Rural
|
Urban
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
7
|
|
Population per Office
|
Northern
|
11,002
|
12,257
|
10,771
|
13,043
|
11,571
|
10,941
|
North-East
|
16,870
|
26,227
|
16,335
|
22,158
|
21,169
|
20,318
|
Eastern
|
16,441
|
19,913
|
16,402
|
21,208
|
16,614
|
15,759
|
Central
|
15,786
|
19,518
|
15,153
|
20,264
|
18,745
|
17,297
|
Western
|
12,771
|
14,618
|
12,579
|
15,526
|
13,108
|
13,472
|
Southern
|
11,932
|
12,328
|
11,276
|
12,372
|
13,811
|
12,243
|
All-India
|
13,711
|
15,680
|
13,462
|
16,650
|
14,484
|
13,619
|
Deposits: Number of Savings
Accounts per 100 persons
|
Northern
|
40.0
|
38.3
|
30.1
|
29.7
|
62.6
|
55.4
|
North-East
|
17.8
|
17.6
|
16.1
|
16.4
|
28.4
|
24.2
|
Eastern
|
21.8
|
20.5
|
17.7
|
16.9
|
40.0
|
36.1
|
Central
|
23.8
|
24.5
|
21.0
|
22.1
|
34.7
|
32.9
|
Western
|
35.5
|
32.5
|
24.7
|
23.8
|
53.8
|
45.2
|
Southern
|
37.0
|
37.6
|
34.6
|
35.5
|
42.7
|
41.8
|
All-India
|
29.9
|
29.2
|
24.5
|
24.4
|
45.6
|
41.6
|
Credit: Number of Credit Accounts
per 100 persons
|
Northern
|
6.4
|
5.7
|
6.6
|
5.1
|
5.9
|
6.7
|
North-East
|
4.4
|
3.3
|
4.4
|
3.2
|
4.4
|
3.9
|
Eastern
|
6.6
|
4.2
|
7.2
|
4.2
|
4.3
|
4.3
|
Central
|
5.5
|
4.3
|
5.8
|
4.2
|
4.4
|
4.5
|
Western
|
5.7
|
7.5
|
6.2
|
4.2
|
4.8
|
12.2
|
Southern
|
11.8
|
14.2
|
13.6
|
12.7
|
7.6
|
17.4
|
All-India
|
7.3
|
7.0
|
7.9
|
6.0
|
5.5
|
9.8
|
Notes: Same as in Tables
3 and 4.
Source: Same as in Table 3.
Thus, the apparent implication
emerging from the above data reveals that the rural areas are not being served
adequately by banks. This suggests that banks need to make efforts to mobilise
resources from the rural sector, where as discussed earlier, scope for increase
in business is emerging. Further, if the banks are to balance their overall
deposit mobilisation and credit extension, as generally robust banking practice
would imply, then they would need to devise imaginative ways to mop up the resources,
particularly in rural areas.
V. Rural Economy- Growth, Production
Patterns and Credit Extension
It is instructive to examine the
rural economy in a bit more detail. Although the share of agriculture in overall
GDP has declined from around 35.8 per cent in 1980-81 to less than 19.9 per
cent at present, the fall in the proportion of population dependent on the sector
has been limited (Table 7). In other words, a majority of the workforce is still
dependent on agriculture, while the GDP growth due to agriculture is marginally
above the rate of growth of the population, in contrast to a strong growth rate
in the non-agriculture sector.
Table 7: Components of Gross Domestic
Products*
(Per cent)
Year/Sector
|
Agriculture
and Allied
|
Of which:
Agriculture
|
Industry
|
Services
|
Total
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
1970-71 to 1979-80
|
42.8
|
37.7
|
16.9
|
40.3
|
100.0
|
1980-81 to 1989-90
|
36.4
|
33.1
|
19.5
|
44.0
|
100.0
|
1990-91 to 1999-2000
|
29.1
|
26.7
|
21.9
|
49.0
|
100.0
|
2000-01 to 2005-06
|
21.9
|
20.8
|
21.4
|
56.7
|
100.0
|
*: Annual averages.
Source: National Account Statistics.
The slowdown in agriculture in
recent years is characterised by the stagnation in domestic production in case
of commodities like wheat, sugar and pulses. There has been a marked deceleration
in the share of cereals in total production (agriculture and allied) from 31.7
per cent in 1960-61 to 24.1 per cent in 2004-05 (Table 8). On the other hand,
the share of other segments such as livestock and fishing, and non-cereals are
recording a significant increase. There has been a silent revolution over the
last 20 years, unnoticed by researchers and policy makers alike. The value of
output of non cereal vegetarian food and of non-vegetarian food (livestock and
fishing) is each higher than that of cereals. In principle, these activities
should be more credit intensive. It is, therefore, of utmost importance that
our image of what is agriculture, changes from that of simple rice and wheat
to a more complex structure, so that policy makers can assign due importance
to the sector and respond accordingly (Mohan, 2006).
Table 8: Changing Pattern of Agricultural
Production
Year
|
Cereals
and
pulses
|
Non-cereals
food
|
Cash
crops
|
Livestock
and fishing
|
Forestry
and
logging
|
Ag. and allied
(Rs. crore)
|
Sectoral shares: as per cent
of agriculture and allied
|
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
7
|
1960-61
|
31.7
|
33.6
|
4.9
|
20.3
|
9.5
|
1,32,292
|
1970-71
|
31.4
|
34.9
|
4.8
|
20.1
|
8.8
|
1,69,066
|
1980-81
|
30.3
|
36.2
|
4.4
|
23.4
|
5.7
|
2,26,719
|
1990-91
|
28.6
|
36.4
|
4.5
|
26.2
|
4.3
|
3,10,165
|
2000-01
|
25.4
|
37.6
|
3.9
|
28.0
|
3.9
|
5,68,990
|
2004-05
|
24.1
|
n.a
|
n.a
|
29.2
|
3.8
|
6,22,183
|
Source: National Accounts
Statistics.
Apart from non-cereal food production,
service and manufacturing activities have also been growing faster in rural
areas. There are new supply chain activities: sorting, grading, storage, cold
storage, transportation, food processing, and the like. All are in the cash
economy and potentially in need of credit. In fact, it is estimated that agriculture
now accounts for less than half of rural GDP: an epochal change that took place
some time in the late 1990s. So "rural" can no longer be equated with
agriculture. The consequence is that rural per capita income has probably been
growing at a rate similar to that of urban per capital income.
There is also good evidence (NCAER)
of the dramatic changes in consumption and income growth and distribution patterns
in the rural economy. As classified consistently by NCAER, keeping real income
cut offs constant, the proportion of households classified as "low income"
in rural areas has fallen from about two thirds in the early 1990s to only about
a quarter now. At the same time, those classified as middle income households
have risen from a third to almost 70 per cent now (NCAER, 2003). Hence, there
should have been a surge in financial savings in rural areas: but we do not
see evidence of this in the number or proportion of households that have bank
accounts.
The banking system needs to adjust
to the realities in the rural sector. There is evidence they are finding it
difficult. As the ratio of agricultural GDP to total GDP declines, agricultural
credit to total GDP would also decline. However, this is not observed from the
data (Table 9). In recent years a concern over the falling share of agricultural
credit as a proportion of total credit has been expressed. The data reveal that
agriculture credit as a ratio of total credit has also been rising in the recent
years but is still below the level of 1970s.
Table 9: Ratio of Direct Agricultural
Credit to Agricultural GDP,
Total GDP and total Credit
Year
|
Ag. Credit/Ag. GDP
|
Ag. Credit/total GDP
|
Ag. Credit/CS
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
1970s
|
5.4
|
2.1
|
10.8
|
1980s
|
8.3
|
2.6
|
8.5
|
1990s
|
7.4
|
2.0
|
6.4
|
1999-2000
|
10.0
|
2.6
|
8.1
|
2000-01
|
11.3
|
2.8
|
7.9
|
2001-02
|
14.0
|
3.0
|
8.2
|
2002-03
|
16.6
|
3.1
|
7.7
|
2003-04
|
18.0
|
3.4
|
8.6
|
2004-05
|
25.0
|
4.4
|
9.8
|
2005-06
|
25.9
|
4.9
|
9.3
|
Notes:
1. Agricultural credit; direct
credit for agricultural and allied activities extended by co-operatives, commercial
banks and regional rural banks.
2. Total GDP and Agricultural GDP are at factor cost and at current prices.
3. CS - other banks’ credit to commercial sector (outstanding) proxy for total
credit.
Source: RBI and NABARD.
The existing agricultural credit
system, as indicated earlier, is geared to the needs of food grain production.
It is gratifying to note that agriculture credit has not fallen as a proportion
of agricultural GDP despite the share of food grain production declining as
a proportion of total agricultural production. In fact, according to available
data, agricultural credit has been rising in recent years as a share of both
the value of inputs and the value of outputs (Table 10).
Moreover, long-term credit as a
share of private investment has also been rising in the 1990s (Table 11). The
balance of evidence also suggests that non-performing loans (NPLs) in agriculture
are not higher than in other sectors, more specifically those in small-scale
industries (SSIs). To illustrate, NPLs in agriculture - both for public as well
as private banks – were lower than those in the SSIs as at end-March 2005 (Mohan,
2006).
Table 10: Gross Value of Output,
Value of Input and Short-Term Credit
(Rs. crore at current prices)
Year
|
Gross value of output
|
Value of input
|
Short-term credit
|
Short-term credit as percentage
of
|
Value of output
|
Value of input
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
1993-94
|
2,71,839
|
55,401
|
5,424
|
2.0
|
9.8
|
1998-99
|
4,88,731
|
93,416
|
10,821
|
2.2
|
11.6
|
1999-2000
|
5,26,658
|
1,21,878
|
12,610
|
2.4
|
10.3
|
2000-01
|
5,29,800
|
1,26,773
|
15,442
|
2.9
|
12.2
|
2001-02
|
5,66,563
|
1,37,802
|
18,882
|
3.3
|
13.7
|
2002-03
|
5,56,121
|
1,51,437
|
23,324
|
4.2
|
15.4
|
2003-04
|
6,25,121
|
1,53,770
|
31,972
|
5.1
|
20.8
|
2004-05
|
6,48,096
|
1,59,658
|
..
|
..
|
..
|
.. : Not available.
Source: National Accounts Statistics.
Table 11: Private Capital Formation
and Share of Long-Term Credit
(Rs. crore)
Decade/Year
|
Private Sector
Capital Formation
|
Investment
Credit
|
Per cent
(Col 3 over Col 2))
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
1980-81 to 1989-90
|
7,840
|
2,603
|
33.2
|
1990-91 to 1999-2000
|
12,299
|
7,794
|
63.4
|
2000-01
|
15,374
|
11,707
|
76.2
|
2001-02
|
15,823
|
11,992
|
75.8
|
Source: Reserve Bank of
India (2004).
In addition to the above data analysis,
I must mention that non-institutional agricultural credit has declined from
over 92.7 per cent in 1950s to 38.9 per cent in 2002. Thus, nationalisation
of banks and their increased geographical expansion into rural areas certainly
made a difference but there is scope for improvement.
The rising economic activity in
rural areas driven by the growth of newer activities such as horticulture, floriculture,
organic farming, genetic engineering, food processing and packaging – all of
which are cash intensive - would necessitate increased banking facilities. In
view of the evidence of a pick-up in consumer financing in rural areas, there
is also a need to streamline the supply chain to deliver credit at the lowest
cost to the ultimate user in the rural areas, to the benefit of both the bank
and the borrower. And, as is the case for most developing countries, bank credit
will be the key driver towards financing emerging activities.
VI. Strategy for Bank Credit
There has been a long history of
concern regarding agricultural credit. The increase in share of institutional
credit to agriculture has been rather slow. It has clearly been found difficult
to extend institutional credit in rural areas. Some of the important reasons
pertained to risk perception, costs of its assessment and management, lack of
rural infrastructure, and vast geographical spread of the rural areas with more
than half a million villages, some sparsely populated.
Lending to small borrowers dispersed
over vast expenses of geographical areas naturally involve high transaction
costs. The strategy that evolved after considerable experimentation was to provide
for directed credit to priority sectors that have primarily included agriculture
and small scale industries. This was also the key reason for nationalisation
of banks. That this strategy has been relatively successful is borne out by
the data (Table 1), but it may have reached its limit, as also demonstrated
by the deterioration in the reach of formal credit in the 1990s.
The key issue now is how to mainstream
rural credit from institutional sources so as to achieve wider coverage, expand
financial inclusion and promote economic growth. Increasingly, banks and other
financial intermediaries have to see the extension of rural credit as a business
opportunity and not as an obligation to do forced directed lending.
One strategy that is achieving
great popularity and wide acceptance is that of micro finance, as best exemplified
by the success of the Bangladesh Grameen Bank, which has now also achieved even
greater recognition through the award of the Nobel Peace Prize to Mohammad Yunus.
But most micro finance is not only for crops, but for other lending, in both
rural and urban areas. The main issue is that of reducing transaction costs
for both the lender and the borrower.
For banks, micro finance agencies
and other financial intermediaries to look at rural lending as business opportunities,
much more information generation has to be done so that they recognise and understand
the many different activities that take place in the rural economy in addition
to crop agriculture. Non cereal foods, non-food agriculture, service activities,
construction and housing, rural retail activities, will all increasing levels
of formal financing channels that are easy to access. This will need innovation
in risk assessment, reduction in transaction costs, the search for new credit
channels, and the use of cheaper information technology for delivery and collection
systems.
The task of policy-makers in designing
an appropriate package of measures becomes more challenging considering the
fact that the new growth areas of agriculture are characterised by a high degree
of heterogeneity, unlike in the case of traditional crops such as rice and wheat.
There is a multiplicity of varieties that can be produced in each of these product
groups; production is often regionally concentrated; the production and marketing
conditions differ significantly; and the input requirements are equally heterogeneous.
Hence, policies and programmes that are to be attuned to support higher productivity
and production in these areas need to be much more regionally disaggregated
and knowledge intensive. A key difference in approach would have to be the much
greater involvement of region-specific market participants, and of private sector
suppliers in all these activities, and credit suppliers ranging from public
sector banks, co-operative banks, the new private sector banks and micro-credit
suppliers, especially self-help groups.
To finance all these new activities,
which will aid and accelerate economic growth tremendously, banks will clearly
need to step up their efforts in generating deposits as well from the many currently
underserved households and small businesses.
VII. Role of RBI
Historically, the Reserve Bank
and the Government of India have been making efforts to increase banking penetration
in the country. Some of these measures include the creation of State Bank of
India in 1955; nationalisation of commercial banks in 1969 and 1980; initiating
the Lead Bank Scheme in 1970; establishing regional rural banks (RRBs) in 1975;
introducing a Self-help Group (SHG)-Bank Linkage Programme in 1992 and formulating
the Kisan Credit Card scheme in 2001. Notwithstanding these improvements,
financial inclusion found a place in policy documents only very recently. In
the Annual Policy of the Reserve Bank for 2004-05, the Governor, Dr. Reddy observed
and I quote -
There has been expansion, greater
competition and diversification of ownership of banks leading to both enhanced
efficiency and systemic resilience in the banking sector. However, there are
legitimate concerns in regard to the banking practices that tend to exclude
rather than attract vast sections of population, in particular pensioners, self-employed
and those employed in unorganised sector. While commercial considerations are
no doubt important, the banks have been bestowed with several privileges, especially
of seeking public deposits on a highly leveraged basis, and consequently they
should be obliged to provide banking services to all segments of the population,
on equitable basis.
Pursuant to this, the Reserve Bank
has undertaken a number of measures with the objective of attracting the financially
excluded population into the structured financial system. These measures, mainly,
are in the nature of code of ethics and voluntary charters to promote greater
financial access (Box 2).
Box 2: Measures undertaken by Reserve
Bank towards Financial Inclusion
In November 2005, banks were advised
to make available a basic banking ‘no-frills’ account with low or nil minimum
stipulated balances as well as charges to expand the outreach of such accounts
to vast sections of the population. Several banks have since introduced such
'no-frills' account with and without value-added features. According to the
information available with the Reserve Bank, about five lakh no-frill accounts
have been opened until March 31, 2006, of which about two-third are with the
public sector and one-third with the private sector banks.
In order to ensure that persons
belonging to low income group, both in urban and rural areas do not encounter
difficulties in opening bank accounts owing to procedural hassles, the know
your customer (KYC) procedures for opening accounts has been simplified. The
Reserve Bank has directed banks to make available all printed material used
by retail customers in English, Hindi and the concerned regional language. More
recently, in January 2006, banks were permitted to utilise the services of non-governmental
organisations (NGOs/SHGs), micro-finance institutions and other civil society
organisations as intermediaries in providing financial and banking services
through the use of business facilitator and business correspondent models.
To extend hassle-free credit to
bank customers in rural areas, the guidelines on general credit card (GCC) schemes
were simplified to enable customers’ access credit on simplified terms and conditions,
without insistence on security, purpose or end-use of credit. With a view of
providing hassle free credit to customers, banks were allowed to issue general
credit cards akin to Kisan credit cards. A simplified mechanism for one-time
settlement of loans with principal amount up to Rs.25,000 which have become
doubtful and loss assets as on September 30, 2005 was suggested for adoption.
In case of loans granted under Government-sponsored schemes, banks were advised
to frame separate guidelines following a state-specific approach to be evolved
by the State-Level Bankers’ Committee (SLBC). Banks have been specifically advised
that borrowers with loans settled under the one time settlement scheme will
be eligible to re-access the formal financial system for fresh credit. Banks
were advised to give effect to these measures at all branches for achieving
greater financial inclusion. Initiatives have also been undertaken towards achieving
greater financial inclusion in the North-Eastern region, which had perennially
remained under-banked.
The Reserve Bank considers that
IT-enabled services can meet the challenges which need to be addressed for increasing
the scope and coverage of financial inclusion such as lack of adequate infrastructure,
higher transaction costs and low volumes of transactions. The Reserve Bank has
already initiated action in the North-Eastern region.
Source: Reserve Bank of
India.
The Reserve Bank has also been
periodically issuing guidelines on public grievance redressal mechanism in banks,
including constitution of customer service centers. Based on the recommendations
of a Committee on Procedures and Performance Audit of Public Services for ensuring
improvements in quality of service rendered, banks were advised to constitute
a Customer Service Committee of the Board. In the Reserve Bank, the Customer
Service Department has recently been constituted to, inter alia, serve
as the interface between customers and banks.
On a broader plane, the Reserve
Bank has been adopting a two-pronged strategy to generate greater awareness
and expand the reach of banking services – which can be termed as empowerment
and protection. As regards the former, financial inclusion is the first stage
of the process. This is strengthened by inculcating awareness among the masses
through financial education. Concurrently, an advisory mechanism in the form
of credit counseling is being encouraged to help distressed borrowers and bring
them within the fold of formal finance. As regards protection, a Banking Codes
and Standards Board of India has been established recently to ensure a comprehensive
code of conduct for minimum standards of banking services to be offered by banks.
The revised Banking Ombudsman Scheme has been put in place to redress deficiencies
in customer service by banks.
VIII. Concluding Remarks
The economy is presently in
a phase of rapidly rising incomes, rural and urban, arising from an expansion
of extant economic activities as well as the creation of new activities. Corporate
profitability has exhibited sustainable trends and consumer incomes are increasing
rapidly, riding on the growth momentum. All of these developments suggest that
the demand for financial services, both for savings as well as production purposes,
will be greater than has been the case in the past, and there will be many new
entrants in need of financial services who have not hitherto been served. At
present our financial depth is much lower than that of other Asian countries,
though it has picked up in the recent past. While there is evidence of an increase
in financial deepening, particularly during the present decade, the increase
in the breadth and coverage of formal finance has been less than adequate. Deepening
the financial system and widening its reach is crucial for both accelerating
growth and for equitable distribution, given the present stage of development
of our country.
There has been a burst of entrepreneurship
across the country, spanning rural, semi-urban and urban areas. This has to
be nurtured and financed. It is only through growth of enterprises across all
sizes that competition will be fostered. A small entrepreneur today will be
a big entrepreneur tomorrow, and might well become a multinational enterprise
eventually if given the comfort of financial support. But we also have to understand
that there will be failures as well as successes. Banks will therefore have
to tone up their risk assessment and risk management capacities, and provide
for these failures as part of their risk management. Despite the risk, financing
of first time entrepreneurs is a must for financial inclusion and growth.
The Parliament passed the Credit
Information Bureau Act last year and the guidelines for its implementation will
be released shortly. This should enable, over time, the availability of credit
histories of both individuals and small businesses, which will help significantly
in reducing transactions and information costs for banks. It will also help
in spreading the credit culture among borrowers. It should help banks greatly
in assessing and managing risk at low cost.
As poverty levels decline and
households have greater levels of discretionary incomes, they will be first
time financial savers. They will, therefore, need to have easy access to formal
financial systems to get into the banking habit. Banks will need to innovate
and devise newer methods of including such customers into their fold. The importance
of 'no-frills' account and expanding the range of identity documents that is
acceptable to open an account without sacrificing objectivity of the process
in this milieu can never be over-emphasised. Banks will need to go to their
customers, rather than the other way around.
The micro-credit and the Self Help
Group movements are in their infancy but are gathering force. More innovation
in the form of business facilitators and correspondents will be needed for banks
to increase their outreach for banks to ensure financial inclusion. New entrants
to the banking system need households at their doorstep.
To conclude, I wish to stress
that with increasing liberalisation and higher economic growth, the role of
banking sector is poised to increase in the financing pattern of economic activities
within the country. To meet the growing credit demand, the banks need to mobilise
resources from a wider deposit base and extend credit to activities hitherto
not financed by banks. The trend of increasing commercialisation of agriculture
and rural activities should generate greener pastures, and banks should examine
the benefits of increasing penetration therein. Financial inclusion will strengthen
financial deepening and provide resources to the banks to expand credit delivery.
Thus, financial inclusion will lead to financial development in our country
which will help to accelerate economic growth.
Thank you.
References
Aghion, P., and P. Howitt (1998):
Endogenous Growth Theory, MIT Press.
Aghion, P., and P. Howitt (2005):
Appropriate Growth Policy: A Unifying Framework, The 2005 Joseph Schumpeter
Lecture, European Economic Association, Amsterdam.
Barth, J., G. Caprio and R. Levine
(2001): The Regulation and Supervision of Banks around the World: A New Database,
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2588. Washington DC.
Bell, C. (2001): 'Post-independence
India: A Case of Finance-led Industrialisation', Journal of Development Economics
65, 153-75.
Buckland, J., and B. Guenther (2005):
'There Are No Banks Here, Financial and Insurance Exclusion in Winnipeg’ North
End', Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada (September).
Caskey, J. P., C. R. Duran, C.
R. and T. M. Solo (2006): 'The Urban Unbanked in Mexico and the United States',
World Bank Policy research Wprking Paper 3835.
Connolly, C., and K.Hajaj (2001):
'Financial Services and Social Exclusion', Financial Services Consumer Policy
Center, University of New South Wales.
Government of India: Economic
Survey (various years), Government of India New Delhi.
HM Treasury (1999): Access to
Financial services. London: HM Treasury.
Kempson, E. (2006): 'Policy Level
Response to Financial Exclusion in Developed Economies: Lessons for Developing
Countries', paper presented at the conference, Access to Finance: Building Inclusive
Financial Systems, World Bank, Washington, D.C.
Kempson, E., J. Caskey, C. Whyley
and S. Collard (2000): In or Out? London: Financial Services Authority.
King, R.G. and R. Levine (1993):
Finance and Growth: Schumpeter might be right, Quarterly Journal of Economics
108, 717-37.
Levine, R. and S. Zervos (1998):
Stock Markets, Banks and Economic Growth, American Economic Review 88,
537-58.
Mohan, R. (2002): 'Transforming
Indian Banking: In Search of a Better Tomorrow', RBI Bulletin (January).
Mohan, R. (2004): 'Financial Sector
Reforms in India: Policies and Performance Analysis', RBI Bulletin (October).
Mohan, R. (2006): 'Agricultural
Credit in India: Status, Issues and Future Agenda', Economic and Political
Weekly (March), pp.1013-23.
NCAER (2003): India
market Demographics Report 2002, New Delhi: NCAER.
Rajan, R.G. and L. Zingales (1998):
'Financial Dependence and Growth', American Economic Review 88, 559-86.
Rajan, R.G. and L. Zingales (2003):
Saving Capitalism from Capitalists, Crown Business, New York.
Reserve Bank of India (2004): Report
of the Advisory Committee on Flow of Credit to Agriculture and Related Activities
from Banking System (Chairman: V. S. Vyas). RBI, Mumbai.
Annex Table 1: Select Macro Economic
Indicators - Annual Average Growth Rate
(per cent)
|
1970-71 to
|
1991-92 to
|
2001-02 to
|
|
1990-91
|
2000-01
|
2005-06
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
1. Per capita income*
|
2.0
|
3.5
|
5.3
|
2. Population
|
2.2
|
2.0
|
1.7
|
3. GDP (constant
prices) |
4.4
|
5.7
|
6.7
|
Agriculture
|
2.9
|
2.6
|
2.5
|
Industry
|
5.9
|
5.9
|
6.2
|
of which:
|
|
|
|
Manufacturing
|
5.7
|
6.1
|
6.8
|
Services
|
5.3
|
7.4
|
8.6
|
4. Gross Domestic
Savings
(as per cent of GDP) |
18.7
|
23.2
|
27
|
Household
|
13.7
|
18.7
|
22.7
|
Corporate
|
1.7
|
3.9
|
4.2
|
Public
|
3.3
|
0.7
|
0.1
|
5. Gross Domestic
Investment
(as per cent of GDP) |
19.8
|
24.3
|
26.4
|
6. Inflation (WPI)
|
8.7
|
7.8
|
4.7
|
*: NNP (factor cost)
Source: National Accounts Statistics, CSO.
Annex Table 2: Index of Openness
of the Indian Economy
(per cent of GDP)
|
1991-96
|
1996-2001
|
2001-06
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
1.Merchandise Exports
2. Merchandise Imports
|
8.0
10.1
|
8.8
12.4
|
11.3
14.9
|
3.Gross Invisible Receipts*
4. Gross Invisible Payments
|
4.1
3.1
|
6.1
3.8
|
9.2
5.1
|
5.Index of opening (1+2+3+4)
|
25.3
|
31.1
|
40.5
|
* Less
official transfers.
Source: Reserve Bank of India.
|
(* Address by Dr. Rakesh Mohan
at the Annual Bankers' Conference 2006, at Hyderabad on Nov 3, 2006. This draws
heavily on my earlier lecture on a similar subject at the FICCI-IBA Conference
in Mumbai on Sep 26, 2006) |