The combination of growth slowdown, persistence of inflation above the comfort level and a
historically high CAD posed a special challenge for monetary policy making during 2012-13.
The Reserve Bank addressed this with calibrated reductions in the policy rate and liquidity
easing measures. Despite a large injection of durable liquidity through CRR cuts and OMOs,
liquidity conditions tightened especially since November 2012, mainly due to large and persistent
build-ups in government cash balances. Broad money growth was in line with the Reserve Bank’s
indicative trajectory for 2012-13. Going forward, while the asset quality of the banking sector
remains a major concern, the Reserve Bank’s monetary policy would strive to ensure adequate
flow of credit to productive sectors, while keeping a vigil on inflation and working towards
reducing macro-economic imbalances.
The Reserve Bank undertakes calibrated
monetary policy easing
IV.1 The Reserve Bank has been managing
the growth-inflation dynamics based on the tenet
that low and stable inflation secures sustained
high medium-term growth and facilitates
consumers’ and investors’ decision-making. The
macroeconomic priorities that have shaped
recent monetary policy making include the need
to address growth slowdown, restrain inflation
pressures and mitigate vulnerabilities in the
external sector. After a quick recovery in the
post-crisis period, domestic economic growth significantly decelerated in 2011-12 and further
during 2012-13 on account of both sluggish
global growth and domestic bottlenecks.
IV.2 Taking cognizance of falling growth,
the Reserve Bank lowered policy interest rate
and the SLR by 100 bps each, and the CRR by
75 bps in 2012-13 on top of a 125 bps cut in the
CRR in Q4 of 2011-12 (Table IV.1). It also
undertook durable liquidity injections through
outright purchases of G-secs as a part of open
market operations (OMOs) totalling about `1.5
trillion during the year. After front-loading a 50
bps policy rate cut in April 2012, the Reserve Bank had to hold rate in the absence of the
expected momentum on fiscal consolidation and
elevated inflation concerns. However, since
September 2012, a renewed commitment to
containing the fiscal deficit provided space to
the Reserve Bank for further policy easing. In
response, the policy rates were lowered further
by 50 bps in Q4 of 2012-13. Rising CAD risks,
however, prompted the Reserve Bank to
exercise caution while easing.
Table IV.1: Movements in Key Policy Variables |
(Per cent) |
Effective since |
Repo Rate |
Cash Reserve Ratio* |
Statutory Liquidity Ratio* |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
May 3, 2011 |
7.25 (+0.50) |
6.00 |
24 |
June 16, 2011 |
7.50 (+0.25) |
6.00 |
24 |
July 26, 2011 |
8.00 (+0.50) |
6.00 |
24 |
September 16, 2011 |
8.25 (+0.25) |
6.00 |
24 |
October 25, 2011 |
8.50 (+0.25) |
6.00 |
24 |
January 28, 2012 |
8.50 |
5.50 (-0.50) |
24 |
March 10, 2012 |
8.50 |
4.75 (-0.75) |
24 |
April 17, 2012 |
8.00 (-0.50) |
4.75 |
24 |
August 11, 2012 |
8.00 |
4.75 |
23 (-1.00) |
September 22, 2012 |
8.00 |
4.50 (-0.25) |
23 |
November 3, 2012 |
8.00 |
4.25 (-0.25) |
23 |
January 29,2013 |
7.75 (-0.25) |
4.25 |
23 |
February 9,2013 |
7.75 |
4.00 (-0.25) |
23 |
March 19, 2013 |
7.50 (-0.25) |
4.00 |
23 |
Note: Since May 2011, the repo rate has been placed in the middle of the corridor, with the reverse repo rate 100 basis points below it and the MSF rate 100 basis points above it.
*: Percent of NDTL. |
Reserve Bank took measures to combat
tight liquidity conditions
IV.3 Liquidity conditions exhibited mixed
trends during 2012-13, with a generally
comfortable liquidity situation interspersed with
bouts of tightness, which, can be divided into
three broad phases. In the first phase, which was
prolonged until June 2012, the liquidity deficit
was broadly outside the Reserve Bank’s comfort
zone, largely due to the spillover of the tight
liquidity conditions of Q4, 2011-12. Active
liquidity-easing measures taken by the Reserve
Bank that included CRR cuts and open market
purchases resulted in a comfortable liquidity
situation by July 2012, which marked the
beginning of the second phase. This phase of
comfortable liquidity lasted until mid-October
2012. The third phase began thereafter, when,
despite easing measures followed by the
Reserve Bank, persistently high government
cash balances and strong currency demand kept
the inter-bank liquidity deficit beyond the Reserve Bank’s comfort zone. The Reserve
Bank reduced the CRR in November 2012, and
resumed outright OMOs on December 4, 2012
after a gap of more than five months
(Chart IV.1).
IV.4 The third phase of liquidity deficit
continued during Q4 of 2012-13. This period
saw a large build-up of government cash
balance. The Reserve Bank provided liquidity
through LAF injections hovering around `1
trillion on a daily average basis during this
period. In order to pre-empt end-quarter
liquidity pressures, the Reserve Bank lowered
the CRR of scheduled banks (SCBs) by 25 basis
points to 4.0 per cent of their net demand and
time liabilities (NDTL) effective from the
fortnight beginning February 9, 2013.
Additionally, the Reserve Bank conducted four
outright OMO (purchase) auctions during Q4
and accepted bids amounting to `335 billion in
these auctions, taking the total amount of
liquidity injection to `1.5 trillion through these
operations during the financial year, including
`231 billion through anonymous trading
platform (NDS-OM). Finally, in view of the
anticipated large volume of banking transactions
during the annual closing of accounts for 2012-
13, the Reserve Bank conducted additional
liquidity operations on March 28, 2013 (only
Repo) and special LAF (Repo, Reverse repo
and MSF) on March 30 and 31, 2013 (i.e.
Saturday and Sunday, respectively), which facilitated smooth and non-disruptive conduct
of banking operations.
IV.5 During 2012-13, liquidity management
encountered several challenges. However, the
pre-emptive and calibrated use of varied
instruments, which included reduction(s) in
SLR and CRR, OMO purchases and additional
LAF arrangements, had a positive impact on
liquidity management, which got reflected in
many of the market indicators. The call rate
generally remained anchored close to the repo
rate and below the MSF rate during 2012-13.
The dependence on MSF was miniscule and
clearly lower than in 2011-12, despite the
Reserve Bank raising the borrowing limit of
SCBs under the MSF to 2 per cent of their
NDTL (Chart IV.2). Moreover, the volatility of
the call rate, as indicated by its monthly
standard deviation, generally declined in 2012-13. The call/notice rates generally
remained within the corridor except on March
28, 2013. During April 2013 so far, liquidity
conditions had eased following significant
draw-down of government’s cash balances.
Reserve money adjusted for CRR changes
increased at a reasonable pace
IV.6 During 2012-13, the path of reserve
money mainly reflected developments in the
net domestic asset (NDA) during the year. On
the components side, growth of currency in
circulation marginally decelerated, reflecting
the impact of the economic slowdown on
currency demand. Bankers’ deposits with the
Reserve Bank recorded negative growth,
mainly on account of policy-induced CRR cuts
by the Reserve Bank. Since January 2012, the
CRR has been reduced in stages by 200 bps to 4 per cent, injecting around `1.3 trillion of
primary liquidity into the banking system.
Reserve money, adjusted for the CRR changes,
however recorded a reasonable growth over the
year (Chart IV.3).
IV.7 In Q4 of 2012-13, there was an increase
in reserve money in absolute terms. This
increase in reserve money was mainly driven
by an increase in the currency in circulation. On
the sources side, there has been a commensurate
increase in the net Reserve Bank credit to the
centre. The y-o-y CRR-adjusted reserve money
growth remained stable at around 9.5 per cent
in 2012-13, the same as in the previous year.
Broad money growth remained on the
indicative trajectory
IV.8 Excess reserves created through cut(s)
in the CRR generally lead to increase in money
supply through the money multiplier process,
which crucially depends on the credit appetite
of the economy. In 2012-13, there was stagnation
in aggregate deposits growth and deceleration
in credit growth. The latter somewhat dampened
the multiplier expansion (Chart IV.4). However,
the M3 remained on the indicative trajectory of
the Reserve Bank during 2012-13 (Table IV.2).
Table IV.2: Monetary Indicators |
Item |
Out-
standing
Amount (` billion)
31-Mar-13 |
Y-o-Y
Variations
(per cent) |
31-
Mar-12 |
31-
Mar-13 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
Reserve Money (M0) |
15,146.4 |
3.6 |
6.2 |
Reserve Money (Adjusted) |
|
9.5 |
9.5 |
Broad Money (M3) |
83,444.9 |
13.2 |
13.3 |
Main Components of M3 |
|
|
|
Currency with the Public |
11,445.3 |
12.2 |
11.9 |
Aggregate Deposits |
71,967.6 |
13.4 |
13.5 |
of which: Demand Deposits |
7,420.9 |
-1.6 |
4.4 |
Time Deposits |
64,546.7 |
15.7 |
14.7 |
Main Sources of M3 |
|
|
|
Net Bank Credit to Government |
26,996.4 |
19.5 |
13.8 |
Bank Credit to Commercial Sector |
56,405.5 |
17.0 |
13.8 |
Net Foreign Assets of the Banking Sector |
15,991.4 |
10.8 |
3.6 |
Note: 1. Data are provisional.
2. Government balances as on March 31, 2013 are before closure of accounts. |
IV.9 On the component side, the muted
aggregate deposit growth during 2012-13 at
13.5 per cent was mainly because of the
deceleration in time-deposit growth. One major reason for the deceleration was the near-zero
real interest rate on term deposits mainly due
to high inflation. Although there was monetary
policy easing over 2012-13, some banks raised
their deposit rates, from mid-December 2012
in certain maturity buckets in view of the tight
liquidity conditions, resulting in a marginal
increase in the modal deposit rate by 2 bps
during the second half of 2012-13 as against a
decline of 13 bps during the first half of the
year. During Q4 of 2012-13, although the deposit growth of SCBs continued to decelerate,
going forward, the ebb in inflation and the
consequent increase in the real interest rate are
likely to boost deposit growth (Chart IV.4).
IV.10 Consequent to deceleration in domestic
growth, the demand for credit in India was
adversely affected. The deterioration in credit
quality, on the other hand, impeded the supply
of domestic credit. Notwithstanding the large
injection of liquidity by the Reserve Bank,
adverse sentiments emanating from global and
domestic developments somewhat dampened
credit expansion and the SCBs’ non-food credit
growth remained below the Reserve Bank’s
indicative trajectory. Despite low off-take,
credit growth remained above deposit growth
for most of 2012-13. However, the wedge
between credit growth and deposit growth
closed at the end of the year (Chart IV.1b).
Preliminary data indicate that the weighted average lending rate on fresh rupee loans
sanctioned by the reporting banks declined
significantly during February 2013 compared
with the previous month which was also
reflected in the interest rates on fresh rupee loans
sanctioned to housing and vehicle segments
during that period.
Risk aversion impacting credit as asset
quality concerns accentuate
IV.11 Besides sluggish demand, a major
factor that led to the low credit growth of the
banking sector over the past year is the
deterioration in its asset quality. Asset quality
indicators of the banking sector, which had
deteriorated significantly during 2011-12, have
further worsened in 2012-13 (Table IV.3).
Although data indicate worsening asset quality
across bank groups during Q3 of 2012-13, it
continued to be led by PSBs, which account for
the major portion of bank advances. Deterioration in both asset quality and macroeconomic
conditions resulted in increased risk aversion
and consequent deceleration in credit growth
across bank groups (Table IV.4).
Table IV.3: Asset Quality Indicator of the Banking Sector |
|
Mar-12 |
Dec-12 |
Gross
NPA to
Gross
Adva nces
(%) |
Net NPAs
to Net
Adva nces
(%) |
Slipp age
Ratio # |
Restru ctured
Std. Asset
to Gross
Advances
(%) |
CRAR
(%) |
Gross
NPA to
Gross
Adva nces
(%) |
Net NPAs
to Net
Adva nces
(%) |
Slippage
Ratio # |
Restru ctured
Std. Asset
to Gross
Advances
(%) |
CRAR
(%) |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
11 |
Public Sector Banks |
3.17 |
1.47 |
2.95 |
5.74 |
13.23 |
4.18 |
2.10 |
3.28 |
7.41 |
12.00 |
Foreign Banks |
2.68 |
0.61 |
2.31 |
0.10 |
16.75 |
2.96 |
1.02 |
1.92 |
0.18 |
17.17 |
New Private Sector Banks |
2.18 |
0.44 |
1.17 |
1.06 |
16.66 |
2.02 |
0.45 |
1.36 |
1.07 |
17.11 |
Old Private Sector Banks |
1.80 |
0.59 |
1.12 |
3.54 |
14.12 |
2.20 |
0.86 |
1.54 |
4.08 |
13.38 |
All Banks |
2.94 |
1.24 |
2.55 |
4.69 |
14.24 |
3.69 |
1.73 |
2.86 |
5.92 |
13.50 |
# Based on the data collected from banks for special analysis. Dec-12 figures of slippage are annualised.
Source: Latest updated OSMOS data. |
Table IV.4: Credit Flow from Scheduled Commercial Banks (` billion) |
Bank Credit |
As on
Apr 5, 2013 Outstanding
Amount |
Variation (y-o-y) |
As on Apr 6, 2012 |
As on Apr 5,2013 |
Amount |
Percent |
Amount |
Percent |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
1 Public Sector Banks* |
39,089.9 |
5,254.8 |
17.9 |
4,410.1 |
12.7 |
2 Foreign Banks |
2,651.6 |
367.9 |
18.8 |
328.9 |
14.2 |
3 Private Sector Banks |
10,361.3 |
1,561.5 |
21.6 |
1,583.2 |
18.0 |
4 All Scheduled Com. Banks@ |
53,463.9 |
7,401.2 |
18.7 |
6,529.8 |
13.9 |
*: Excluding RRBs in public sector banks. @: including RRBs.
Note: Data as on April 5, 2013 are provisional. |
IV.12 An analysis of the sectoral deployment
of credit based on data from select banks (which
cover 95 per cent of total non-food credit
extended by all SCBs) for March 2013 reveals
that non-food bank credit growth (y-o-y) to
industries and services decelerated. The year-on-
year bank credit growth to industry at 15.7
per cent in March 2013 moderated considerably,
from 20.3 per cent in March 2012. Deceleration
in credit growth to industry was observed in all
the major sub-sectors, barring leather, chemicals,
cement, wood products, food processing,
textiles, glass and vehicles.
Flow of resources from banks to the
commercial sector was significantly
augmented by non-bank sources
IV.13 During 2012-13, non-banks continued
to significantly contributed to the resource flow
to the commercial sector in addition to the
banks. The quantum flow of financial resources
to the commercial sector increased during 2012-
13 mainly due to an increase in non-SLR
investment by SCBs and gross private
placements by non-financial entities compared
to the corresponding period last year. Among
foreign sources, while there were increases in
external commercial borrowings (ECBs) and
short-term credit from abroad, foreign direct
investment flows declined (Table IV.5).
Table IV.5: Resource Flow to the Commercial Sector |
(` billion) |
|
April–March |
April–March |
2009-10 |
2010-11 |
2011-12 |
2011-12 |
2012-13 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
A. |
Adjusted Non-Food Bank Credit (NFC) |
4,786 |
7,110 |
6,773 |
6,773 |
6,839 |
|
i) |
Non-Food Credit |
4,670 |
6,815 |
6,527 |
6,527 |
6,359 |
|
|
of which: petroleum and fertiliser credit |
100 |
-243 |
171 |
101* |
38 * |
|
ii) |
Non-SLR Investment by SCBs |
117 |
295 |
246 |
246 |
481 |
B. |
Flow from Non-Banks (B1+B2) |
5,850 |
5,341 |
5,274 |
4,841 |
5,951 |
|
B1. |
Domestic Sources |
3,652 |
3,011 |
2,970 |
2,033 |
2,772 |
|
|
1. Public issues by non-financial entities |
320 |
285 |
45 |
45 |
117 |
|
|
2. Gross private placements by non-financial entities |
1,420 |
674 |
558 |
401* |
620 p* |
|
|
3. Net issuance of CPs subscribed to by non-banks |
261 |
68 |
36 |
36 |
55 |
|
|
4. Net Credit by housing finance companies |
285 |
428 |
530 |
430$ |
583 $ |
|
|
5. Total gross accommodation by 4 RBI-regulated AIFIs: NABARD, NHB, SIDBI & EXIM Bank |
338 |
400 |
469 |
347$ |
288 $ |
|
|
6. Systemically important non-deposit taking NBFCs (net of bank credit) |
607 |
795 |
912 |
480+ |
716 + |
|
|
7. LIC's net investment in corporate debt, infrastructure and social sector |
422 |
361 |
419 |
295# |
393 # |
|
B2. |
Foreign Sources |
2,198 |
2,330 |
2,304 |
2,808 |
3,179 |
|
|
1. External Commercial Borrowings/FCCBs |
120 |
555 |
421 |
421 |
466 |
|
|
2. ADR/GDR Issues, excluding banks and financial institutions |
151 |
92 |
27 |
27 |
10 |
|
|
3. Short-term credit from abroad |
349 |
502 |
306 |
298* |
855 * |
|
|
4. Foreign Direct Investment to India |
1,578 |
1,181 |
1,550 |
2,062$ |
1,848 $ |
C. |
Total Flow of Resources (A+B) |
10,636 |
12,451 |
12,047 |
11,615 |
12,791 |
Memo:
Net resource mobilisation by Mutual Funds through Debt (non-Gilt) Schemes |
966 |
-367 |
-185 |
-185 |
830 |
$ Up to end-February 2013. P : Provisional. + Up to September 30, 2012. * Up to December 2012. |
Monetary conditions may evolve with
macroeconomic developments and shifting
growth-inflation dynamics
IV.14 While the calibrated monetary policy
and liquidity measures over the year have
resulted in monetary growth in line with the
indicative trajectory, the monetary policy stance
in 2013-14 would be conditioned primarily by
three macroeconomic challenges that need to
be addressed. These challenges emanate from
decelerating growth, comparatively high
consumer price inflation and external
vulnerability.
IV.15 At present, domestic inflation remains
at a level that is above the Reserve Bank’s
comfort level. Furthermore, consumer price
inflation is in double digits, in part driven by
food inflation that gets a higher weight in CPI
than headline inflation. The significant wedge
between wholesale price and consumer price
inflation is exacerbating the challenge for
monetary management in anchoring inflationary
expectations.
IV.16 In this context, it may be restated that
the Reserve Bank looks at all types of inflation and inflation indices while framing its monetary
policy. While communicating its inflation
projections in terms of headline WPI inflation,
to which it accords greater weight, it does take
into account CPI inflation. The high CPI
inflation and large food inflation in the WPI
cannot be ignored, especially in view of the
consumption patterns in India and the time-tested
fact that high food inflation, if it persists,
gets generalised and often requires a monetary
policy response.
IV.17 Monetary policy reactions would need
to keep in view the forward-looking expectations
on inflation and the level of real interest rates.
It is important to avoid financial disintermediation
or financial repression if growth is to be revived
on a sustainable footing. In a period of economic
slowdown, a pro-growth monetary policy may
push the interest rate down, but if the internal
rate of return (IRR) falls at a faster rate due to
depressed expected returns on investment,
monetary policy stimulus may have limited
effect. Factoring in these limitations and the
three challenges enumerated above, monetary
policy would need to be carefully calibrated to
balance growth-inflation dynamics. |