by Michael Debabrata Patra, Sunil Kumar, Joice John and Amarendra Acharya^ This study investigates the effectiveness of forex interventions undertaken by the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) and finds that the volatility of portfolio flows, induced by global spillovers, is the main source of exchange rate volatility in India. Foreign exchange interventions, both spot and forward, effectively counter capital flows volatility, with symmetric effects of purchases and sales. The impact of gross spot intervention on exchange rate volatility indicates the existence of threshold effects, explaining the “leaning against the wind” phenomenon. Introduction Since the latter half of the 1980s when several emerging market economies (EMEs) dismantled barriers to increasingly engage in international trade and finance, either voluntarily or as a part of structural adjustment programs, a steady accumulation of international reserves has given way to a surge since 2004. Global reserve holdings peaked at US $ 12.9 trillion by 2021, although bouts of high financial market volatility driven by risk-on- risk-off sentiment shifts since then necessitated interventions that have slightly modulated this stock to US $ 12.7 trillion in September 2024. This phenomenon has quite naturally found resonance with an old stream in the literature dating back to the days of the gold standard that worried about the motives, costs and benefits of reserve accumulation. This paper, by contrast, deals with the motives, costs and benefits of holding foreign exchange positions from an EME perspective, scarred by the experience with spillovers, which can be quite different from what engaged the older strand. It is important to note the differences. First, this phenomenon is about EMEs, which currently hold roughly three-fifth of international reserves whereas the older literature focused almost exclusively on advanced economies (AEs). Secondly, AEs have almost stopped intervening in foreign exchange markets; EMEs, on the other hand, intervene regularly and have developed institutional formats for it. Thirdly, these interventions tend to impact the path of the exchange rate more than in AEs because (a) they are not routinely sterilized; (b) the size of interventions are significant relative to the level of market turnover and base money; (c) elaborate reporting requirements confer on central banks in EMEs an information advantage in inferring the aggregate order flow in the market; and (d) prudential regulations and operating practices amplify the information advantage and the size of the intervention relative to the market (Canales-Kriljenko, 2003; Filardo et al., 2022; Linde et al., 2024). For EMEs, foreign exchange rate interventions are umbilically linked to the objective, either explicit or implicit, of mitigating volatility and not the level of the exchange rate or any band around it: in short, not the first moment but the second moment. Against the above backdrop, this paper evaluates the effectiveness of interventions by the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) in the foreign exchange market in India. In the rest of the paper, Section II extracts lessons from the existing literature. Some stylized facts with respect to intervention in India’s foreign exchange market are furnished in Section III. Section IV contains empirical results. Concluding perspectives are set out in Section V. II. Guideposts from the Literature As advanced economies withdrew from intervening in foreign exchange markets, the empirical literature imbibed the spirit of this retreat and largely focused on issues relating to its effectiveness – does it work or matter? (Obstfeld, 1990; Dominguez and Frenkel, 1993; Dominguez, 1998; Beattie and Fillion, 1999; Sarno and Taylor, 2002; Ito, 2003; Daude et al., 2016; Menkhoff, 2013; Linde et al., 2024 ); if it does, what is optimal and under what conditions? - an older strand had grudgingly visualized limiting conditions (Boyer, 1978; Buiter, 1979; Roper and Turnovsky, 1980; Jones, 1984; Blanchard et al., 2015); is it essentially the fear of floating? (Calvo and Reinhart, 2002); and is there room for it under an inflation targeting framework? (Domac and Mendoza, 2002; Adler et al., 2021). The repetitive visitations of crises through the 1990s and 2000s has swung the narrative completely! Modern generations of currency crises seem to be triggered by markets that conduct value at risk assessments of the central bank’s balance sheet, including off-balance sheet items, and whenever confidence levels in the central bank’s solvency appear likely to be breached, they strike (Blejer and Schumaker, 1998; Zeuli, 2013; Nocetti, 2006). Further, the illiquidity, arising out of short-term foreign currency debt becoming larger than liquid foreign currency assets, has been a cause of many exchange rate crises (Chang and Velasco, 1999). In these low probability high intensity events, fundamentals do not matter and each country stands alone – the implications of a crisis can be global but the responsibility for financial stability is national. Central banks having strong reserve buffers and institutional character generally come out of financial crises with less loss to their credibility (Bordo and Siklos, 2015). By the 2000s, the emerging market model of foreign exchange interventions had arrived! The benefits of foreign exchange intervention overwhelmed its costs as managing exchange rates and accumulating reserves became preferred policy options, rather than being stigmatized as in the earlier literature. In fact, high liquidity was increasingly seen as able to offset weak fundamentals and ward off contagion (Mulder and Bussier, 1999; Lai, 2002). Accordingly, attention turned to the market microstructure (Dominguez, et al. 1993; Vitale, 2011; Ormos and Timotity, 2016); instruments (Evans and Lyons, 2002; Galan et al., 1997; Hooyman, 1994; Hung, 1997; IMF, 1998; Mandeng, 2003; Zapatero et al., 2003); issues in transparency – announcement effects; signal to noise ratios – and the management of unavoidable operational risk (Fratzscher et al., 2019); persistence and asymmetric effect of purchase and sales (Blanchard et al., 2015; Adler et al., 2019) and policy framework resilience (Linde et al., 2024). We argue in this paper that perhaps the analytics of foreign exchange intervention in an EME context are better informed by the positive findings of consensus/central tendencies in a young but incisive stream in the literature that focuses on coalescing the experiences of the practitioners i.e., central banks themselves, through questionnaire-based surveys. It is also informed by progress under the IMF’s Integrated Policy Framework (IPF) which has a case study on India (Linde et al., 2024). This literature offers an interesting study in comparative statics. The starting point of reference becomes the IMF’s 2001 survey on foreign exchange market organization and the work spawned by it (Canales-Kriljenko, et al., 2003; Linde et al., 2024). This survey was perhaps the most extensive, with 91 respondents that together accounted for 85-90 per cent of developing countries’ GDP, trade and reserves. Moreover, such detailed information on foreign exchange operations in a broad range of countries had not been previously available (IMF, 2003). In 2013, the BIS sought the views of central banks about intervention for its annual meeting of Deputy Governors through a survey questionnaire. This survey revisited many of the aspects of intervention identified in the 2004 BIS survey (BIS, 2013), especially the role of interventions in reducing financial and monetary stability risks, in provision of liquidity support to the foreign exchange market and in meeting exchange rate objectives. Studies conducted around it, both within the BIS and by participating central banks, yield useful insights and importantly, provide an update on the 2001 IMF survey on operational aspects of intervention that are the centre of interest of this paper1. In this spirit, attempts have been to empirically estimate equilibrium exchange rates for India (Patra, et al., 2024) Definitional Issues In the emerging market context, the narrow definition of intervention in the mainstream literature – central bank foreign exchange operations targeting the exchange rate2 - gives way to a broader format encompassing moderating exchange rate fluctuations and correcting misalignments, addressing disorderly market conditions (an objective blessed by the IMF), accumulating reserves and supplying liquidity to the foreign exchange market (Canales-Kriljenko et al., 2003). Consequently, operational issues – timing; frequency; amounts; instruments/currency pairs; locations; counterparties – are the main decision drivers for central banks. Another major consideration is that interventions effectively turn into monetary policy operations when not fully sterilized and necessitate calibration with the monetary policy stance3. Also, though thinly advocated, interventions provide breathing space for undertaking deeper macroeconomic adjustments if there are structural imbalances impacting the exchange market. The microstructure approach (Lyons, 2001; Evans and Lyons, 2002) shines light on this operational view. The balance between buyer-initiated and seller-initiated orders is a measure of the net exchange market pressure. Interventions cause changes in expectations on future exchange rates, triggering modifications in open positions, especially by noise traders chasing trends. The result is a tide of buy/ sell orders well in excess of the central bank’s initial intervention. Furthermore, market participants may regard these operations as central banks exploiting superior or privy information and order flows generated in response to “impound information into prices” (Lyons, 2001). The microstructure approach also emphasizes the size of intervention relative to market turnover – the larger the intervention, the higher is its impact on the price, thus potentially more effective in emerging markets that have relatively low market turnover and are less liquid, including due to exchange control and other regulations (Canales-Kriljenko et al., 2003). The IMF’s quantitative integrated policy framework (IPF) shows that even though India’s FX market has been mostly deep, it could become shallow in certain periods, including during the GFC and COVID-19 (Linde et al., 2024). Operational Priors The intervention strategy involves as a first step the setting up of management tolerance thresholds. -
Defining the metric – which exchange rate measure i.e., nominal/real; effective/bilateral; the extent of movement to be tolerated; and over what specified period. The overwhelming choice among surveyed central banks is a currency pair(s), a tight band in basis points around it that defines authorities’ tolerance during a trading day (Goldstein, 2002). -
Amount and timing – clearly an area in which the optimal intervention literature fails the practitioner4. Determining the amount is usually highly subjective, shaped by trial and error, and suffused with central banks’ judgment honed by unique experiences and country-specific circumstances. Central banks also report extensive reliance on assessments of market intelligence, observable market indicators and the level of reserves. In terms of first principles, the size of the intervention is usually a multiple of the typical market order and technically as large as necessary to achieve the exchange rate metric. Size constraints apply less to purchases than to sales, since the former can be financed by printing domestic currency and sterilized to insulate the inflation objective. The timing of intervention, on the other hand, is typically a function of the central bank’s ‘scenting’ of the presence of misalignment/disorderly conditions. Proximate indicators of market conditions turning disorderly are cited as accelerated changes in the exchange rate potentially driven by one-way bets; widening bid-offer spreads signaling heightened uncertainty; the composition of turnover – a rising ratio of interbank trades relative to customer-related turnover or ‘hot potato’ trading; volatility measured in several ways, including implied volatility and GARCH, though some tolerance to volatility is warranted if it co-exists with price discovery. Generally, these indicators are viewed in conjunction rather than in isolation. The central bank may set benchmarks for these indicators to enhance its capacity to respond. Considerable discretion is widely practiced on revealing intervention operations, with tactical ambiguity being the revealed preference among emerging markets (Chiu, 2003). Technical Aspects Surveys also offer valuable glimpses at various technical issues embedded in implementing the decision to intervene or not. They relate to the choice of markets, onshore or offshore, the intervention currency, choice of counterparties, and administration and governance aspects. A summary of central bank responses is set out below. -
Interventions generally take place in the spot market to benefit from liquid conditions and obtain direct effects on the spot exchange rate; forward markets involve transmission mechanisms that are affected by monetary conditions, whereas using derivatives could result in leveraged net open positions and margin calls can disrupt cash flows. -
Onshore markets where the bulk of trading takes place are normally preferred for intervention operations so as to directly impact order flows and exploit market intelligence as well; offshore interventions are undertaken only where the local currency trades significantly or beyond working hours offshore. -
Intervention is generally conducted in the most widely traded currency pair to reduce costs and facilitate settlement. The US dollar was reported as the most favoured intervention currency (AREAER, IMF, 2022)5. -
Typically, central banks prefer the wholesale market to the retail cash market for intervention operations to reap economies of scale that work towards reducing transaction costs. -
As regards counterparties, the choice is generally of financial institutions and authorized dealers which (a) are solvent, (b) provide competitive two-way quotes and are market makers, and (c) provide information on market developments. -
Close coordination between the foreign exchange market and money market desks is considered essential, with a clear decision-making hierarchy. The chain of command (it may involve a small committee, or a chief dealer being delegated decisions on amount of intervention subject to thresholds, consistent with the management tolerance limits, provided there are no principalagent problems), with the front office separated from middle/back offices. III. Some Stylised Facts Exchange rate management in India has undergone a major transformation since the implementation of structural reforms starting 1991. A brief transitional dual exchange rate arrangement instituted in March 1992 was followed by a market determined exchange rate system in March 1993, current account convertibility in August 1994 under Article VIII of the Articles of Agreement of the IMF, development of the forex market from the second half of the 1990s based on recommendations made by Sodhani Committee (1994) and Expert Group on the Foreign Exchange Markets (2005), and a gradual liberalisation of the capital account based on the recommendations of the Committee on Capital Account Convertibility (1997) and Committee on Fuller Capital Account Convertibility (2006). As a result, trading volumes have picked up, adding structure, depth and liquidity to the forex market. Subsequently, the derivatives segment has been deepened by removing segmentation between onshore and offshore markets for the INR. Indian banks have been allowed to undertake non-deliverable derivative contracts with each other as well as with customers. Non-residents have been given access to the INR Non-Deliverable Foreign Exchange Derivative Contract (NDDC) segment, irrespective of purpose. Market makers in India can now deal in forex market on a 24x5 basis. In fact, all regulatory barriers based on residence, entity, product, venue, and type of exposure have been removed to enable every economic entity to hedge its forex risks flexibily and efficiently. The size of the forex market has increased substantially over the years (chart 1). The RBI’s intervention in the foreign exchange market has been two-sided, driven by the objectives of smoothing excessive volatility, irrespective of its source (Table 1&2). It is observed that demand and supply conditions witness abrupt swings because of sudden and excessive movements in foreign portfolio investment (FPI). This is corroborated by a strong co-movement between FPI flows and the RBI’s interventions (Chart 2).  Table 1: Indian Rupee-US Dollar Exchange Rate and RBI’s Forex Intervention | Period | Exchange Rate at the end of the Period | Appreciation (-) /Depreciation (+) in per cent during the period | Volatility (Standard Deviation) | Net Forex Intervention (Purchase +/ Sales -) (US$ Bn) | Forex Purchase (US$ Bn) | Forex Sales (US$ Bn) | Jan 2006-Aug 2008 | 43.3 | -1.64 | 2.43 | 110 | 132 | 22 | Sep 2008-Oct 2009 | 46.9 | 7.78 | 1.37 | -32 | 15 | 47 | Jan 2010-Dec 2010 | 44.8 | -3.57 | 0.94 | 1.8 | 3.3 | 1.5 | Jan 2011-Dec 2011 | 53.0 | 15.49 | 3.11 | -13 | 0 | 13 | Jan 2012-Dec 2012 | 54.9 | 3.37 | 2.47 | -11 | 7 | 18 | Jan 2013-Dec 2013 | 61.9 | 11.40 | 4.22 | 4 | 51 | 47 | Jan 2014-Dec 2014 | 63.0 | 1.78 | 1.20 | 32 | 98 | 66 | Jan 2015-Dec 2015 | 66.2 | 4.76 | 1.72 | 37 | 84 | 48 | Jan 2016-Dec 2016 | 67.9 | 2.55 | 0.76 | 9 | 78 | 69 | Jan 2017-Dec 2017 | 63.8 | -6.41 | 1.10 | 28 | 46 | 18 | Jan 2018-Dec 2018 | 69.6 | 8.26 | 3.11 | -16 | 42 | 58 | Jan 2019-Dec 2019 | 71.4 | 2.49 | 1.05 | 40 | 60 | 19 | Jan 2020-Dec 2020 | 73.0 | 2.26 | 1.32 | 88 | 127 | 39 | Jan 2021-Dec 2021 | 74.4 | 1.86 | 0.86 | 33 | 159 | 126 | Jan 2022-Dec 2022 | 82.7 | 10.07 | 2.85 | -46 | 180 | 226 | Jan 2023-Dec 2023 | 83.2 | 0.56 | 0.57 | 18 | 185 | 167 | Jan 2024-Sep 2024 | 83.8 | 0.68 | 0.33 | 32 | 150 | 118 | Source: CEIC and RBI. | Table 2: Nature of Monthly Forex Intervention by RBI (Jan 2006 - Sept 2024) | | Net Intervention (Purchase +/ Sales -) | Purchase | Sale | Total Sample Months | 225 | 225 | 225 | Months of Intervention | 202 | 198 | 180 | % Intervention Months | 90 | 88 | 80 | Average Monthly Intervention (US$ mn) | 1569 | 7160 | 6115 | Max Intervention (US$ mn) | 18633 | 36650 | 38770 | Min Intervention (US$ mn) | -20101 | 25 | 25 | Source: RBI. | Episodes of heightened volatility have been observed during the global financial crisis of 2008-09, the taper tantrums of 2013, the (ILFS) crisis of 2018, then COVID-19 pandemic, the Russia-Ukraine conflict and more recently, from early 2022 to late 2023 due to spillovers from synchronised monetary tightening around the world, the banking crisis of March 2023, the unwinding of yen-carry trade in August 2024 and fears of recession in September 2024. In the second half of 2024, judicious interventions have ensured that the Indian Rupee (INR) has experienced less volatility than other major currencies, despite the unrelenting pressure from a surging US dollar (Chart 3) and sustained outward flights of FPIs. IV. Empirical Results Since our objective is to investigate the efficacy of RBI’s interventions, we carry out two sets of analyses using monthly data from January 2014 till September 2024. First, we examine the impact of interventions in countering the impact of capital flows in an auto regressive distributed lag (ARDL) model that is specified in terms of the changes in the level of the INR/USD: 
 where, der is monthly change in the INR/USD exchange rate (in per cent). A positive value of der is synonymous with depreciation of INR/USD and vice versa. Since the exchange rate changes are expected to exhibit persistence due to hysteresis (Baldwin, 1988; Campa, 2004), the lagged values of der are included in (1). X is a vector of explanatory variables controlling for (i) net FPI flows (debt and equity are also examined separately); (ii) an interaction term – Net FPI x Net interventions (spot and forward interventions are considered separately, as also spot purchases and sales); (iii) inflation differentials (CPI headline inflation in India minus CPI headline inflation in the US), assuming purchasing power parity or PPP; and (iv) the difference between the weighted average call money rate in India and the effective US Fed Fund rate to represent uncovered interest parity (UIP). In the second stage, the impact of forex interventions on exchange rate volatility is examined. The mean equation in (1) is augmented with volatility equations (2) and (3) – a GARCH model with different specifications (Dominguez,1993 and Broto, 2013): gross forex intervention (purchases plus sales) in a month, which captures the volume affect; and the nonlinear effects of gross interventions in the form of a squared term. The results indicate that an increase in net FPI inflows leads to INR appreciation and vice versa. Both debt and equity portfolio flows are found to be statistically significant in the same direction. Inflation differentials and interest rate differentials are not statistically significant (Table 3) – neither PPP nor UIP holds in short-run in Indian conditions. The coefficient of the interaction term (net FPI x net Intervention)6 is positive and statistically significant, opposing the negative and significant impact of net FPI flows term and indicating that forex intervention, both purchases and sales, effectively weaken the impact of capital flows on the exchange rate. These coefficients are also found to be statistically not different from one another7, which suggests no asymmetry in the impact of forex purchases and sales on the exchange rate. The coefficient of the interaction term between forward market interventions and net FPI is also positive and statistically significant, indicating that forward market interventions8 also reduce the impact of FPI flows on exchange rate changes. The US VIX has a positive and statistically significant impact on exchange rate volatility, indicating that heightened global uncertainty accentuates exchange rate volatility in India. The impact of the gross spot intervention, on the other hand, is statistically significant and negative, implying that interventions curb exchange rate volatility, confirming the results from (1) to (4) in Table 3. The relationship is non-linear as shown by the positive and statistically significant impact of the squared term, suggesting the existence of threshold effects and explaining the “leaning against the wind” phenomenon. Table 3: Regression Estimates: Dependent Variable is Changes in INR/USD | Exogenous Variables | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | Mean Equation | Inflation differential (-1) | 0.023 | 0.003 | 0.015 | 0.049 | (-) 0.024 | -0.023 | | (0.672) | (0.965) | (0.765) | (0.387) | (0.734) | (0.748) | Interest rate differential (-1) | 0.001 | 0.017 | 0.032 | (-) 0.020 | 0.010 | 0.013 | | (0.975) | (0.722) | (0.448) | (0.652) | (0.830) | (0.771) | Net FPI inflows | (-) 0.151*** | | (-) 0.206*** | (-) 0.121*** | (-) 0.108*** | (-) 0.112*** | | (0.000) | | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | (0.000) | Net FPI inflows (Equity) | | (-) 0.119*** | | | | | | | (0.002) | | | | | Net FPI inflows (Debt) | | (-) 0.209*** | | | | | | | (0.002) | | | | | Net FPI x Net Intervention Spot | 0.007** | 0.007** | | | | | | (0.023) | (0.018) | | | | | Net FPI x Spot Purchases# | | | 0.005** | | | | | | | (0.047) | | | | Net FPI x Spot Sales^ | | | 0.008*** | | | | | | | (0.001) | | | | Net FPI x Outstanding Forwards | | | | 0.015*** | | | | | | | (0.000) | | | Constant | 0.281 | 0.276 | 0.194 | 0.291* | 0.433** | 0.412** | | (0.130) | (0.144) | (0.259) | (0.091) | (0.014) | (0.020) | AR (-1) | 0.030 | 0.039 | (-) 0.027 | 0.121 | (-) 0.009 | (-) 0.032 | | (0.721) | (0.670) | (0.764) | (0.220) | (0.925) | (0.740) | AR (-2) | (-) 0.066 | (-) 0.048 | (-) 0.091 | (-) 0.137 | (-) 0.075 | (-) 0.099 | | (0.516) | (0.668) | (0.359) | (0.198) | (0.436) | (0.290) | Volatility Equation | ARCH (-1) | | | | | (-) 0.088* | (-) 0.114** | | | | | | (0.054) | (0.017) | ARCH (-2) | | | | | 0.036 | 0.073 | | | | | | (0.826) | (0.626) | GARCH (-1) | | | | | 0.239 | 0.319** | | | | | | (0.388) | (0.034) | US VIX | | | | | 0.052** | 0.050** | | | | | | (0.042) | (0.034) | Gross Intervention | | | | | (-) 0.569*** | (-) 4.690*** | Spot | | | | | (0.009) | (0.000) | Gross Intervention | | | | | | 0.219*** | Spot^2 | | | | | | (0.000) | Constant | | | | | 4.142** | 23.318*** | | | | | | (0.028) | (0.000) | Portmanteau test for white noise of residuals (p-value) | 0.243 | 0.166 | 0.792 | 0.517 | 0.486 | 0.510 | Note: p-values in parentheses are based on robust standard errors; *p<0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01; AR: Auto Regressive; ARCH: Auto Regressive Conditional Heteroscedastic; GARCH: Generalized ARCH. #: The interaction term is generated in those months where there are net purchases, otherwise kept zero. ^: The interaction term is generated in those months where there are net sales, otherwise kept zero. Source: Authors’ estimates | V. Conclusion Several emerging market economies (EMEs) have opted for market-determined exchange rates – broadly classified as managed floats in de jure terms – to reap the equilibrating properties of freer exchange rates movements in the context of balance of payments disquilibria. The experience with floating exchange rates the world over has, however, been quite the converse, marked by idiosyncratic movements, overshoots hysteresis and several generations of currency crises, with adverse implications for domestic real economic activity. Hence, EMEs and even several advanced economies (AEs) have employed foreign exchange interventions to curb excessive exchange rate volatility and thereby prevent macroeconomic and financial stability risks from materialising. These interventions assume policy relevance, especially when net international investment positions are negative and when imports are a significant component of consumer prices. In this context, it has been acknowledged that marrying foreign exchange interventions with inflation targeting has significantly strengthened EMEs macroeconomic policy framework (BIS, 2019). This has also led to the recognition of such interventions as a legitimate instrument in the macroeconomic toolkit of EMEs [IMF, 2016; Adler et al., (2016)]. The results of the empirical analysis presented here shows that with the progressive liberalisation of current and capital transactions, the Indian economy has experienced bouts of exchange rate volatility, with destabilising consequences for real activity. It is the volatility of portfolio flows induced by risk-on-risk-off sentiments, mainly on account of global spillovers, that is the source of exchange rate volatility rather than differentials in inflation or interest rates. Foreign exchange interventions, both spot and forward, effectively counter capital flows volatility, with symmetric effects of purchases and sales. We also detect threshold effects of forex interventions. Throwing sand in the wheels to dampen the exchange rate volatility is more effective than attempts to influence the level of the exchange through large interventions. This finding has important implications for the conduct of exchange rate policy in countries like India. References Adler G, N Lisack & R C Mano (2019), Unveiling the effects of foreign exchange intervention: A panel approach, Emerging Markets Review, Volume 40. Adler G., K S Chang & Wang, Zijiao. (2021) Patterns of foreign exchange intervention under inflation targeting, Latin American Journal of Central Banking, Volume 2, Issue 4. Adler G, R. Lama & J.P.Medina (2016), Foreign Exchange Intervention under Policy Uncertainty, IMF Working Paper, WP/16/67. Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions, 2022, IMF. Baldwin, R. E. (1988). Some Empirical Evidence on Hysteresis in Aggregate Us Import Prices. NBER Working Paper, (w2483). Beattie N & J F Fillion (1999). An intraday analysis of the effectiveness of foreign exchange intervention, Bank of Canada Working Paper 99-4. Blanchard O, G Adler & I de C Filho, (2015), Can Foreign Exchange Intervention Stem Exchange Rate Pressures from Global Capital Flow Shocks? IMF Working Paper, WP/15/159. Broto, C. (2013). The effectiveness of forex interventions in four Latin American countries. Emerging Markets Review, 17, 224-240. Blejer M I & L Schumachar (1998), Central Bank Vulnerability and the Credibility of Commitments, A value-at-risk approach to Currency Crisis, IMF Working Paper, WP/98/65. Bordo M.D. & P L Siklos (2015), Central Bank Credibility Before and After the Crisis, NBER Working Paper, No. Working Paper 21710. Boyer, Russell S., 1978, Optimal Foreign Exchange Intervention, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 86 (December), pp. 1045–1055. Buiter, W., 1979, Optimal Foreign Exchange Intervention with Rational Expectations. in Trade and Payments Adjustment under Flexible Exchange Rates, ed. by J. Martin and A. Smith (London: Macmillan). Buiter , W. H. (1979), Feedback and the Use of Current Information: The Use of General Linear Policy Rules in Rational Expectations Models, NBER Working Paper, No. 335. Calvo GA & CM Reinhart (2002). Fear of floating, The Quarterly journal of economics, me 117, Issue 2, May 2002, Pages 379-408. Campa, J. M. (2004). Exchange rates and trade: How important is hysteresis in trade? European Economic Review, 48(3), 527-548. Canales-Kriljenko J I, R Guimaraes & C Karakadaco (2003). Official Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market: Elements of Best Practice, IMF Working Paper, WP 03/152. Chang R. & A. Velasco (1999). Liquidity Crises in Emerging Markets: Theory and Policy. NBER Macroeconomics Annual ,Volume 14. Chiu P (2003). Transparency Versus Constructive Ambiguity in Foreign Exchange Intervention, BIS Working Paper No. 144. Dominguez, K. M. (1998). Central bank intervention and exchange rate volatility. Journal of International Money and Finance, 17(1), 161-190. Daude C, E L Yeyati & A Nagengast (2016), On the effectiveness of Exchange Rae Interventions in emerging markets, Journal of International Money and Finance, Volume 64, Pages 239-261. Domac I. & A. Mendoza (2002), Is there room for forex interventions under inflation targeting framework? Evidence from Mexico and Turkey, CBRT Discussion Papers, 2002. Dominguez, K. M. (1993), Does Central Bank Intervention Increase the Volatility of Foreign Exchange Rates? National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 4532. Dominguez, K. M. & J. A. Frankel. (1993) Does Foreign Exchange Intervention Work? Institute for International Economics, Washington, D. C. Dominguez, K. (1998). Central Bank intervention and exchange rate volatility. Journal of International Money and Finance, 18, 161–190. Evans MDD & R K Lyons (2002). Order Flow and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 110, no. 1. Filardo A, G. Gelos, & T McGregor (2022), Exchange-Rate Swings and Foreign Currency Intervention, IMF Working Paper, WP/22/158. Foreign Exchange Market Organisation: Selected Issues (2003) Chapter IV, IMF e-Library. Fratzscher M., O. Gloede, L. Menkhoff, L.Sarno, & T. Stöhr (2019), When Is Foreign Exchange Intervention Effective? Evidence from 33 Countries, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2019, 11(1): 132–156. Galan M., J. D G D Castillo & A.G. Tames (1997). A strategy to accumulate reserves through options to sell dollars, Unpublished manuscript. Goldstein, M. (2002). Managed floating plus: the great currency regime debate, Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC. Hooyman C. J. (1994), The Use of Foreign Exchange Swaps by Central Banks, Volume 41, Pages 149-162. Hung J.H.(1997), The Exchange Rate’s Impact on Overseas Profits of U.S. Multinationals, Journal of Economics and Business, Volume 49, Issue 5, Pages 439-458. International Capital Market Report, (1998), Reserve Impact of Forward Foreign Exchange Intervention, Box 2.11, International Monetary Fund. Ito, T., (2003). Is foreign exchange intervention effective? The Japanese experiences in the 1990s. In: Mizen, P. (Ed.), Monetary History, Exchange Rates and Financial Markets, Essays in Honour of Charles Goodhart. Edward Elgar Pub, Cheltenham, U.K. Jones, Michael, (1984). “Optimal Foreign exchange intervention: Evidence from the Bretton Woods Era,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 66, pp. 242–55, IMF Working Papers 2003, 152. Lai A. (2002). Modelling Financial Instability: A Survey of the Literature. Bank of Canada Working Paper 2002-12. Linde J., P. Schneider, N. Suphaphiphat & H.Wang (2024). Foreign Exchange Intervention under Integrated Policy Framework: The Case of India, IMF WP/24/236. Lyons R. K. (2001). The Microstructure Approach to Exchange Rates. MIT Press. Mandeng M. O. (2003). Central bank foreign exchange market intervention and option contract specification: the case of Colombia, IMF working paper WP/03/135. Mark N C & D. Sul (2001). Nominal exchange rates and monetary fundamentals: Evidence from a small post-Bretton woods panel, Journal of International Economics, Volume 53, Issue 1, Pages 29-52. Market volatility and foreign exchange intervention in EMEs: what has changed?, (2013) Monetary and Economic Department, BIS Papers No. 73. Menkhoff, L. (2010). High-Frequency Analysis of Foreign Exchange Interventions: What Do We Learn?, Journal of Economic Surveys, 24, 1, 85-112. Menkhoff L. (2013). Foreign Exchange Intervention in Emerging Markets: A Survey of Empirical Studies, The World Economy, Vol 36, Issue 9, Menkhoff L, Malte Rieth & Tobias Stohr, (2021). The Dynamic Impact of FX Interventions on Financial Markets, The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, vol. 103(5), pages 939-953. Monetary policy frameworks in EMEs: inflation targeting, the exchange rate and financial stability, BIS Annual Economic Report, 2019. Mulder MCB & MM Bussier (1999). External Vulnerability in Emerging Market Economies: How High liquidity can offset weak fundamentals and the effects of contagion, IMF working paper WP/99/88. Neely, C. J. (2001). The Practice of Central Bank Intervention: looking under the hood, Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Vol. 83, pages 1-10. Neely C.J. (2008). Central bank authorities’ beliefs about foreign exchange intervention, Journal of International Money and Finance, 27 (2008) 1-25. Nochetti D. (2006). Central Bank’s Value-at- Risk and Financial Crises: An Application to the 2001 Argentine Crisis, Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. 9, Issue 2. Obstfeld, M (1990), The effectiveness of foreign exchange intervention: Recent experience, 1985-1988, International Policy Coordination and Exchange Rate Fluctuations, W.H. Branson, J.A. Frankel, & M. Goldstein , University Chicago Press, ISBN:0-226-07141-3. Ormos M & D.Timotity (2016). Market microstructure during financial crisis: Dynamics of informed and heuristic-driven trading, Finance Research Letters, 19, 60–66. Patra M. D., H. Behera, D. Gajbhiye, S Kundu & R Suroy (2024) A Suite of Approaches for Estimating Equilibrium Exchange Rates for India, RBI Bulletin, November. RBI (1997). Report of the committee on capital account convertibility. RBI (2006). Report of the Committee on Fuller Capital Account Convertibility. Report of the Expert Group on Foreign Exchange Markets in India (Chairman: O. P. Sodhani), 1995. Report of the Expert Group on the Foreign Exchange Markets, RBI, 2005. Rogoff K., (1999). Monetary Models of Dollar/Yen/ Euro Nominal Exchange Rates: Dead or Undead?, The Economic Journal, Vol. 109, No. 459. Roper, Don E., and Stephen J. Turnovsky, 1980, Optimal Exchange Market Intervention in a Simple Stochastic Macro Model, Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 13, pp. 296-309. Sarno L. & M P Taylor (2001). Official Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market: Is it Effective and, if so, How does it work? Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 39, No. 3, Sarno L. & M.P. Taylor (2002). Purchasing Power Parity and the Real Exchange Rate, IMF Staff Papers, Vol.49. Vitale, P. (2011). The impact of FX intervention on FX markets: a market microstructure analysis, International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol 16, Issue 1. Zapatero F. & L.F. Reverter (2003). Exchange Rate Intervention with Options, Journal of International Money and Finance, Volume 22, Issue 2, Pages 289-306. Zeuli M (2013). Value-at-Risk Approach to Currency Crises: A Brazilian Example With the Central Bank and Currency Based Assets, Chinese Business Review, 2013, Vol. 12, No. 9, 593-609. |