Respected Vice-Chancellor Professor Simhadri,
Professor Bhanoji Rao, Professor K.C. Reddy, and fellow-members of Andhra Pradesh
Economic Association. I am thankful to the organisers for inviting me to be
the President and deliver the Presidential Address. There are several reasons
for my being keen to be in Visakhapatnam to deliver the Presidential Address.
I commenced my career in Government of Andhra Pradesh in Visakhapatnam as Assistant
Collector Under Training over forty years ago - in 1965. I had the benefit of
professional guidance from eminent scholars and economists in Andhra University
such as Professors Sarveswara Rao garu, D.V. Ramana garu, G. Parthasarathy garu,
K.V. Ramana garu and S. Chandrasekhar garu. Subsequently, I acquired many friends
with strong links here, such as Professors Krishnamurthy garu and R. Radhakrishna
garu. Professor Bhanoji Rao garu has been a valued friend, whether he was in
the World Bank with me, or in Singapore or in the Administrative Staff College
in Hyderabad. Professor K.C. Reddy garu worked alongside me when I was the Secretary
in Planning and Finance Department of the Government of Andhra Pradesh. With
all these attractions, I regret to say that I am not able to be physically present
in Visakhapatnam to deliver the Presidential Address at the 23rd Annual Conference
due to unavoidable official commitments.
The Andhra Pradesh Economic Association has
been one of the pioneering efforts in our country in organising a sub-national
level professional body of economists. I have no doubt that it is a wise initiative
and needs to be carried forward. As the economic reform in India progresses,
the relative balance in public policy would shift in favour of the states relative
to the centre. The important areas earmarked for the centre, such as external
sector and financial sector, tend to be subjected to globalisation while in
areas such as education, health, sanitation, roads, water works, power, etc.
which are localized in nature, states could have a greater role. Greater marketisation
of economies and private capital flows tend to look for conducive governance
at the state-level where economic activities are located. Hence, the state governments
are well advised to take dynamic policy-initiatives and it is in this background
that the economists engaged at the state level have to play a crucial role in
the reform-process. In fact, there is some evidence of a positive link between
education health and other public services and economic growth. Interestingly,
most states which have done well in terms of investment and growth also have
research institutes of repute in the area of social and economic sciences.
Needless to say that, in this background, I
am delighted to deliver the Presidential Address at the Annual Conference of
Andhra Pradesh Economic Association. In a conference of economists, it is appropriate
to go by the principle of comparative advantage, and accordingly I decided to
focus my comments on the core of my current professional as well as official
preoccupation and talk on the monetary policy.
In its conduct of monetary policy, the central
bank responds to the evolving economic activity within an articulated monetary
policy framework. This framework would normally have three basic constituents,
viz.,
- the objectives of monetary policy;
- the analytics of monetary policy focusing on the transmission
mechanism; and
- the operating procedure focusing on operating targets and
instruments.
For convenience, each of these issues has been
dealt with separately and in this light, the Indian experience has been touched
upon briefly.
Objectives
Traditionally, central banks have pursued the
twin objectives of price stability and growth. Central banks have to keep in
view the considerations of exchange rate stability and financial stability also
in pursuing the basic objectives. Can we achieve these objectives all at a time?
As in most aspects of life, the objectives of monetary policy are interrelated,
and there are trade-offs as well. Illustratively, economists often talk of the
Phillips curve according to which there is a short-run negative relation between
inflation and unemployment. While there are various viewpoints on Phillips curve,
in a world where the Phillips curve is valid, a central bank can reduce inflation
only at the cost of having more unemployment. Similar trade-offs exist among
other objectives as well.
Faced with multiple objectives that are equally
desirable, there remains the problem of assigning to each policy instrument
the most appropriate objective. Accordingly, there is a broad consensus, both
in academic and policy circles, that monetary policy is useful as an instrument
to achieving the goal of price stability.
The adoption of price stability as the only
objective of monetary policy is, however, by no means universal. While a number
of prominent central banks including the European Central Bank, Bank of England
and Bank of Japan have adopted price stability as the single objective of monetary
policy, the Federal Reserve of the US continues to pursue multiple objectives
of monetary policy, viz., a) maximum employment, b) stable prices, and
c) moderate long-term interest rates. Central banks in several developing countries
have placed exchange rate management as another important policy objective.
In recent years, particularly after the financial crises of 1990s, the concern
for financial stability is an integral part of the central bank’s activism.
Analytics of Monetary Policy
The process through which changes in the monetary
policy get transmitted to the ultimate objectives like inflation or growth has
come to be known as "monetary transmission mechanism". Interestingly,
economists often refer to the channels of "monetary transmission"
as a black box – implying that we know that monetary policy does influence output
and inflation but we do not know for certain how precisely it does so. Nevertheless,
in the literature, a number of transmission channels have been identified: (a)
the quantum channel (e.g., relating to money supply and credit); (b) the interest
rate channel; (c) the exchange rate channel; and (d) the asset price channel.
How these channels function in a given economy depends on the stage of development
of the economy and its underlying financial structure. Illustratively,
in an open economy one would expect the exchange rate channel to be important;
similarly, in an economy where banks are the major source of finance (as against
the capital market), credit channel seems to be a major conduit for monetary
transmission. Besides, it needs to be noted that these channels are not mutually
exclusive – in fact, there could be considerable feedbacks and interactions
among them.
Central banks may not be in a position to directly
achieve their ultimate objectives and hence, monetary policy is often formulated
in terms of an intermediate target. For example, in a monetary targeting framework,
a suitable monetary aggregate is considered as an intermediate target based
on the basic relationship between money, output and prices. Exchange rate as
an intermediate target can be suitable for small open economies, setting the
exchange rate against a low-inflation anchor country. This may, however, entail
loss of independence in steering domestic interest rates.
In this context, it is necessary to touch upon
what is known as the ‘impossible trinity’, or ‘trilemma’ of monetary policy.
This refers to the incompatibility among three policy choices, viz.,
(a) fixed exchange rate, (b) open capital account, and (c) independent monetary
policy. The basic message of the ‘trilemma’ is that a central bank can achieve
any two of the above-mentioned parameters, but not all the three. Illustratively,
if a country wants to have fixed exchange rate and independent monetary policy
then it is difficult to maintain an open capital account.
Another important issue in monetary policy is
the extent of transparency. Central bankers all over the world are not exactly
known for clarity in their language. Nevertheless, the rational expectations
school in macroeconomics holds that no policy can be successful over a period
by "fooling" the economic agents. In this context, one may differentiate
between genuine uncertainties about the future vis-à-vis not revealing
the expected outcome of the policy. In fact, since the 1990s, there has been
a preference all over the world to improve the transparency of monetary policy.
In the context of improving transparency, the
recent trend has been towards direct inflation targeting. Adoption of explicit
inflation targeting as the final goal of monetary policy involves the preparation
of an inflation forecast, which, in a way, serves the purpose of both an intermediate
target and final objective. The pre-requisites for inflation targeting include
a considerable degree of operational autonomy or independence for central bank,
flexible exchange rate conditions, well-developed financial markets and absence
of fiscal dominance.
In view of the growing complexities of macroeconomic
management, several central banks including the European Central Bank have placed
reliance on a broad set of economic and leading indicators rather than focusing
exclusively on an intermediate target or a direct inflation target. The Federal
Reserve has traditionally been following a more broad based approach to the
conduct of monetary policy in the US.
Operating Procedures: Instruments and Targets
Operating procedures refer to the day-to-day
implementation of monetary policy by central banks through various instruments.
These instruments can be broadly classified into direct and indirect instruments.
Typically, direct instruments include required cash and/ or liquidity reserve
ratios, directed credit and administered interest rates. Cash reserve ratio
(CRR) determines the level of reserves (central bank money or cash) banks need
to hold against their liabilities. Similarly, liquidity reserve ratio requires
banks to maintain a part of their liabilities in the form of liquid assets (e.g.,
government securities). Credit and interest rate directives take the form of
prescribed targets for allocation of credit to preferred sectors/industries
and prescription of deposit and lending rates.
The indirect instruments generally operate through
price channel which cover repurchase (repos) and outright transactions in securities
(open market operations), standing facilities (refinance) and market-based discount
window. For example, if the central bank desires to inject liquidity for a short
period, it could do so by providing funds to the banks in exchange of securities
at a desired interest rate, reversing the transaction at a pre-determined time.
Similarly, if the central bank desires to influence liquidity on an enduring
basis, it could resort to open market operations (OMO), involving outright purchase
(or sale) of securities.
While OMO including repo transactions operate
at the discretion of the central bank, standing facilities provide limited liquidity
which could be accessed by the eligible market participants (generally banks)
at their discretion. Market-based discount window makes available reserves either
through direct lending or through rediscounting or purchase of financial assets
held by banks.
In practice, the choice between direct and indirect
instruments is not easy. While direct instruments are effective, they are considered
inefficient in terms of their impact on the financial market. On the other hand,
the use and efficacy of indirect instruments depends on the extent of development
of the supporting financial markets and institutions. These instruments are
usually directed at attaining a prescribed value of the operating target. Central
banks typically adopt either (a) bank reserves or (b) a very short-term interest
rate (usually the overnight inter-bank rate) as the operating target.
The optimal choice between price and quantity
targets would depend on the sources of disturbances in the goods and money markets.
In reality, it often becomes difficult to trace out the sources of instability.
Hence, monetary policy is implemented by fixing, at least over some short time
interval, the value of an operating target. In a single-period context, the
choice of the level of the target amounts to setting a rule for monetary policy.
However, in a dynamic context, their connection is less straightforward. Indeed,
a deviation from a target could occur, either intended or unintended, which
may impart an inflationary bias when monetary policy is conducted with discretion.
In order to address such problems of dynamic inconsistency, rule-based solutions
are emphasized in literature, e.g., monetary rule (changes in money supply at
a pre-determined rate) and Taylor-type rule (changes in interest rate based
on deviation of growth and inflation from their potential/desired levels). While
a rule-based system imparts transparency, providing certainty about future policy
response, it becomes ineffective in its response to unanticipated shocks given
its inflexibility. In practice, therefore, central banks follow an approach
of what has been best described as constrained discretion.
The operating procedures of monetary policy
of most central banks have largely converged to one of the following three variants:
(i) estimate the demand for bank reserves and then carry out open market operations
to target short-term interest rates; (ii) estimate market liquidity and carry
out open market operations to target the bank reserves, while allowing interest
rates to adjust; and (iii) modulate monetary conditions in terms of both the
quantum and price of liquidity, through a mix of open market operations, standing
facilities and minimum reserve requirement and changes in the policy rate with
the objective of containing overnight market interest rate within a narrow corridor
of interest rate targets.
Indian Specifics
In this backdrop, let me now turn to the conduct
of monetary policy in India.
What has been the objective of Indian monetary
policy? The preamble to the Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934 sets out the objectives
of the Bank as "to regulate the issue of Bank notes and the keeping of
reserves with a view to securing monetary stability in India and generally to
operate the currency and credit system of the country to its advantage".
Although there is no explicit mandate for price stability, as is the current
trend in many countries, the objectives of monetary policy in India have evolved
as those of maintaining price stability and ensuring adequate flow of credit
to the productive sectors of the economy. In essence, monetary policy aims to
maintain a judicious balance between price stability and economic growth. The
relative emphasis between price stability and economic growth is governed by
the prevailing circumstances in a particular time and is spelt out from time
to time in the policy announcements of the Reserve Bank.
Of late, considerations of financial stability
have assumed greater importance in view of increasing openness of the Indian
economy and financial reforms. In the Indian context, financial stability could
be interpreted to embrace three aspects, viz., (a) ensuring uninterrupted
financial transactions, (b) maintenance of a level of confidence in the financial
system amongst all the participants and stakeholders, and (c) absence of excess
volatility that unduly and adversely affects real economic activity. It is the
endeavour of the Reserve Bank to ensure all these aspects of financial stability.
As far as the conduct of monetary policy is
concerned, it may be noted that monetary policy in India used to be conducted
till 1997-98 with broad money (M3) as an intermediate target. The
aim was to regulate money supply consistent with two parameters, viz.,
(a) the expected growth in real income, and (b) a projected level of inflation.
On the basis of estimates of these two crucial parameters, the targeted monetary
expansion could be set. In practice, the monetary targeting framework was used
in a flexible manner with feedback from developments in the real sector. However,
questions were raised about the appropriateness of such a framework with the
changing inter-relationship between money, output and prices in the wake of
financial sector reforms and opening up of the economy. The Working Group on
Money Supply (1998) sought to address some of these issues. The most significant
observation of the Group was regarding the changing nature of transmission mechanism
as it highlighted that the interest rate channel was gaining in importance.
In line with this thinking, since 1998-99, the
Reserve Bank has switched over to a multiple indicator approach. As per this
approach, interest rates or rates of return in different markets (money, capital
and government securities markets), along with data such as on currency, credit
extended by banks and financial institutions, fiscal position, trade, capital
flows, inflation rate, exchange rate, refinancing and transactions in foreign
exchange available on high-frequency basis, are juxtaposed with output for drawing
policy perspectives.
What is the operating procedure of monetary
policy in India? In the current monetary policy framework, with growing inter-linkages
in the financial market, reliance on direct instruments has been reduced and
liquidity management in the system is carried out through OMO in the form of
outright purchases/sales of government securities and daily reverse repo and
repo operations under Liquidity Adjustment Facility (LAF). The LAF has enabled
the Reserve Bank to modulate short-term liquidity under varied financial market
conditions, including large capital inflows from abroad. In addition, it has
enabled the Reserve Bank to set a corridor for the short-term interest rates
consistent with the policy objectives. This has also facilitated bringing down
the CRR of banks without engendering liquidity pressure. These operations are
supplemented by access to the Reserve Bank’s standing facilities. In this new
operating environment, changes in reverse repo and/or the Bank Rate have emerged
as interest rate signals.
There is no explicit interest rate target envisaged
in India. Nevertheless, a great deal of reliance has been placed in recent years
on interest rates and exchange rates in the day-to-day conduct of monetary policy.
In the context of increasing openness of the economy and a market-determined
exchange rate, the large capital inflows witnessed in recent years have posed
major challenges to the conduct of monetary and exchange rate management. A
critical issue in this regard is a view on whether the capital flows are temporary
or permanent in nature. The recent episode of large capital flows prompted a
debate in India on the need for exchange rate adjustment. In a scenario of uncertainty
facing the monetary authorities in determining temporary or permanent nature
of inflows, it is prudent to presume that such flows are temporary till they
are firmly established to be of permanent nature.
The liquidity impact of large inflows was managed
till the year 2003-04, largely through the day-to-day LAF and OMO. In the process,
the stock of government securities available with the Reserve Bank declined
progressively and the burden of sterilization increasingly fell on LAF operations.
In order to address these issues, the Reserve Bank signed in March 2004, a memorandum
of understanding (MoU) with the Government of India for issuance of Treasury
Bills and dated government securities under the Market Stabilisation Scheme
(MSS). The intention of MSS is essentially to differentiate the liquidity absorption
of a more enduring nature by way of sterilisation from the day-to-day normal
liquidity management operations. The ceiling on the outstanding obligations
of the Government under MSS has been initially indicated but is subject to revision
through mutual consultation. The issuances under MSS are matched by an equivalent
cash balance held by the Government in a separate identifiable cash account
maintained and operated by the Reserve Bank. The operationalisation of MSS to
absorb liquidity of more enduring nature has considerably reduced the burden
of sterilisation on the LAF window.
In its monetary operations, the Reserve Bank
uses multiple instruments to ensure that appropriate liquidity is maintained
in the system so that all legitimate requirements of credit are met, consistent
with the objective of price stability. Towards this end, the Bank pursues a
policy of active management of liquidity through OMO including LAF, MSS and
CRR, and using the policy instruments at its disposal flexibly, as and when
the situation warrants.
Way Ahead
Conduct of monetary policy is complex. It has
not only to be forward looking but also to grapple with uncertain future. Additional
complexities arise in the case of an emerging market like India, which is transiting
from a relatively closed to a progressively open economy. In an environment
of increasing capital flows, narrowing cross-border interest rate differentials
and surplus liquidity conditions, exchange rate movement tends to have linkages
with interest rate movements. The challenge of a monetary authority is to balance
the various choices into a coherent whole and to formulate a policy as an art
of the possible.
Let me now conclude by wishing this Conference
all success.