1. Introduction
II.1. In recent years, inflation in India has been
amongst the highest within the G-20. Household
inflation expectations have risen sharply and have
remained at elevated levels, unhinged from the low
inflation experience of 2000-07 as also from the global
inflation record (Table II.1). Professional forecasters’
surveys show that the long-term inflation expectations
have risen by about 150 basis points during this period
(Charts II.1 and II.2).
II.2. The consequences can be far reaching. First,
with high and persistent inflation, real interest rates
have remained negative for savers during most of the
post-global crisis period leading to a decline in
domestic financial saving. Second, since India’s
inflation has persisted at a level higher than that of
trading partners, external competitiveness is getting
eroded. If the nominal exchange rate adjusts to offset
the inflation differential it can set off a depreciationinflation spiral, thereby undermining macroeconomic stability1. Third, as the recent experience
demonstrated, the large demand for gold as a hedge
against inflation exacerbated the decline in financial
savings and contributed to a widening of the current
account deficit (CAD), rendering the economy
vulnerable to external shocks. Fourth, the consequent
weakening of the exchange rate has imposed balance sheet risks on borrowers in foreign currency with the
potential for financial instability. Fifth, persistently
high inflation adversely impacts the economy’s
allocative efficiency and impedes growth2. Sixth, high
and persistent inflation contributes to a worsening
of income distribution as the poor use
disproportionately higher cash-in-hand as part of their
savings.

Table II.1: Cross-Country Inflation Comparison |
(Per cent y-o-y) |
|
2000-07 |
2008 |
2009 |
2010 |
2011 |
2012 |
2008-12 |
I. Global Inflation (CPI) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
World |
3.9 |
6.0 |
2.5 |
3.6 |
4.8 |
4.0 |
4.2 |
EMEs |
6.7 |
9.2 |
5.3 |
5.9 |
7.1 |
6.1 |
6.7 |
BRICS (excluding India) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Brazil |
7.3 |
5.7 |
4.9 |
5.0 |
6.6 |
5.4 |
5.5 |
Russia |
14.2 |
14.1 |
11.7 |
6.9 |
8.4 |
5.1 |
9.2 |
China |
1.7 |
5.9 |
-0.7 |
3.3 |
5.4 |
2.7 |
3.3 |
South Africa |
5.3 |
11.5 |
7.1 |
4.3 |
5.0 |
5.7 |
6.7 |
II. Inflation in India |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Consumer Price Index – Industrial Workers |
4.5 |
9.1 |
12.4 |
10.4 |
8.4 |
10.4 |
10.1 |
Wholesale Price Index |
5.2 |
8.1 |
3.8 |
9.6 |
8.9 |
7.4 |
7.5 |
Wholesale Price Index -Food |
3.8 |
8.9 |
14.6 |
11.1 |
7.2 |
9.3 |
10.2 |
Wholesale Price Index –Non Food Manufactured Products |
4.3 |
5.7 |
0.2 |
6.1 |
7.3 |
4.9 |
4.8 |
Note: Indian inflation pertains to financial year (April-March).
Source: World Economic Outlook, IMF; RBI (for India). |

II.3. Drawing from the lessons of the global
financial crisis, there is a consensus gathering
internationally that monetary policy should move
away from its narrow focus on inflation towards a
multiple target-multiple instrument approach without
swerving from a commitment to price stability over
the medium term. This emerging consensus, however,
is reflected primarily in the form of institutionalising greater flexibility in the prevailing monetary policy
frameworks rather than an explicit regime overhaul.
The Committee recognises the evolving global
thinking on the subject. Yet, given the initial
conditions facing India at the current juncture,
bringing down inflation must be accorded primacy.
Anchored inflation expectations will then provide the
latitude to address other objectives without
compromising on price stability.
2. Choice of Nominal Anchor
II.4. A transparent and predictable policy
framework is, almost by definition, rule-based. Central
to a credible framework is a nominal anchor. Whether
fixed or moving, it ties down the final goal of monetary
policy and/or its path in the medium-to long-term,
and the expectations of economic agents adjust
accordingly. By acting as a constraint on policy
discretion, a nominal anchor disincentivises time
inconsistency3, including due to pressures from
interest groups.
II.5. Broadly, three types of nominal anchors have
been recorded, at least in recent history (Appendix
Table II.1). The exchange rate, arguably the oldest one
and an example of a fixed anchor in its original form,
faces diminishing practitioner appeal today as it
entails a loss of independence of monetary policy in
the pursuit of national objectives, and exposes the
economy to external shocks, particularly those
emanating from the anchor economy. Furthermore, as currency crises have repeatedly shown, an exchange
rate anchor makes the monetary policy framework
vulnerable to speculative attacks and consequent
financial instability.
II.6 Monetary aggregates have also served as
nominal anchors, but they have been undermined by
instability and loss of predictability of the demand
for money, discrediting accountability and
communication when targets are missed.
II.7. Since the late 1980s, several countries have
adopted inflation as a nominal anchor for monetary
policy, drawing upon the strong theoretical and
empirical support for low and stable inflation as a
necessary precondition for sustainable high growth.
II.8. The explicit domestic orientation of inflation
is seen as a clear advantage over other candidates for
the nominal anchor. It tasks monetary policy to
achieve price stability as an unambiguous and
sustainable goal upon which the private sector can
anchor its expectations about future inflation. The
other positives associated with inflation as an anchor
are that it is simple, easily communicated and hence,
well understood by the public at large. By promoting
low and stable inflation expectations, it contributes
to producing a desirable macroeconomic outcome.
The varied country experience with inflation targeting
(IT) suggests that it has yielded significant benefits in
terms of reduced inflation volatility (Svensson, 1997),
reduced impact of shocks (Mishkin, 2004) and
anchoring of inflation expectations (Kohn 2007, Swanson, 2006, Levin et al., 2004)4. Accordingly, IT
frameworks have gained widening acceptance among
advanced and emerging economies alike (Appendix
Tables II.2A and II.3). This has catalysed the deepening
of the institutional architecture around them.
II.9. IT has disadvantages in that (a) some part of
inflation, such as from food and fuel, is not easily
controlled by monetary policy; (b) it is inherently a
medium-term framework because of the long and
variable lags in monetary policy transmission. The
lack of immediate demonstrability of outcomes can
result in ambiguous perceptions of the policy stance.
Yet another concern has been the instability imparted
to output and employment due to the overarching
emphasis on achieving the inflation target, and the
observed increase in output losses associated with
disinflation.
II.10. Starting with Chile in 1991, the number of
EMEs (23) adopting inflation targeting as a monetary
policy framework has outstripped that of AEs (9). Most
EMEs used inflation targeting initially as a price
stabilising device, with a sequence of annually
declining inflation targets measured by headline
consumer price index (CPI) which is perceived as well
understood by the public and quickly available. These
EMEs tended to move away from a one-year ahead
inflation target to either multi-year targets or a
medium-term target. Several countries in this category
refer to their monetary policy framework as “inflation
targeting light” (ITL)5. There are some 38 countries
that have not committed to any specific target; among EMEs, important examples in this category are Russia
(to complete transition to an IT regime by 2015) and
India.
II.11. Finally, some monetary policy frameworks do
not operate under an explicit nominal anchor, but
such an anchor is implicit and the track record has
been creditable6 (e.g., the US), with forward-looking
behaviour triggering pre-emptive strikes against target
warnings (Appendix Table II.2B). The main criticisms
are the uncertainty in financial markets on policy
actions and herding of expectations; strong
dependence on individual skills and charisma of the
monetary policy wielder; and susceptibility to outside
pressures.
II.12. In spite of strong theoretical positions that
monetary policy can only hope to affect nominal
variables, and that in the long run, there is no tradeoff
between inflation and employment, policy makers
in some parts of the world have shown interest in
bypassing nominal anchors and choosing targets from
among real variables that have a direct bearing on
growth and consumption. Real exchange rate targeting
has been the most popular, but the experience has
been that while monetary policy may be able to
temporarily influence the real exchange rate, this can
come at the cost of a combination of higher inflation
and higher real interest rates. Additionally, this runs
the risk of losing the nominal anchor completely – in
the case of the real exchange rate target for instance,
the rate of nominal appreciation/ depreciation
becomes undetermined. The real interest rate has
served as an anchor as well7. Here too, the experience has shown that inflation can easily come unhinged
since there is nothing to tie it down8.
3. The Indian Experience
II.13. India’s monetary policy framework has
undergone several transformations, reflecting
underlying macroeconomic and financial conditions
as also the dominant socio-politico-economic
paradigm. Drawing from the colonial past, the initial
years following independence were characterised by
an exchange rate anchor set by the proportional
reserve system prescribed by the RBI Act where under
at least 40 per cent of the total note issue was to be
backed by gold bullion and sterling. The proportional
reserve system gave way to the minimum reserve
system in 1957 (only `2 billion worth of foreign
securities and bullion needed to be maintained as a
backing for currency issue, of which `1.15 billion had
to be in gold) and the use of credit aggregates as the
nominal anchor for monetary policy. Changes in the
Bank Rate and the cash reserve ratio (CRR) were the
main instruments of monetary policy supporting its
explicit credit allocation role embodied in selective
credit control, credit authorisation and ‘social control’
measures to enhance the flow of credit to priority
sectors. Setting the tone of monetary policy, the First
Five Year Plan envisaged “...judicious credit creation
somewhat in anticipation of the increase in production
and availability of genuine savings”.
II.14. During 1971-1985, the monetisation of the
fiscal deficit exerted a dominant influence on the
conduct of monetary policy. The pre-emption of
resources by the public sector and the resultant inflationary consequences of high public expenditure
necessitated frequent recourse to the CRR to neutralise
the secondary effects of the expansion. Financial
repression in the form of interest rate prescriptions,
statutory pre-emptions and directed credit partly
crowded out the private sector from the credit market.
Against this backdrop, the Committee to Review the
Working of the Monetary System (Chairman:
Dr. Sukhamoy Chakravarty) recommended in 1985 a
new monetary policy framework based on monetary
targeting with feedback, drawing on empirical
evidence of a stable demand function for money.
Thus, broad money became the intermediate target
while reserve money was one of the main operating
instruments for achieving control on broad money
growth. The Committee had also emphasized that
“short-term interest rates could reinforce the antiinflationary impact of monetary targeting if they are
also used as a monetary management tool in fighting
inflation”.
II.15. Analysis of the money growth outcomes
during the monetary targeting regime indicates that
targets were rarely met9. The biggest impediment to
monetary targeting was lack of control over RBI’s
credit to the central government, which accounted
for the bulk of reserve money creation10. Even with
the CRR and the statutory liquidity ratio (SLR) raised
to close to their statutory ceilings, money supply
growth remained high and fuelled inflation persistence
at elevated levels. With the reforms introduced in
1991, capital flows became another factor that rendered control over monetary aggregates difficult.
As the pace of trade and financial liberalisation gained
momentum in the 1990s, the efficacy of broad money
as an intermediate target was re-assessed. Financial
innovations and external shocks emanating from
swings in capital flows, volatility in the exchange rate
and global business cycles imparted instability to the
demand for money. There was also increasing
evidence of changes in the underlying transmission
mechanism of monetary policy with interest rate and
the exchange rate gaining importance vis-à-vis
quantity variables.
II.16. The structural reforms and financial
liberalisation in the 1990s also led to a shift in the
financing pattern for the government and commercial
sectors, with interest rates and the exchange rate,
increasingly market-determined. The RBI was able to
move away from direct instruments to indirect
market-based instruments. The CRR and SLR were
brought down to 9.5 per cent and 25 per cent of NDTL
of banks, respectively, by 1997. The RBI adopted a
‘multiple indicator approach’ in April 1998 with a
greater emphasis on rate channels for monetary policy
formulation relative to quantity instruments11. Under
this approach, which is currently in use, a number of
quantity variables such as money, credit, output,
trade, capital flows and fiscal position as well as rate
variables such as rates of return in different markets,
inflation rate and exchange rate are analyzed for
drawing monetary policy perspectives. The multiple
indicator approach is informed by forward looking indicators since the early 2000s drawn from the RBI’s
surveys of industrial outlook, credit conditions,
capacity utilization, professional forecasters, inflation
expectations and consumer confidence. The RBI
continues to give indicative projections of key
monetary aggregates.
II.17. The multiple indicator approach seemed to
work fairly well from 1998-99 to 2008-09, as reflected
in an average real gross domestic product (GDP)
growth rate of 7.1 per cent associated with average
inflation of about 5.5 per cent in terms of both the
wholesale price index (WPI) and the CPI. In recent
years, however, there has been mounting public
censure of the efficacy and even the credibility of this
framework as persistently high inflation and
weakening growth have come to co-exist. Using a large
panel of indicators has been criticised as not providing
a clearly defined nominal anchor for monetary
policy12. It also leaves policy analysts unclear about
what the RBI looks at while taking policy decisions.
II.18. WPI and Consumer Price Index-Industrial
Workers (CPI-IW) inflation declined from 8.0 per cent
and 8.8 per cent, respectively, in the monetary
targeting regime (1985-86 to 1997-98), to 5.4 per cent
and 5.6 per cent, respectively, during the first decade
of the multiple indicator regime (1998-99 to 2008-09).
Thereafter, it rose to 7.2 per cent and 10.5 per cent,
respectively, between April 2009 and November 2013.
Since 2008, retail inflation has trended up and has
persisted at double digit levels over the last six years
(Charts II.3 and II.4). In addition to supply side
bottlenecks, there have been sharp increases in the
minimum support prices (MSPs) since 2007-08
(Tables II.2 and II.3).
3.1. Recommendations of Earlier Committees
II.19. Since 2007 several high level Committees in
India have highlighted that the RBI must consider
switching over to IT.
II.20. The Report of the High Powered Expert
Committee on Making Mumbai an International Financial Centre, 2007 (Chairman: Percy S. Mistry) emphasised that the gold standard for a monetary
policy framework is a transparent, independent,
inflation-targeting central bank. With such an
arrangement the Indian State would be: (a) underlining
its commitment to delivering low and predictable
inflation; and (b) inducing greater confidence in the
Rupee in the eyes of domestic and global investors.

Table II.2: Minimum Support Price for Foodgrains according to Crop Year |
(Y-o-y growth in per cent) |
Year |
Paddy Common |
Coarse Cereals |
Wheat |
Gram |
Arhar (Tur) |
Moong |
Urad |
2000-01 |
4.1 |
7.2 |
5.2 |
8.4 |
8.6 |
8.6 |
8.6 |
2001-02 |
3.9 |
9.0 |
1.6 |
9.1 |
10.0 |
10.0 |
10.0 |
2002-03 |
0.0 |
0.0 |
0.0 |
1.7 |
0.0 |
0.8 |
0.8 |
2003-04 |
3.8 |
4.1 |
1.6 |
14.8 |
3.0 |
3.0 |
3.0 |
2004-05 |
1.8 |
2.0 |
1.6 |
1.8 |
2.2 |
2.9 |
2.9 |
2005-06 |
1.8 |
1.9 |
1.6 |
0.7 |
0.7 |
7.8 |
7.8 |
2006-07 |
1.8 |
2.9 |
15.4 |
0.7 |
0.7 |
0.0 |
0.0 |
2007-08 |
11.2 |
11.1 |
33.3 |
10.7 |
9.9 |
11.8 |
11.8 |
2008-09 |
39.5 |
40.0 |
8.0 |
8.1 |
29.0 |
48.2 |
48.2 |
2009-10 |
11.1 |
0.0 |
1.9 |
1.7 |
15.0 |
9.5 |
0.0 |
2010-11 |
0.0 |
4.8 |
6.4 |
19.3 |
52.2 |
33.0 |
34.9 |
2011-12 |
8.0 |
11.4 |
9.8 |
33.3 |
5.7 |
9.0 |
11.8 |
2012-13 |
15.7 |
19.9 |
5.1 |
7.1 |
4.1 |
10.0 |
13.2 |
2013-14 |
4.8 |
11.5 |
3.7 |
3.3 |
11.7 |
2.3 |
0.0 |
Source: Handbook of Statistics on Indian Economy, RBI; Ministry of Agriculture, Government of India. |
II.21. The Report of the Committee on Financial
Sector Reforms, 2009 (Chairman: Raghuram G. Rajan)
reiterated that the RBI can best serve the cause of
growth by focusing on controlling inflation, and
intervening in currency markets only to limit
excessive volatility. This focus can also best serve the
cause of inclusion because the poorer sections are
least hedged against inflation. The RBI should formally
have a single objective to stay close to a low inflation
number, or within a range, in the medium term, and
move steadily to a single instrument, the short-term
interest rate (repo and reverse repo) to achieve it.
II.22. The Financial Sector Legislative Reforms
Commission (FSLRC), 2013 (Chairman: B.N. Srikrishna) also recommended that price stability is
a desirable goal in its own right, particularly in India
where inflation is known to hurt the poor and
therefore the central bank must be given a quantitative
monitorable objective by the Central Government for
its monetary policy function. According to the
Committee, the Ministry of Finance should put out a statement defining a quantitative monitorable
‘predominant’ target. Additional/subsidiary targets
could also be specified, which would be pursued when
there are no difficulties in meeting the predominant
target.
Table II.3 : Mean Inflation Rates and Contribution to Overall Inflation |
Year |
WPI |
Contribution to Inflation in percentage points |
Food Items |
Non-food Articles |
Fuel Group and Minerals |
Non-food Manufacturing |
1983-84 |
7.6 |
3.1 |
0.5 |
0.4 |
3.3 |
1984-85 |
6.4 |
1.2 |
0.5 |
0.5 |
4.6 |
1985-86 |
4.5 |
0.5 |
-0.1 |
0.9 |
4.2 |
1986-87 |
5.8 |
2.5 |
0.5 |
0.5 |
1.6 |
1987-88 |
8.2 |
2.3 |
0.9 |
0.2 |
4.3 |
1988-89 |
7.5 |
2.1 |
-0.1 |
0.4 |
6.4 |
1989-90 |
7.4 |
1.2 |
0.2 |
0.4 |
7.0 |
1990-91 |
10.3 |
2.8 |
0.7 |
1.1 |
5.3 |
1991-92 |
13.7 |
4.5 |
0.8 |
1.2 |
6.9 |
1992-93 |
10.0 |
2.9 |
0.0 |
1.2 |
7.1 |
1993-94 |
8.3 |
1.8 |
0.4 |
1.6 |
4.6 |
1994-95 |
12.6 |
3.7 |
1.0 |
1.0 |
7.5 |
1995-96 |
8.0 |
1.1 |
0.4 |
0.5 |
6.1 |
1996-97 |
4.6 |
2.0 |
0.0 |
1.1 |
0.8 |
1997-98 |
4.4 |
1.5 |
0.1 |
1.4 |
1.1 |
1998-99 |
5.9 |
2.8 |
0.5 |
0.4 |
1.7 |
1999-00 |
3.3 |
1.6 |
-0.3 |
1.0 |
1.8 |
2000-01 |
7.2 |
-0.8 |
0.1 |
3.4 |
2.9 |
2001-02 |
3.6 |
-0.1 |
0.2 |
1.3 |
1.3 |
2002-03 |
3.4 |
0.9 |
0.3 |
0.8 |
1.1 |
2003-04 |
5.5 |
1.6 |
0.5 |
1.0 |
2.7 |
2004-05 |
6.5 |
0.9 |
0.0 |
1.8 |
3.6 |
2005-06 |
4.4 |
0.9 |
-0.1 |
2.2 |
1.5 |
2006-07 |
6.6 |
1.9 |
0.2 |
1.4 |
3.1 |
2007-08 |
4.7 |
1.4 |
0.5 |
0.2 |
2.7 |
2008-09 |
8.1 |
2.2 |
0.5 |
2.2 |
3.1 |
2009-10 |
3.8 |
3.6 |
0.2 |
-0.1 |
0.1 |
2010-11 |
9.6 |
3.0 |
1.0 |
2.4 |
3.1 |
2011-12 |
8.9 |
2.0 |
0.5 |
2.9 |
3.6 |
2012-13 |
7.4 |
2.5 |
0.5 |
1.9 |
2.4 |
2013-14 (up to December) |
6.2 |
2.9 |
0.3 |
1.7 |
1.2 |
Source: Patra, M.D. et al. (2013), extended up to December 2013-14. |
3.2. Rationale for Flexible Inflation Targeting in
India
II.23. Major central banks, in both advanced and
emerging economies, have adopted flexible inflation
targeting (FIT) under which the inflation target is
aimed to be achieved on average over the business
cycle, while accommodating growth concerns in the
short run (Ito, 2013).14 While FIT recognises the
existence of the growth-inflation trade-off in the short
run, it is designed around the critical importance of
price stability for sustainable growth in the medium
run. The flexibility under FIT, however, is not relevant
for conditions where the inflation target is not
achieved even over a full business cycle – whether at
any point of time or on an average i.e., high inflation
expectations exhibit far greater stickiness than
inflation – despite sustained slowdown in growth;
and persistently high inflation in itself becomes a risk
to growth (please see footnote no. 2), which limits
the space for accommodating growth concerns even
in the short run. India, arguably, faces similar
conditions in recent years and visible signs of
stagflation – i.e., high inflation co-existing with
sluggish growth – warrants a refocusing on the critical
importance of price stability for improving overall
macroeconomic stability in the near term, and for
securing growth prospects in the medium run. As set
out in Paragraph II.3, India is faced with the unique
challenge of experiencing one of the highest inflation
rates among G-20 countries, with the level of inflation
expectations having doubled over the last four years. As enunciated earlier, elevated inflation is creating
macroeconomic vulnerabilities. In the light of these
unique circumstances, the foremost and dominant
objective of monetary policy must be to anchor
inflation expectations. A monetary policy framework
with inflation as the nominal anchor is also consistent
with flexibility in exchange rate management15.
II.24. Stabilising and anchoring inflation
expectations – whether they are rational or adaptive
– is critical for ensuring price stability on an enduring
basis, so that monetary policy re-establishes credibility
visibly and transparently, that deviations from
desirable levels of inflation on a persistent basis will
not be tolerated. In doing so, monetary policy provides
a common set of expectations to all economic agents
which, in turn, influences their behaviour and thereby
aggregate demand. These dynamics can be captured
within the framework of the New Keynesian
macroeconomic model that is widely employed by
modern central banks (Box II.1).
Recommendations
II.25. Drawing from the review of cross-country
experience, the appraisal of India’s monetary policy
against the test of outcomes and the recommendations
made by previous committees, the Committee
recommends that inflation should be the nominal
anchor for the monetary policy framework. This
nominal anchor should be set by the RBI as its
predominant objective of monetary policy in its policy
statements. The nominal anchor should be
communicated without ambiguity, so as to ensure a
monetary policy regime shift away from the current
approach to one that is centered around the nominal
anchor. Subject to the establishment and achievement
of the nominal anchor, monetary policy conduct
should be consistent with a sustainable growth
trajectory and financial stability.
Box II.1: A Theoretical Framework as a Guide for Monetary Policy
The New Keynesian (NK) research programme is one of the
most influential and prolific areas of research in monetary
policy analysis. The framework provides the foundations of
the NK DSGE (dynamic stochastic general equilibrium) model
which is the workhorse model for the analysis of monetary
policy at major central banks. DSGE models are based on
optimising behaviour of households and firms, rational
expectations, and market clearing, i.e., it adopts many of the
tools associated with research on real business cycles.
However, firms are modeled as monopolistic competitors,
and nominal rigidities a key element of the model bring the
main source of monetary policy non-neutrality (Gali, 2008a,
2008b; Walsh, 2010; Sbordone et al., 2010).
The simple NK model comprises three equations. The first
equation is called the New Keynesian Philips Curve (NKPC).
This is the supply block of the model. This can be derived
from the aggregation of price-setting decisions by firms,
combined with an equation describing the relationship
between marginal cost and the level of activity (see Gali
2008a, 2008b). It is given by:
Equation (2) is called the dynamic IS equation (DIS). The
demand block exhibits a negative relationship between the
real interest rate and real activity, since a rise in the real
interest rate increases savings and lowers consumption (and
investment). Both the NKPC and the DIS constitute the nonpolicy
block of the New Keynesian model.
Finally, the model is closed by a monetary policy rule.
Monetary policy itself is often described by a central bank,
which sets the short-term nominal interest rate according
to a Taylor-type policy:
where it
is the short-term nominal interest rate, vt is a shock
(an exogenous policy disturbance), and y*t represents
deviations of log output from its steady state value. The policy reaction function of the monetary authority closes
the model allowing for a complete description of the
relationship between the key variables: output, inflation,
and the nominal interest rate.
Optimal Monetary Policy
Woodford (2003) showed that the objectives of inflation
targeting can be approximated by a quadratic loss function
consisting of the sum of the squares of inflation deviations
from target and a weight times the square of the output gap.
The loss function associated with inflation targeting is given
by:
where λ= 0 denotes a central bank that is a strict inflation
targeter, and λ > 0 denotes a central bank that is a flexible
inflation targeter (i.e., also concerned about the stability of
the economy).
Flexible inflation targeting refers to an optimal monetary
policy that minimizes the central bank’s loss function
(subject to equation (1)) by attaching a penalty to output gap
fluctuations. It can be shown that there are potential welfare
gains to be made if the central bank conveys credibly the
extent of its anti-inflationary stance (Svensson, 1997).
Further, in the context of the simple NK model in equations
(1), (2) and (3), the welfare comparisons will vary depending
on the weight given to output stabilization. The general
result is that the smallest welfare losses are obtained when
monetary policy responds to changes in inflation only.
As Gali (2008b) points out, there are two direct costs of
inflation in this framework which justify why central banks
should pursue a policy aimed at price stability. In the absence
of cost-push shocks, inflation becomes an indicator of an
inefficient level of economic activity, because of the deviation
of output from its natural level due to the presence of
nominal rigidities. Inflation also generates a more inefficient
allocation of resources across firms and sectors, because not
all firms can adjust their prices, which makes relative prices
vary in accordance with firm or sectoral level shocks. This
leads to sub-optimal goods being consumed and produced.
Both considerations, and other practical considerations (such
as the risk of hitting the zero lower bound on the nominal
interest rate), suggest that a desirable policy is the attainment
of a positive target for inflation over a medium-term horizon.
Also, because inflation and the output gap are forward-looking variables, the analysis of monetary policy in the
context of models with forward-looking variables points to
the importance of a credible commitment to improve the
central banks trade-offs.
The NK framework can be used to evaluate the desirability
of alternative monetary policy rules. It can also be used to
determine the optimal monetary policy rule using welfarebased
criterion. Because of its flexibility, it is able to
incorporate a wide variety of country-specific characteristics
of emerging market economies (commodity price shocks,
formal-informal sector linkages), as well as other extensions
(open economy features, credit frictions, etc.) for monetary
policy analysis.
References:
1. Gali, Jordi (2008a) “Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the
Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian
Framework”, Princeton University Press, New Jersey.
2. Gali, Jordi (2008b) “The New Keynesian Approach to
Monetary Policy Analysis: Lessons and New Directions”, Economics Working Papers 1075, Department of Economics
and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, February
3. Ghate, Chetan, Pandey, Radhika and Ila Patnaik (2013)
“Has India Emerged? Business Cycle Stylized Facts from a
Transitioning Economy” Structural Change and Economic
Dynamics, Vol. 24(C), pp 157-172
4. Walsh, Carl E. (2010) “Monetary Theory and Policy”, Third
Edition. MIT Press Books, The MIT Press.
5. Sbordone, Argia M., Tambalotti, Andrea, Rao, Krishna and
Kieran Walsh (2010) “Policy Analysis Using DSGE Models:
An Introduction” Economic Policy Review, Vol. 16, No. 2,
October, pp 23-43.
6. Woodford, Michael (2003) “Interest and Prices: Foundations
of a Theory of Monetary Policy”, Princeton University Press,
New Jersey.
7. Svensson, Lars E. O. (1997) “Optimal Inflation Targets,
‘Conservative’ Central Banks, and Linear Inflation Contracts”,
American Economic Review, Vol. 87(1), pp 98-114.
II.26. This recommendation is intended to better
ground inflation expectations by making clear that
inflation is the RBI’s primary objective and that it
expects to be held accountable for its performance in
this regard.
4. The Choice of Inflation Metric in India
4.1 Range of Options
II.27. Until recently, the RBI communicated
indicative inflation projections in terms of the WPI
alone, essentially because it is the only measure of
prices at a national level and CPIs have traditionally
addressed prices facing specific sections of society.
The three legacy consumer price indices – CPI-IW,
Consumer Price Index- Agricultural Labourers (CPIAL)
and Consumer Price Index-Rural Labourers (CPIRL)
– capture the heterogeneity of the economic
structure and the differences in the consumption
basket across different population segments. Since
October 2013, the RBI has started providing
indicative projections of inflation in terms of the
broader CPI-Combined. While WPI weights are primarily based on production and traded values,
the CPI-Combined weighting diagram is based on
the National Sample Survey Office (NSSO)’s 2004-05
consumer expenditure survey. The RBI internally
conducts inflation analysis on the basis of a number
of other indicators besides WPI/CPIs – inflation
expectations; yield spreads; input and output prices
in business expectations surveys and purchasing
managers’ indices; rural wages and corporate staff
costs; house prices and the like.
II.28. The WPI is an imperfect substitute for a
producer price index (PPI). Furthermore, it does not
capture price movements in non-commodity
producing sectors like services, which constitute close
to two-thirds of economic activity in India. It also does
not generally reflect price movements in all wholesale
markets as the price quotes of some of the important
commodities like milk, LPG and the like are basically
taken from retail markets. Movements in WPI often
reflect large external shocks. Moreover, it is often
subject to large revisions; for instance, between
January 2010 and October 2013, WPI inflation was revised 43 times out of which 36 times were in the
upward direction. These revisions are made two
months after the first announcement, generating large
uncertainty in the assessment of inflation conditions.
Conducting monetary policy based on provisional
numbers generally entails the risk of under-estimating
inflationary pressures, especially when inflation is
rising.
II.29. The true inflation that consumers face is in
the retail market. Although price indices that relate
to consumer expenditures are at best imperfect, they
are still close indicators of the cost of living. Almost
all central banks in AEs and EMEs use CPI as their
primary price indicator. Other price indicators like
the national income price deflator are used as a
secondary indicator16. The choice of CPI establishes
‘trust’ viz., economic agents note that the monetary
policy maker is targeting an index that is relevant for
households and businesses17. The widespread use of
the CPI as the major price indicator reflects its
advantages – it is familiar to large segments of the
population and often used in both public and private
sectors as a reference in the provision of government
benefits or in wage contracts and negotiations.
Importantly in India, unlike the WPI, the CPI is not
subject to large revisions, which enhances its utility
to the public and its usefulness for monetary policy
purposes18. There is no revision in CPI-IW and in case
of the CPI-Combined, revisions have so far been
marginal.
II.30. It is observed that the CPI-Combined has a
strong and statistically significant correlation with
the CPI-IW, allowing the superimposition of the
weighting pattern of the former on the price trends
of the latter so as to generate a sufficiently long time series for empirical assessment. The lag in the data
release of the CPI-Combined is only 12 days as against
one month for CPI-IW. The CPI-Combined and the
CPI-IW also show similar inflation momentum. Also,
the CPI-Combined is empirically found to be robust
in comparison with CPI-IW as far as price reporting
is concerned. Accordingly, the argument that the
CPI-Combined does not have adequate history to
support data analysis is not by itself a limiting
consideration.
II.31. In India, food has 48 per cent weight in the
CPI-Combined. If ‘food’ and ‘fuel and light’ are
excluded in order to arrive at a core inflation measure,
57.1 per cent of the consumption basket will be
discarded. Also, two major energy components, viz.,
petrol and diesel, are part of transport and
communication, which cannot be further segregated
(as item level disaggregated price index is not available
for the CPI-Combined). This also limits the estimation
of CPI core inflation based on statistical techniques
other than exclusion. Furthermore, high inflation in
food and energy items is generally reflected in
elevated inflation expectations. With a lag, this gets
manifested in the inflation of other items, particularly
services. Shocks to food inflation and fuel inflation
also have a much larger and more persistent impact
on inflation expectations than shocks to non-food
non-fuel inflation. As such, any attempt to anchor
inflation expectations cannot ignore shocks to food
and fuel. Furthermore, it is the headline CPI that
households use to deflate nominal returns and
therefore headline CPI informs their portfolio choice
of financial assets vis-a-vis other categories (like gold
and real estate). Therefore, in spite of the argument
made that a substantial part of CPI inflation may not
be in the ambit of monetary policy to control, the exclusion of food and energy may not yield ‘true’
measure of inflation for conducting monetary policy.
In these conditions, the CPI-Combined based headline
inflation measure appears to be the most feasible and
appropriate measure of inflation – as the closest proxy of a true cost of living index – for the conduct of
monetary policy. Going forward, improvements in
the index will be helpful to make the CPI-Combined
a more robust and comprehensive measure of
inflation conditions (Box II.2).
Box II.2: CPI-Combined as a Representative Measure of Inflation
The introduction of new CPIs in 2011, i.e., all India CPICombined,
CPI-Rural and CPI-Urban provides for the first
time a nationwide retail price index in India that captures
the inflation faced by households, i.e., cost of living inflation.
The new CPIs have a comprehensive coverage across regions
as well as commodity groups including services. With a base
year of 2010, the new CPIs have a weighting pattern that
reflects more recent consumption patterns as compared with
the other CPIs, as it is based on NSSO’s 61st Round of
Consumer Expenditure Survey data (2004-05). The CPI
consumption basket will become up to date with its
forthcoming revision based on weights from the NSS 68th
round Consumer Expenditure Survey (2011-12). As per the
latest NSSO survey, the weight of food in the consumption
basket has gone down (from 55.0 per cent and 42.5 per cent
respectively in the 2004-05 Round to 48.6 per cent and 38.5
per cent in the 2010-11 Round for rural and urban areas, as
per the uniform reference period (URP) of last 30 days).
The prices data collected from across India on a monthly
basis by NSSO, Department of Posts as well as through web
portals maintained by the National Informatics Centre, has
contributed to improving the quality of data. At times, other
measures of CPI have yielded similar inflation as the new
CPIs; however, due to large differences in coverage and the
weighting diagram (Table 1), comparison of new CPI and old
CPIs (i.e. CPI-IW, CPI-AL and CPI-RL) at item level, is not
directly feasible.
While inflation measured by CPI-Combined is the most
representative among available measures of inflation for
households and therefore monetary policy, disaggregated
information on weights and prices at the commodity level
is not yet available. Public dissemination of disaggregated
information is important for analysis and as a ‘public good’
in itself. Availability of data on item level indices will also
help in understanding the nature of price flexibility/
stickiness. Moreover, if the disaggregated information is also
made available for sub-groups based on Classification of
Individual Consumption by Purpose (COICOP), it would
facilitate cross-country comparison of price movements.
Currently, the housing index for CPI-Urban includes different
sub-samples for different months and the samples are repeated only once in six months. Information on centres
included in each sub-sample would be required to get a
clearer idea of region specific movements in house prices
and rent.
Table 1: Weight of Different Groups in the CPIs |
Items |
CPI- Urban |
CPI- IW |
CPI- Rural |
CPI- RL |
CPI- Combined |
Food and beverages |
35.80 |
46.19 |
56.58 |
66.77 |
47.58 |
Pan, tobacco and intoxicants |
1.35 |
2.27 |
2.73 |
3.7 |
2.13 |
Fuel and light |
8.40 |
6.43 |
10.42 |
7.9 |
9.49 |
Housing |
22.53 |
15.27 |
- |
- |
9.77 |
Clothing, bedding and footwear |
3.91 |
6.57 |
5.36 |
9.76 |
4.73 |
Miscellaneous |
28.00 |
23.27 |
24.91 |
11.87 |
26.31 |
Note: CPI-Urban and CPI-Rural are the components of the new CPICombined |
The CPI-Combined is compiled based on aggregation of
State-level CPIs using state-based weights to derive the all
India Index. Considering the heterogeneous nature of price
movements across different regions, the CPI-Combined
inflation could be susceptible to localised price pressures
and volatility. Having indices based on national level weights
at commodity level, to an extent, could mitigate this. More
detailed information at the state level should also be made
available in the public domain.
Given that CPI captures end-user prices which include both
central and state taxes, there could be price fluctuations
imparted by different tax structures across States. Currently,
in the absence of a uniform GST, state level variations in tax
policies and their contribution to the national inflation
would have to be carefully analysed to understand the
inflation dynamics. Some information on the tax component
of prices at retail level, if compiled separately, could help in
disentangling the effects of market driven price movements
from the impact of changes in taxes on CPI.
Currently services are largely captured within the
Miscellaneous group. Even within the sub-group of
miscellaneous, the baskets constitute a mix of goods and
services. A separate service price index as a memo item
would be desirable for analytical purposes.
4.2 Rationale for the Choice of CPI
II.32. In view of the long and variable lags
characterising monetary policy, an appropriate
inflation indicator has to be forward-looking, tracking
inflation expectations. A wide consensus in the
theoretical and empirical literature has settled around
the position that inflation is driven by the output gap
and by inflation expectations (either backward or
forward-looking) which influence wage and price
setting behavior (as typified in the “New Keynesian
Phillips Curve (NKPC)”). The evidence forming in the
post-2008 global financial crisis period suggest that
the role of inflation expectations in shaping inflation
dynamics has become even more important.
Illustratively, the level of slack in advanced economies
should have imparted sustained deflationary
pressures in this period; instead, inflation has
remained in the 2-3 per cent range because inflation
expectations were anchored at those levels by
advanced economy central banks (IMF, 2013)19. More
generally, over the last few decades the role of output
gaps vis-à-vis inflation expectations in influencing
inflation dynamics is observed to be secularly falling.
II.33. A similar dynamic, albeit undesirable, may be
currently playing out in India. Even as the Indian
economy has experienced negative output gaps in
2013, CPI inflation excluding food and fuel has
remained sticky at an elevated level, averaging above
8 per cent, and playing a growing role in determining
wage and price behavior in India. The crucial question,
therefore, is: what is driving household inflation
expectations in India? An examination of the
quantitative inflation expectations of households in
the RBI’s survey shows that inflation expectations
tended to follow WPI inflation during 2008-09. Post-
2011, however, they seem to be following CPI
inflation. Panel data analysis based on the RBI’s urban
households’ inflation expectations survey shows that
both three-month ahead and one-year ahead
expectations are significantly influenced by food as
well as fuel inflation measured from CPI-IW (Annex 2). This indicates the need to target headline CPI and
not CPI excluding food and fuel to anchor inflation
expectations. Empirical evidence also suggests that:
(a) changes in CPI-headline as well as CPI-food and
fuel inflation drive changes in inflation expectations,
and (b) increases in policy rates respond to rising
inflation expectations (details in Chapter-IV).
II.34. Modeling inflation as a function of its lag and
forward-looking inflation expectations along with the
output gap in a Bayesian Vector Auto Regression (VAR)
framework – to account for the dynamic properties
of each variable and the simultaneity properties –
shows that shocks to food and fuel inflation within
the CPI basket have the largest and most persistent
impact on overall inflation expectations. Specifically,
a 100 basis points (bps) shock to food inflation
immediately affects one-year forward expectations
by as much as 50 bps and persists for 8 quarters. The
persistence of the food inflation shock on expectations
reveals that either households perceive food shocks
to be sustained and/or they expect food shocks will
inevitably translate into a more generalized inflation
with a lag. Shocks to fuel inflation also result in large
changes in expectations but are less persistent,
impacting one-year-ahead expectations up to four
quarters. Interestingly, shocks to inflation excluding
food and fuel have a far more muted quantitative
impact on expectations and persist for only two-three
quarters. Shocks to WPI inflation have no statistically significant impact on inflation expectations, indicating
that targeting the WPI would do little to anchor
inflation expectations. This analysis is robust to
different estimations of output gaps and to the use
of both three-month and one-year-ahead inflation
expectations (Box II.3).
II.35. The results are intuitive because households
experience food and fuel price changes on a daily
basis but other prices change infrequently. The role
of inflation expectations cannot be ignored in the
price formation process and, in fact, may have
assumed greater importance than before. In particular, the elevated and entrenched nature of expectations
in India – as measured by the RBI’s households’
surveys – is likely a key reason why elevated inflation
currently co-exists with negative output gaps.
Consequently, the choice of the inflation metric
cannot ignore food and fuel shocks and must, in fact,
react to them to avoid a more generalized inflation
spiral that influences household expectations
lastingly. Not a single EME inflation-targeting central
bank targets core CPI – other than Thailand – all of
them target headline CPI. It is often argued that India is unique, with food and fuel inflation constituting
57.1 per cent of the CPI basket and therefore outside
the direct control of the RBI. In this context, however,
it needs to be recognized that there are other EMEs
that also have a relatively significant fraction of food
and fuel in the CPI basket (close to 40 per cent in the
case of Indonesia and Brazil) but still choose to target
headline CPI20. Accordingly, the Committee is of the
view that in the current context, targeting headline
CPI would be a critical prerequisite for reducing and
then anchoring inflation expectations.

Recommendation
II.36. The Committee recommends that the RBI
should adopt the new CPI (combined) as the measure
of the nominal anchor for policy communication. The
nominal anchor should be defined in terms of
headline CPI inflation, which closely reflects the cost
of living and influences inflation expectations relative
to other available metrics.
5. Numerical Target and Precision
II.37. A numerical inflation target reflects, explicitly
or implicitly, the meaning of price stability in a
country specific context. An explicit interpretation of
inflation as an objective of monetary policy is
exemplified by the ECB which defines price stability
as “...a year-on-year increase in the Harmonised Index
of Consumer Prices (HICP) for the euro area of below
2 per cent”. An illustration of an implicit inflation
goal is that of China: “Government announced to hold
CPI inflation in 2013 at 3.5 per cent, 0.5 percentage
point lower than the target of last year”. The cross
country experience suggests that the numerical target
should be a low but non-zero positive number.
II.38. What should be the non-zero positive number
for India? Estimates using multivariate methods on
quarterly data indicate that the level of CPI-Combined
inflation (all India back-casted using the CPI-IW) above
which it is inimically harmful to growth is 6.2 per
cent (Annex 3). Alternative methods of estimating the
output gap (univariate and multivariate) suggest that
the output gap was fairly close to zero during the
period from Q3 of 2003-04 and Q1 of 2006-07 (Annex
4). During the same period, average CPI inflation was at around 4 per cent. Admittedly, these estimates may
not hold for a future regime that is centered around
a clear nominal anchor (in other words, the past may
not be a robust guide to the future – a form of Lucas
critique at play). Notwithstanding the limitations,
these estimates provide, as a possible starting point,
empirical support to a range of 4 to 6 per cent for the
inflation target.
II.39. The choice of the exact numerical range or
target for a country is also informed by inflation in
comparator EMEs and trading partners, consistent
with its broader integration with the global economy.
Country practices suggest that the target should be
either less than or equal to the level of inflation that
may be consistent with minimum attainable noninflationary
rate of unemployment or maximum
non-inflationary rate of growth21. In the literature,
there is a convergence of views that an inflation rate
of 1 to 3 per cent corresponds to price stability in AEs
(since the Balassa-Samuelson effect would suggest
higher inflation in emerging markets), while in
transition economies inflation in the range of 4 to 5
per cent would correspond to price stability22 (Appendix Table II.4A and B). Thus, the 1 to 3 per cent
AE inflation range sets a lower bound, while an
inflation rate for India at around 6 per cent23 can be
regarded as an upper bound. The key advantage of a
range/band is that it allows monetary policy to do best
what it can do, i.e., it remains sensitive to short run
trade-offs between inflation and growth, but
pursues the inflation target on average over the course
of a business cycle. Data limitations (ranging from large revisions to low quality of final revised data),
projection errors, and short run developments having
a large impact on the near-term inflation path – such
as failure of agricultural crops, high commodity prices,
sharp depreciation in the exchange rate, higher taxes
– also warrant flexibility through adoption of ranges/
bands. A band also provides lead information on
maximum tolerance levels of monetary policy to
accommodate unanticipated shocks, which enhances
transparency and predictability.
5.1. Time Horizon for Attaining Price Stability
II.40. Speed of disinflation is important for arriving
at the appropriate time horizon over which the
inflation target may have to be attained, but
particularly important for a country aiming at
adoption of flexible inflation targeting from a very
high and persistent level of CPI inflation. Speed also
has to take into account the fact that prolonged high
inflation itself imposes costs – in the recent
experience in India, these costs have entailed
appreciating real effective exchange rate (REER), high
CAD, financial disintermediation (into gold), and
resultant decline in financial saving and investment
that may have contributed to low growth.
II.41. It is difficult to identify the optimal speed of
disinflation. The time horizon should ideally reflect
the trade off long and variable lags (which may justify
two to three years) versus credibility of the target
(which may demand a shorter time horizon of about
one year, since large deviations in the short run,
despite the best communication, may not help in
anchoring inflation expectations)24 (Appendix Table
II.5). While the Committee recognises that setting a
relatively short time horizon can pose controllability
problems (i.e., ability of a central bank to achieve the
targets without large costs) and lead to loss of
credibility if the target is missed, a time horizon of two years for achieving the inflation target is
necessitated by the initial conditions in India and the
serious macroeconomic consequences that they have
entailed. A two-year time horizon should enable the
performance of monetary policy to be easily verified
by the public, enhancing credibility. Recognising,
however, that large output variations in a short time
horizon should generally be avoided by monetary
policy, it is pragmatic, on balance, to set multi-year
targets that provide a lower medium-term target along
with somewhat higher targets for the intermediate
years (Box II.4).
Recommendations
II.42. The Committee recommends that the
nominal anchor or target should be set at 4 per cent
with a band of +/- 2 per cent around it (a) in view of
the vulnerability of the Indian economy to supply/
external shocks and the relatively large weight of food
in the CPI; and (b) the need to avoid a deflation bias
in the conduct of monetary policy. This target should
be set in the frame of a two-year horizon that is
consistent with the need to balance the output costs
of disinflation against the speed of entrenchment of
credibility in policy commitment.
II.43. In view of the elevated level of current CPI
inflation and hardened inflation expectations, supply
constraints and weak output performance, the
transition path to the target zone should be graduated
to bringing down inflation from the current level of
10 per cent to 8 per cent over a period not exceeding
the next 12 months and 6 per cent over a period not
exceeding the next 24 month period before formally
adopting the recommended target of 4 per cent
inflation with a band of +/- 2 per cent. The Committee
is also of the view that this transition path should be
clearly communicated to the public.
Box II.4: Glide Path for Inflation Targets: Case Studies of Chile and Czech Republic
Since India’s CPI inflation has persisted at a high level over
successive years, the experience of countries such as Chile
and Czechoslovakia could be particularly useful.
The Central Bank of Chile adopted inflation targeting in
September 1990 when the country’s level of inflation was
over 25 per cent. It announced its first annual inflation
target in a range of 15-20 per cent for 1991. The inflation
target for each successive year was set at a somewhat lower
level than in the previous year. For example, the inflation
target range was revised down to 13-16 per cent for 1992.
In 1995, however, it adopted a point target. The point target
was also gradually lowered from 8 per cent in 1995 to 3.5
per cent in 2000. After reaching a reasonably steady-state
inflation rate in 1999, the Central Bank of Chile announced
its inflation target as 2 per cent with a tolerance band of 1 per
cent point in either direction, to be achieved over the time
horizon of 2 years. Chart 1 shows the cautious and gradual
approach to adoption of a low inflation target; almost one
decade of transition to explicit inflation targeting.

The approach of CNB (Czech National Bank) is a classic
example of how all range of options could be tried by a single
country over time, recognising the challenge of adopting
inflation targeting from a high level of inflation (Chart 2).
The CNB switched to inflation targeting in December 1997,
by announcing a medium-term inflation target for end-
2000 (of 3.5 - 5.5 per cent), but with higher targets of 5.5-6.5
per cent for end-1998, and 4-5 per cent for end-1999. In
April 1999, it announced a long-term objective of 1-3 per
cent range for end-2005. A band was announced, starting
in January 2002, at 3-5 per cent and ending in December
2005 at 2-4 per cent. An inflation target of 3 per cent with a
tolerance band of one percentage point in either direction
was announced for the period from January 2006. In March
2007, a new inflation target of 2 per cent was announced
(to become effective from January 2010). Currently the CNB
strives to ensure that actual inflation does not differ from
the target by more than one percentage point on either
side.

II.44 Since food and fuel account for more than 57
per cent of the CPI on which the direct influence of
monetary policy is limited, the commitment to the
nominal anchor would need to be demonstrated by
timely monetary policy response to risks from second
round effects and inflation expectations in response
to shocks to food and fuel.
5.2. Institutional Requirements
II.45. While inflation is clearly a monetary
phenomenon in the medium run, several nonmonetary
factors – both domestic and external; supply side and demand side – can lead to significant
deviations from the target in the short run, which
may also impact the medium-term path through
persistence and unanchored inflation expectations.
It is necessary, therefore, that the adoption of flexible
inflation targeting is based on reasonably clear
identification of the pre-conditions. In India, building
on the reputational bonus from adherence to fiscal
targets in 2012-13, the Government must commit on
a priority basis to a re-invigoration of the mediumterm
fiscal consolidation, as was pursued under the
Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management (FRRBM) Act, 200325. The Committee is of the view
that the goal of reducing the central government
deficit to 3 per cent of GDP by 2016-17 is necessary
and achievable. Towards this objective, the Government
must set a path of fiscal consolidation with zero or
few escape clauses; ideally this should be legislated
and publicly communicated. The Report of the
Committee on Roadmap for Fiscal Consolidation, 2012
(Chairman: Vijay L. Kelkar) already provides a path
for the period up to 2014-1526. Furthermore, it may
be important to identify and address other fiscal/
administrative sources of pressure on inflation/drivers
of inflation persistence. For instance, the design of
programmes like Mahatma Gandhi National Rural
Employment Guarantee Act (MGNREGA) provide a
sustained upward push to nominal wages unrelated
to productivity growth, and the National Food Security
Act which could increase demand for foodgrains
without corresponding efforts to augment supply. A
policy induced wage-price/cost-price spiral can be
damaging for the credibility of an inflation targeting
framework. The burden on monetary policy to
compensate for these sources of inflation pressure is
correspondingly higher.
II.46. The Committee recognises that excessive
emphasis on pre-conditions may delay the adoption
of flexible inflation targeting, and in fact, very few
inflation targeting countries achieved all the preconditions
before formal adoption of the framework.
Many inflation targeting countries got instrument
independence, achieved more transparency in terms
of publication of inflation target/reports, and
continued to manage the exchange rate after the
switch over to inflation targeting. Fiscal discipline
generally turned out to be the biggest immediate
advantage of formal adoption of inflation targeting
(Table II.4).
Table II.4: Fiscal Balances of Countries in the Year
of Adopting Inflation Targeting and in 2007 |
Country |
Year of Adopting Inflation Targeting |
Fiscal Balance in the Year of Adopting Inflation Targeting (Per cent of GDP) |
Fiscal Balance in 2007 (Per cent of GDP) |
Chile |
1990 |
3.5 |
8.4 |
Israel |
1990 |
-4.4 |
-0.2 |
Australia |
1993 |
-3.9 |
1.5 |
Canada |
1990 |
-4.9 |
1.6 |
Finland |
1992 |
-8.1 |
5.2 |
New Zealand |
1990 |
-1.7 |
2.5 |
Spain |
1994 |
-4.9 |
1.9 |
Sweden |
1992 |
-9.8 |
3.7 |
UK |
1992 |
-7.2 |
-2.7 |
Brazil |
1999 |
-6.9 |
-2.6 |
Czech Republic |
1998 |
-1.6 |
-0.7 |
Poland |
1999 |
-5.0 |
-1.9 |
South Africa |
2000 |
-2.7 |
1.2 |
Thailand |
2000 |
-2.2 |
0.2 |
Source: 1. IMF (2001) “The Decline of Inflation in Emerging Markets: Can it be Maintained?”, World Economic Outlook, Chapter
4, Table 4.5, May.
2. IMF (2010) “Fiscal Exit: From Strategy to Implementation”, Fiscal Monitor, Statistical Table 1, November. |
Recommendations
II.47. Consistent with the Fiscal Responsibility and
Budget Management (Amendment) Rules, 2013, the
Central Government needs to ensure that its fiscal
deficit as a ratio to GDP is brought down to 3.0 per
cent by 2016-17.
II.48. Administered setting of prices, wages and
interest rates are significant impediments to monetary
policy transmission and achievement of the price
stability objective, requiring a commitment from the
Government towards their elimination .
II.49. Finally, communication and transparency is
important for any monetary policy framework, but
more so for flexible inflation targeting (Appendix Tables II.6A and B). There are several factors that
demand clearer communication on monetary policy.
First, every democratic society requires public
institutions that are accountable. The central bank
must explain how it uses its monopoly power over
money to attain the goals assigned to it by the elected
government. Secondly, in a market economy, a central
bank has to rely on financial markets for transmission
of its policies. It must, therefore, provide frequent
assessments on macro-financial conditions (credible information for the markets) and clarify the intent
of the policy stance. This is necessary for enhancing
policy effectiveness and containing destabilising
expectations. Frameworks with inflation as a nominal
anchor emphasise transparency in the form of public
release of inflation reports, monetary policy
committee minutes, projected inflation path with fan
charts and open letters to explain deviations from
the inflation target27. These aspects are addressed in
Chapter III.
|