2.1 The world economy witnessed a truly
global crisis since mid 2008. This crisis has tested
the contours of the functioning of the global
financial landscape, while the interlinkages
between the financial and the real economy were
magnified. The problems that surfaced in the US
sub-prime market in August 2007 reached their
peak during September 2008 when some of the
prime Wall Street financial institutions collapsed,
leading to a worldwide failure of confidence. Credit
markets virtually froze with financial institutions
almost unwilling to lend to each other. The loss of
confidence set off a chain of deleveraging,
declining asset and commodity prices, falling
incomes, shrinking demand and trade and capital
flows, and rising unemployment in the advanced
economies in the early stages. Although advanced
countries clearly remained the epicentre of the
recent global crisis, emerging market economies
(EMEs) have also been substantially affected by
the crisis. The turmoil in the financial sector of the
advanced countries traversed to the financial
sector of the EMEs, including India, especially
after the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy in mid-
September 2008. The contagion spread to these
economies through financial, trade and confidence
channels, despite their relatively sound
fundamentals. This promoted many to revisit the
so-called ‘decoupling theory’ in an increasingly
globalised world. Thus, what started off as a subprime
crisis in the US housing market in August
2007 turned successively into a global banking
crisis, a global financial crisis and then a global
economic crisis.
2.2 The period prior to the unravelling of the
crisis was generally characterised by relatively
steady growth and low and stable inflation in
advanced economies and rapid growth and
development in EMEs, popularly known as the
period of ‘Great Moderation’ (Bernanke, 2004). This prolonged period of macroeconomic stability was
attributed to free markets and successful
globalisation. The ‘Great Moderation’ in economic
performance, however, ignored the possibility of
catastrophic failures in a market economy. What
remained hidden within these overall signs of
prosperity were the immensely complex financial
systems that at times remained beyond the
regulatory purview of policy authorities, and posed
tremendous systemic risks. In addition, some
structural imbalances had also developed in the
world economy over the years in terms of
mismatches between savings and investments and
production and consumption across nations that
were manifested in widening current account
imbalances, misaligned exchange rates, and low
interest rates and asset prices, which had to unwind
at some point of time. All these factors manifested
themselves in the form of the worst-ever global
financial crisis.
2.3 The rapid speed with which the financial
crisis spread from the United States to Europe and
then to the rest of the world shocked the entire
world. While crises have been part of the financial
landscape for ages, it is now widely accepted that
the nearest precedent to the recent crisis is the
Great Depression of the 1930s in terms of its depth,
geographical spread, intensity and duration. No
country has been spared from its wrath, although
the impact has varied across nations.
2.4 The recent financial crisis and the
subsequent recession have re-opened two crucial
debates – on the efficacy of the markets and the
role of public policy, the so-called Keynesianism
– and have posed new challenges for the discipline
of economics. The recent crisis has again
questioned the role of finance in leading to growth
and brought into focus the role of non-economic
motives in explaining market rise and fall. The
recent crisis has also necessitated a revisit of the current global regulatory and supervisory
structures and perimeters against the backdrop
of rapid financial innovations. Finally, it has reinvoked
the debate on the adequacy and efficacy
of the current international financial architecture
to prevent and manage global crises of the kind
recently seen.
2.5 The depth and breadth of the crisis has
tested the limits of the conventional and
unconventional policy options available to
policymakers around the world. The initial estimate
of actual and potential global write-downs held by
banks and other financial institutions, which started
at about US$ 50 billion in mid-2007, increased to
around US$ 4.0 trillion by end-2008 and was scaled
down to US$ 2.3 trillion by the IMF in April 2010.
As per IMF forecasts (April, 2010), world GDP
growth after decelerating to 3.0 per cent in 2008
from 5.2 per cent in 2007 declined by 0.6 per cent
in 2009. However, the global growth is projected to
rise to 4.2 per cent in 2010 and 4.3 per cent in
2011. The advanced economies exhibited a
negative growth of 3.2 per cent in 2009 (as against
a positive growth of 0.5 per cent in 2008), while
emerging and developing economies grew by 2.4
per cent in 2009 (compared with 6.1 per cent in
2008). The advanced economies and the emerging
and developing economies are projected to grow
by 2.3 per cent and 6.3 per cent, respectively,
during 2010.
2.6 Against the above backdrop, this chapter
will trace the genesis and nature of the crises
affecting both the developed and developing world
over the past century and a half when they often
arrived with fierce force and departed with important
lessons for policymakers. This will be covered under
three broad sections. Section I will discuss in detail
the causes of the recent financial crisis and
simultaneously trace the evolving debate on the
various contributing factors. The crisis in a historical
perspective is covered in Section II. A comparison
between the recent crisis and similar earlier
episodes is presented in Section III. Section IV sets
out the concluding observations.
I. CAUSES OF THE CRISIS
2.7 The causes of the crisis were many and
intertwined as such a pervasive crisis cannot be
triggered by a single or isolated cause. In trying to
understand the various causes of the crisis,
different viewpoints have emerged. One view
believes that the current disruption of financial
markets is the long-run consequence of the easy
global money and credit conditions that existed,
particularly from the start of the decade. While the
immediate cause of the financial crisis is attributed
to the problems persisting in the sub-prime
mortgage sector of the United States, the root lies
in the persistence of global imbalances since the
start of the current decade (BIS, 2009; Mohan,
2008; Portes, 2009; Taylor, 2009). The global
imbalances interacted with the flaws in financial
markets and instruments to generate the specific
features of the crisis.
2.8 Another view argues that if imbalances at the
global level were the root cause, then why did the
crisis originate in the United States and not in other
countries which were also partners of global
imbalances? The excesses in the US financial
system are, in fact, at the core of the current crisis
and all other factors contributed to further aggravate
the crisis. Finance has been the proximate factor
behind most crises of the past and the recent crisis
is no different (Ferguson, 2009). Some are also of
the opinion that one important cause of the crisis is
the US Fed’s very low interest rates that were
maintained for a very long time leading to a housing
and asset price bubble (ECB, 2007; Taylor, 2009;
Skidelsky, 2009) and an equally important cause has
been the lack of recognition of asset prices in policy
formulation (Borio and Lowe, 2004; White 2008).
According to some, the Basel Accord is also a cause
of the recent banking crisis; banks’ efforts to
circumvent the capital adequacy requirements of
Basel Accord caused the financial crisis (Acharya
et al., 2009; Plender, 2007). Leaders at the G-20
Summit in September 2009 blamed global
imbalances, seeing them as more responsible for
the crisis than the failure of global financial regulation.
2.9 The debate on the causes of the crisis has
also revolved around whether the crisis was the
result of market failure or of governance failure.
The Great Moderation in economic performance
over the previous decade and half ignored the
possibility of catastrophic failures in the market
economy. During the golden years, financial
economists believed that free-market economies
could never go astray, which is belied by the crisis
(Krugman, 2009). The IMF too supported the
market-oriented ideology.
2.10 In contrast, the recent crisis has also been
considered to be a failure of governance. Central
banks focused excessively on CPI inflation at the
expense of financial vulnerability (IMF, 2009a).
Since there was no formal mandate to maintain
financial stability, the latter was inadvertently
ignored in public policy. By accommodating lax
credit conditions and rising debt, monetary
policymakers in a way increased the risks of a bust.
Besides, many central banks were persuaded to
be very transparent and provided forward guidance
to the financial markets on their policy stance,
especially on the future course of monetary policy.
Such forward guidance provided excessive comfort
to the financial markets and aided the under-pricing
of risks1. The roles of international financial
institutions like the IMF with the responsibility of
surveillance, have also been questioned. It is
lamented that the IMF failed in diagnosing and
pointing out the vulnerabilities both at the global
level and at the level of systemically important
advanced economies.
2.11 A more balanced viewpoint is that the recent
crisis reflects a collapse of the market as well as
the State, since governance in both private and
public sectors failed (Reddy, 2009c). This argument
has been stretched further to interpret failure of
governance at all levels as indicative of moral failure
of the whole economic system or what some have
described as a failure of capitalism (Krugman, 2009). Be that as it may, as the debate on the
causes of the crisis still continues, it is worth
distilling the variety of factors that contributed to
the crisis.
Global Imbalances
2.12 From a historical perspective, many now
argue that the US sub-prime mortgage crisis was
only a proximate cause or simply a trigger for the
recent crisis through the re-pricing of risks that
spilled over to other parts of the world via
securitised mortgage derivatives. At a more
fundamental level, it can be traced to the
persistence of large global imbalances of various
systemically important economies over a period of
time – large current account deficits in the US along
with some other advanced economies such as the
United Kingdom, Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain
mirrored by substantial surplus in Asia, particularly
in China, oil-exporting countries in the Middle East
and Russia – that posed risks to the global financial
system of a disorderly unwinding. Global
imbalances, in general, can be defined as “external
positions of systemically important economies
reflecting distortions or entailing risks for the global
economy” (Bracke et al., 2008).
2.13 The period following the bursting of the dotcom
bubble in the US was marked by a highly
accommodative monetary policy that boosted
aggregate demand in the US as well as in other
advanced countries. Lower interest rates along with
financial innovations encouraged a housing boom
and an increase in housing and other asset prices,
providing further impetus to consumption and
investment through wealth effects. While real
activity in the US did provide a stimulus to activity
in the rest of the world, it was accompanied by large
and growing current account deficits (Table 2.1). In
absolute terms, the current account deficit (CAD)
of the US saw a seven-fold increase from US$
114 billion in 1995 to US$ 804 billion in 2006 (Table 2.2). As a percentage of GDP, the CAD of
the US almost doubled every 5 years from the early
1990s (Table 2.3). During 2006, the CAD was close
to 6 per cent of GDP, the highest-ever CAD for the
US that amounted to about 1.5 per cent of global
GDP. Although it has declined since then, it remains
high by historic standards. A large increase in
current account deficits was not confined to the US;
in fact; since 1996 a number of other key industrial
countries have also seen their current accounts
turning to deficit, including France, Italy, Spain,
Australia, and the United Kingdom. Most of these have experienced substantial housing appreciation
and increases in household wealth (Bernanke,
2005). For example, since 1996 wealth-to-income
ratio has risen by 14 per cent in France, 12 per
cent in Italy, and 27 per cent in the United Kingdom.
Table 2.1: Macro Parameters of the United States |
(in per cent, annual average) |
Period |
GDP growth |
CAD/ GDP |
General Government Fiscal Balance/ GDP |
Savings |
Investments |
Savings- Investment gap |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
1981-85 |
3.3 |
-1.3 |
-4.5 |
18.7 |
20.8 |
-2.1 |
1986-90 |
3.2 |
-2.4 |
-4.1 |
16.6 |
19.8 |
-3.2 |
1991-95 |
2.5 |
-1.1 |
-4.5 |
15.4 |
17.8 |
-2.4 |
1996-2000 |
4.3 |
-2.6 |
-0.02 |
18.1 |
20.1 |
-1.9 |
2001-2005 |
2.4 |
-4.8 |
-3.3 |
14.9 |
19.3 |
-4.4 |
2005-2008 |
1.8 |
-5.3 |
-3.6 |
14.4 |
19.4 |
-5.0 |
Source : World Economic Outlook, October 2009, International Monetary Fund. |
2.14 With large current account imbalances,
capital flew from capital-poor emerging countries
to capital-rich industrial economies, especially the US.
Also, in response to the series of financial crises the
EMEs experienced during the 1990s, they either
chose or were forced into new strategies for
managing international capital flows. In general, these
strategies involved shifting from being net importers
of financial capital to being net exporters, resulting
in large current account surpluses (Chart II.1). This
contradictory phenomenon was attributed to a
significant rise in saving rates in emerging market
economies (EMEs), especially in China, a dearth
of investment opportunities, and the accumulation
of large foreign exchange reserves by EMEs to
check their currency appreciation and as selfinsurance
against a sudden reversal of capital
flows. Many of these economies, particularly the
East Asian countries, began to build up large
amounts of foreign exchange reserves from the beginning of the current decade. Emerging market
countries saw these reserve stockpiles as welcome
‘war-chests’ to defend them from sudden capital
flow reversals of the sort that had occurred during
the Asian crisis.
Table 2.2: Current Account Balance |
(US$ billion) |
|
1990-94 |
1995-99 |
2000-04 |
2005 |
2006 |
2007 |
2008 |
2009 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
China |
5.5 |
18.6 |
37.6 |
160.8 |
253.3 |
371.8 |
426.1 |
283.8 |
France |
0.9 |
32.3 |
18.2 |
-9.1 |
-11.6 |
-25.9 |
-64.8 |
38.8 |
Germany |
-10.2 |
-19.4 |
36.5 |
142.8 |
188.4 |
253.8 |
245.7 |
160.6 |
India |
-3.8 |
-5.0 |
2.7 |
-10.3 |
-9.3 |
-11.3 |
-26.6 |
-25.9 |
Japan |
97.4 |
101.5 |
125.7 |
165.7 |
170.4 |
211.0 |
157.1 |
141.7 |
Korea |
-3.5 |
5.0 |
13.2 |
15.0 |
5.4 |
5.9 |
-5.8 |
42.7 |
Malaysia |
-3.2 |
0.6 |
10.4 |
20.7 |
25.8 |
29.2 |
38.9 |
32.0 |
Philippines |
-2.1 |
-2.3 |
-0.5 |
2.0 |
5.3 |
7.1 |
3.6 |
8.6 |
Russia |
3.1 |
8.5 |
41.0 |
84.4 |
94.3 |
77.0 |
102.4 |
47.5 |
Saudi Arabia |
-15.4 |
-3.4 |
23.2 |
90.1 |
99.1 |
93.5 |
132.5 |
20.5 |
South Africa |
1.5 |
-1.9 |
-1.5 |
-8.6 |
-13.9 |
-20.1 |
-19.6 |
-11.4 |
Switzerland |
14.3 |
24.9 |
32.5 |
52.2 |
59.5 |
43.5 |
11.9 |
43.1 |
Thailand |
-6.9 |
-0.8 |
5.3 |
-7.6 |
2.3 |
15.7 |
1.6 |
20.3 |
Turkey |
-2.2 |
-1.9 |
-5.7 |
-22.1 |
-31.9 |
-37.7 |
-41.3 |
-13.6 |
United Arab Emirates |
2.9 |
2.3 |
8.0 |
22.6 |
36.2 |
19.5 |
22.2 |
-7.0 |
United Kingdom |
-21.9 |
-13.3 |
-34.6 |
-59.8 |
-80.8 |
-75.5 |
-40.7 |
-28.8 |
United States |
-66.5 |
-178.4 |
-485.5 |
-748.7 |
-803.5 |
-726.6 |
-706.1 |
-418.0 |
Note: (-) indicates deficit.
Source: World Economic Outlook database, International Monetary Fund. |
Table 2.3: Current Account Balance |
(Per cent to GDP) |
Country |
1990-94 |
1995-99 |
2000-04 |
2005 |
2006 |
2007 |
2008 |
2009 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
China |
1.4 |
1.9 |
2.4 |
7.2 |
9.5 |
11.0 |
9.4 |
5.8 |
France |
0.0 |
2.0 |
1.3 |
-0.4 |
-0.5 |
-1.0 |
-2.3 |
-1.5 |
Germany |
-0.4 |
-0.8 |
1.4 |
5.1 |
6.5 |
7.6 |
6.7 |
4.8 |
India |
-1.3 |
-1.3 |
0.5 |
-1.3 |
-1.1 |
-1.0 |
-2.2 |
-2.1 |
Japan |
2.4 |
2.3 |
2.9 |
3.6 |
3.9 |
4.8 |
3.2 |
2.8 |
Korea |
-1.0 |
1.9 |
2.1 |
1.8 |
0.6 |
0.6 |
-0.6 |
5.1 |
Malaysia |
-5.2 |
1.8 |
9.8 |
15.0 |
16.4 |
15.7 |
17.5 |
16.7 |
Philippines |
-4.0 |
-2.8 |
-0.7 |
2.0 |
4.5 |
4.9 |
2.2 |
5.3 |
Russia |
0.9 |
3.5 |
11.2 |
11.0 |
9.5 |
6.0 |
6.2 |
3.9 |
Saudi Arabia |
-11.7 |
-2.4 |
10.6 |
28.5 |
27.8 |
24.3 |
27.9 |
5.5 |
South Africa |
1.2 |
-1.3 |
-0.7 |
-3.5 |
-5.3 |
-7.0 |
-7.1 |
-4.0 |
Switzerland |
5.7 |
8.8 |
10.8 |
14.0 |
15.2 |
10.0 |
12.4 |
8.7 |
Thailand |
-6.4 |
1.0 |
4.2 |
-4.3 |
1.1 |
6.3 |
-0.6 |
7.7 |
Turkey |
-0.9 |
-0.8 |
-1.6 |
-4.6 |
-6.0 |
-5.8 |
-5.7 |
-2.3 |
United Arab Emirates |
8.3 |
4.6 |
9.9 |
16.9 |
22.1 |
9.4 |
8.5 |
-3.1 |
United Kingdom |
-2.1 |
-1.0 |
-2.0 |
-2.6 |
-3.3 |
-2.7 |
-1.5 |
-1.3 |
United States |
-1.0 |
-2.1 |
-4.5 |
-5.9 |
-6.0 |
-5.2 |
-4.9 |
-2.9 |
Memo: |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Euro Area |
n.a. |
0.9 |
0.4 |
0.4 |
0.4 |
0.4 |
-0.8 |
-0.4 |
Note: (-) indicates deficit.
Source: World Economic Outlook Database, April 2010, International Monetary Fund. |
 |
Savings Glut Hypothesis
2.15 The large global current account
imbalances also got reflected in the savingsinvestment
behaviour in both emerging and
advanced nations. This is why global imbalances
are now universally ascribed to the ‘savings glut’
hypothesis, which states that the US current
account deficit was driven by a savings glut in the
rest of the world, especially in emerging market
countries (Bernanke, 2005). While in the US the
gap between savings and investment almost
doubled from minus 2.7 per cent of GDP in 2001 to
minus 5.6 per cent of GDP in 2008, the opposite
was observed in the case of EMEs where excess
savings led to significant current account surpluses.
2.16 There was a significant rise in global gross
saving as a percentage of GDP, from about 21.4
per cent in 2001 to almost 24.2 per cent in 2007.
Most of the increase reflected the relatively high
saving rate of the EMEs in the post-Asian crisis
period, where a more than three-fold rise in
aggregate saving between 2001 and 2007 had lifted the marginal propensity to save to 43 per cent (BIS,
2009). In gross terms, the share of EMEs in global
saving rose from 25 per cent in 1992–96 to 30 per
cent in 2003 and 37 per cent in 2007. In
comparison, the EME share of world GDP did not
rise quite so rapidly, moving from 21 per cent in
1992–96 to 31 per cent in 2007. Within emerging
markets, the rise in average saving rates was
significant for China and the Middle East. The US,
in contrast, has observed a decline in savings since
2001 (Table 2.4).
2.17 The precautionary motive was the main
reason behind the high savings in these economies. The absence of adequate safety nets and the
consequent need for self-insurance coupled with
financial market underdevelopments in emerging
economies have led private agents in these
economies to oversave, particularly in countries
such as China (Francia, 2009). The one-child policy in China has also contributed to the rise in
savings as children are substitutes for life-cycle
savings (Modigliani and Cao, 2004). Besides, as
per capita income increases at high rates,
consumption usually does not keep pace with
income and the savings rate tends to increase.
Higher migration from rural to urban areas added
to the rise in savings as the consumption habits
of the migrants remained unchanged even though
their income rose.
2.18 The saving-investment balances also
differed across EME regions in the pre-crisis period.
In China, gross saving exceeded gross investment
by a large margin: the saving rate reached 59 per
cent of GDP in 2008 even though China maintained
one of the highest investment rates in the world of
around 49 per cent of GDP. While India also saw a
sharp rise in the saving rate, the savingsinvestment
gap remained negative due to an
equivalent increase in the investment rate. Other
Asian emerging economies saw only a modest rise
in saving and investment rates between 2003 and
2007, with both remaining below the levels
preceding the Asian crisis.
2.19 Higher net savings by oil exporters are also
believed to have contributed to the global savings
glut. Consequent upon the sharp rise in oil prices,
the current account surpluses of oil exporters,
notably in the Middle East and also in countries
such as Russia, Nigeria, and Venezuela, rose as
oil revenues surged. The collective current account
surplus of the Middle East and Africa rose by more
than US$ 115 billion between 1996 and 2004. As a
percentage of GDP, the current account surplus of
the Middle East rose from around 1.0 per cent in
2000 to about 18.5 per cent in 2005. Thus,
changes in the collective current account position
of the developing world resulted in many
developing and emerging-market countries becoming large net lenders to the rest of the world
rather than net borrowers.
Table 2.4: Savings and Investment |
(as a percentage of GDP) |
Countries |
Savings |
Investment |
1995 |
2001 |
2007 |
2008 |
1995 |
2001 |
2007 |
2008 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
Advanced Economies |
21.4 |
20.0 |
19.9 |
18.8 |
21.6 |
20.6 |
21 |
20.4 |
United States |
16.0 |
16.4 |
14.2 |
11.9 |
18.6 |
19.1 |
18.8 |
17.5 |
Japan |
30.5 |
26.9 |
28.9 |
26.7 |
28.4 |
24.8 |
24.1 |
23.5 |
Germany |
21.1 |
19.5 |
25.8 |
25.7 |
22.2 |
19.5 |
18.3 |
19.3 |
United Kingdom |
15.9 |
15.4 |
15.3 |
15.1 |
17.2 |
17.4 |
18.2 |
16.8 |
Others |
21.4 |
22.5 |
22.5 |
21.9 |
20.1 |
21.2 |
23.5 |
23.2 |
Emerging Economies |
26.8 |
26.6 |
35.4 |
36.6 |
27.6 |
25.1 |
30.2 |
31.8 |
China |
42.1 |
37.6 |
57.6 |
59.0 |
41.9 |
36.3 |
46.6 |
49.0 |
India |
24.4 |
23.4 |
37.7 |
36.3 |
26.0 |
23.1 |
38.7 |
39.1 |
Other Emerging Asia |
33.3 |
28.9 |
30.9 |
30.4 |
33.9 |
24.6 |
25.1 |
26.3 |
Middle East |
24.0 |
33.3 |
49.6 |
50.8 |
20.9 |
24.8 |
26.5 |
26.7 |
Source: World Economic Outlook, October 2009, International Monetary Fund. |
2.20 One view of the savings glut hypothesis is
that there was an investment drought rather than a
savings glut. The East Asian crisis has exerted
permanent depressing effects on investment in
these economies (Barro and Lee, 2003). While the
savings rate in most East Asian EMEs, which has
generally remained higher than in the industrialised
countries, exhibited a modest decline, investment
rates showed sharper declines, resulting in the
widening of the savings-investment gap in the
EMEs. A corroborative view is that the consumption
glut in the advanced countries has exacerbated the
current account disequilibrium across the world.
Excess consumption combined with higher
leveraging in a loosely regulated and unsupervised
financial system fuelled the housing bubble
(Francia, 2009).
Inadequate Exchange Rate Flexibility
2.21 Several emerging market economies as
part of their export-led growth strategy were
deliberately maintaining undervalued exchange
rates. Between 2003 and mid-2008, many EMEs
experienced rapid integration with the advanced
economies and became substantially dependent on
exports as an engine of growth. The share of
exports of goods and services to GDP for China
rose from about 23 per cent during 1992-95 to
around 30 per cent during 2003 and further to
around 43 per cent during 2007 before coming
down to 35 per cent of GDP in 2008 (Table 2.5).
For emerging Asia as a whole, exports rose from
already high levels in the pre-Asian crisis period to
about 75 per cent of GDP in 2007. Reserves were
accumulated in the context of foreign exchange
interventions intended to prevent any exchangerate
appreciation (Michael Dooley et al., 2004).
Countries typically pursued export-led growth
because domestic demand was thought to be
insufficient to fully employ domestic resources.
Further, these surpluses were intended to build up
precautionary reserves to deal with sudden stops
in capital flows.
Table 2.5: Exports of Goods and Services |
(Percentage of GDP) |
Country |
1992-95 |
2003 |
2005 |
2007 |
2008 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
China |
23.3 |
29.6 |
37.4 |
42.5 |
35.0 |
France |
21.8 |
25.6 |
26.1 |
26.5 |
.. |
Germany |
23.4 |
35.6 |
40.9 |
46.7 |
.. |
India |
10.0 |
14.8 |
19.9 |
21.2 |
24.0 |
Japan |
9.3 |
12.0 |
14.3 |
.. |
.. |
Korea |
27.1 |
35.4 |
39.3 |
41.9 |
52.9 |
Malaysia |
84.5 |
106.9 |
117.5 |
110.2 |
.. |
Philippines |
32.7 |
49.6 |
47.6 |
42.5 |
36.9 |
Russia |
39.4 |
35.2 |
35.2 |
30.5 |
33.4 |
Saudi Arabia |
36.4 |
46.1 |
60.9 |
65.0 |
69.9 |
South Africa |
22.2 |
28.1 |
27.4 |
31.6 |
36.3 |
Switzerland |
36.2 |
44.0 |
48.8 |
.. |
.. |
Thailand |
38.9 |
65.7 |
77.2 |
76.0 |
.. |
Turkey |
17.3 |
23.0 |
21.9 |
22.0 |
23.6 |
United Arab Emirates |
71.4 |
79.0 |
92.6 |
.. |
.. |
United Kingdom |
25.9 |
25.5 |
26.5 |
25.9 |
.. |
United States |
10.0 |
10.0 |
11.0 |
11.9 |
12.9 |
.. : Not Available.
Source : World Development Indicators, World Bank Online Database. |
2.22 This argument, however, puts excessive
emphasis on exchange rate policy. The existence
of excess demand for an extended period in the
developed economies was more influenced by their
own macroeconomic and monetary policies, and may
have continued even with more flexible exchange
rate policies in EMEs. The argument is based on
the premise that low-priced consumer goods and
services from EMEs were available worldwide. Yet,
other regions such as the Euro area as a whole did
not exhibit large current account deficits throughout
the current decade. In fact, it exhibited a surplus
except for a minor deficit in 2008. Thus, even with
flexible exchange rate policies in some of the EMEs
the US current account deficit would have continued
to remain large, though the source of imports for the
US could have varied. The perceived lack of
exchange rate flexibility in the Asian EMEs cannot,
therefore, fully explain the large and growing current
account deficits in the US (Mohan, 2009).
2.23 The current account surpluses of the
emerging countries were used to purchase assets
in economies with market-based financial systems, such as the US. The depth of the US financial
markets together with rapid innovation of new
products for effective risk management has made
the US an attractive destination for global investors’
funds. Another factor is the special international
status of the US dollar. Because the dollar is the
leading international reserve currency, and
because some emerging-market countries use the
dollar as a numeraire when managing the values
of their own currencies, the saving flowing out of
the developing world has been directed relatively
more into dollar-denominated assets, such as U.S.
Treasury securities.
Monetary Policy Easing and Low Real Interest
Rates
2.24 The global imbalances were accentuated
by the excessively loose monetary policy in
advanced economies, especially the US. To some
extent the lack of adequate exchange rate flexibility
in some EMEs, which gave rise to excess liquidity
and low interest rates, exacerbated the problem.
In fact, since the technology stocks meltdown in
2000, there has been significant monetary
accommodation by the major economies such as
the US, the Euro area and Japan, particularly during
the first half of the decade. The US Fed funds rate
remained at its lowest when compared with the
previous two decades. The real interest rate2 in the
United States was consistently below 1 per cent
from mid-2001 up to the end of 2005; indeed, for
much of this period it was negative (Chart II.2). It
was generally accepted that the Fed had followed
an excessively loose monetary policy in 2002-2006
(Taylor, 2007). In response to sluggish growth in
the Euro area, the ECB held short-term real interest
rates below 1 per cent for most of the period
between mid-2001 and 2005; in Japan, real interest
rates hovered around 0 to 1 per cent for most of
the past decade. The low interest rates were
possible because of improved macroeconomic
performance in terms of not only higher growth and
low inflation, but also in terms of their reduced volatility. The period since the early 1990s which
witnessed substantial decline in macroeconomic
volatility in the US economy was termed as ‘Great
Moderation’. Bernanke (2004) offered three
explanations for this phenomenon, which include
structural change (institutional reforms,
globalisation and technological progress), improved
macroeconomic policies (explicit focus on price
stability) and good luck (smaller and infrequent
shocks). Moreover, relatively cheaper goods and
services from China and other EMEs helped keep
measured inflation low in the advanced economies.
 |
2.25 Along with a fall in short-term real interest
rates, the long-term real interest rates also
remained low during the first half of the current
decade. There are two different views on this. First,
given the global savings glut, one theory suggests
that the real long-term interest rate must fall to
establish global equilibrium at a higher level of
investment (Bernanke, 2005). The other theory is
that financial crises and high saving in emerging
markets, combined with limited financial
development, created a global shortage of low-risk
assets, leading to lower long-term bond rates
(Caballero et al., 2008).
2.26 The low interest rate regime had a variety
of effects. Low interest rates combined with ample
liquidity provided the impetus for strong credit
growth in a number of economies, and led to a
build-up of domestic imbalances. For instance,
credit in the United States and the United Kingdom
rose annually by 7 per cent and 10 per cent,
respectively, between 2003 and mid-2007. While
cheap credit formed the basis for the housing boom
and the dramatic rise in household revolving debt,
the low interest rate also increased the present
discounted value of the revenue streams arising
from earning assets, thereby driving up asset prices
and creating asset bubbles. Real housing prices in
the United States, the United Kingdom and a
number of European countries increased by more
than 30 per cent between 2003 and 2007. Monetary
policy, however, failed to respond to this asset price
inflation, guided by the now notorious Greenspan
orthodoxy, according to which, first, asset price
bubbles are hard to identify on a real-time basis
and the fundamental factors that drive asset prices
are not directly observable. Second, monetary
policy is too blunt an instrument to counteract asset
price booms. And third, a central bank cannot
presume to know more than the market because
financial markets are all-efficient, rational and selfcorrecting.
Thus, it was considered more costeffective
for monetary policy to wait for the bubble
to burst and clean up afterwards rather than prick
the bubble in advance (Subbarao, 2010).
2.27 Further, at unusually low levels of interest
rates, financial institutions found it difficult to
generate the returns promised in their generally
long-term nature of contracts, which induced them
to take on more risks in the hope of generating the
returns needed to remain profitable. The credit
boom, therefore, created grounds for rapid financial
innovations and increased risk-taking behaviour.
Even as financial imbalances were building up,
however, macroeconomic stability was maintained
(a reflection of Great Moderation), which
encouraged under-pricing of risks. The immediate
cause was the ‘originate and distribute’ mortgage
model and structured finance products like assetbacked securities (ABS) and collateralised debt
obligations (CDOs), which facilitated a general
increase in risk-taking. The housing boom, the
surge in debt-financed consumer expenditure and
the search for yield distorted the macroeconomic
structure in many economies.
2.28 Thus, global imbalances accompanied by
a ‘savings glut’ in the emerging economies and
loose monetary policy in the US and other
advanced economies led to an era of low real
interest rates and rapid search for yield that resulted
in many of the financial excesses. Both these
factors were clear precursors of unsustainable
bubbles, which were ignored in general because
of the pre-crisis phase of high global growth with
low inflation (Chakrabarthy, 2009). Theoretically,
the period after 2000 can be characterised as a
period when both the IS and the LM curves shifted
to the left, thus maintaining output at low interest
rates (Portes, 2009). Concern had been expressed
that the continued widening of global imbalances
could have a disorderly unwinding with a sudden
stop of capital flows from emerging markets to the
US that would trigger a crisis in the US leading to
substantial dollar depreciation (Obstfeld and
Rogoff, 2005). However, the trigger for the crisis
came not from the global imbalances but from the
housing bubble in the US economy. Even as
financial imbalances were building up,
macroeconomic stability was maintained, which in
turn, encouraged under-pricing of risks. Financial
innovations, regulatory arbitrage, lending
malpractices, excessive use of the originate-anddistribute
model, together with securitisation of subprime
loans and their bundling into AAA tranches
without risk being adequately assessed culminated
into excessive leverage of financial market entities
in the United States.
Domestic Imbalances in the United States
2.29 While global imbalances represent the
general macroeconomic or “macrofinancial”
explanation for the current crisis, the immediate
explanation, which in a sense complements the
former, focuses on uneven functioning of the US housing market and the shortcomings of specific
types of financial products which recently gained
prominence in the US.
Functioning of US Housing Market
2.30 Until the mid-1990s, the bulk of housing
loans in the US mortgage market was given to prime
borrowers. Since the late 1990s, the US home loan
growth has been very high, registering even higher
growth rates than the US GDP. A major part of this
lending was essentially sub-prime lending. Within
12 years, their share in total mortgage origination
jumped from 4.5 per cent in 1994 to more than 20
per cent in 2006 (Table 2.6). Sub-prime lending
refers to the practice of making loans to borrowers
who do not qualify for market interest rates because
of their poor credit history or the inability to prove
that they have adequate resources to support the
monthly installments of the loan. Sub-prime loans
or mortgages are risky for both creditors and
debtors because of the combination of high interest
rates, bad credit history and murky personal
financial situations often associated with sub-prime
applicants. Except during the recessionary years
of 2001 and 2002, (following the bursting of the dotcom
bubble) when the house price (Case-Shiller) inflation showed some deceleration, sub-prime
lending exhibited strong growth, particularly during
the period 2003-06.
2.31 On the demand side, the low interest rates
to make housing affordable for everyone increased
housing prices. The combination of the ‘originateto-
distribute’ mortgage model and the securitisation
of loans together with rapid innovation in financial
products on the supply side resulted in a large
increase in the availability of funds and made house
loans attractive. While credit quantity increased, its
quality got eroded. Most of these loans were with
low margin money and with low teaser payments.
2.32 Under any conventional banking
arrangement, when a bank provides a housing loan,
it has to assume the credit risk (risk of borrower
default), the market risk (risk of the interest rate
changing over the tenure of the loan), and the
liquidity risk (since long-term illiquid housing loans
could be issued against liquid deposit liabilities).
With the creation of a secondary market for
mortgages, these risks, namely, credit risk, market
risk, and liquidity risk could be shifted from the
banks to the mortgage agencies. This system was
functioning in the US from 1938 when the Federal National Mortgage Association (FNMA), commonly
known as Fannie Mae, was established. Fannie
Mae began buying mortgages from banks and other
originators, thereby supporting mortgage lending,
especially for low- and middle-income families. In
1968, the activities of Fannie Mae were privatised
and de-linked from the Federal budget, and the
emphasis shifted to mortgage-backed securities
(MBSs), which were intended to help Fannie Mae
shift credit, market, and liquidity risk to the market
by pooling mortgages, securitising them, and selling them in the market. The MBSs derived their value
from the cash flows associated with the pool of
mortgages. In 1970, the Federal Home Loan
Mortgage Corporation (FHLMC), commonly known
as Freddie Mac, was set up to compete with the
privatised Fannie Mae and also to further boost the
MBSs market. As a result, with a large percentage
of ‘prime’ home loans securitised and sold through
these two institutions, the housing finance market
had shifted from an ‘originate-and-hold’ basis to an
‘originate-and-distribute’ mode (Box II.1).
Table 2.6: Mortgage Originations |
Year |
Total Mortgage Originations (US$ billion) |
Sub-prime Originations (US$ billion) |
Prime and Alt-A Originations (US$ billion) |
Sub-prime Share in Total Originations (% of $ value) |
Sub-prime Mortgage- Backed Securities (US$ billion) |
Sub-prime Originations Securitised (% of $ value) |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
1994 |
773 |
35 |
738 |
4.5 |
NA |
NA |
1995 |
636 |
65 |
571 |
10.2 |
NA |
NA |
1996 |
785 |
97 |
689 |
12.3 |
NA |
NA |
1997 |
839 |
125 |
734 |
14.5 |
NA |
NA |
1998 |
1,430 |
150 |
1,280 |
10.5 |
NA |
NA |
1999 |
1,275 |
160 |
1,115 |
12.5 |
NA |
NA |
2000 |
1,048 |
138 |
910 |
13.2 |
NA |
NA |
2001 |
2,215 |
190 |
2,025 |
8.6 |
95 |
50.4 |
2002 |
2,885 |
231 |
2,654 |
8.0 |
121 |
52.7 |
2003 |
3,945 |
335 |
3,610 |
8.5 |
202 |
60.5 |
2004 |
2,920 |
540 |
2,380 |
18.5 |
401 |
74.3 |
2005 |
3,120 |
625 |
2,495 |
20.0 |
507 |
81.2 |
2006 |
2,980 |
600 |
2,380 |
20.1 |
483 |
80.5 |
Source : The Subprime Lending Crisis - Report and Recommendations by the majority staff of the Joint Economic Committee, October 2007. |
2.33 Thus, securitisation of loans was not
something new. It was prevalent in the US market
from the 1930s. However, only the prime loans sold
on to agencies like Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac
were being securitised until recently. Moreover, the
loan portfolio bought by these agencies conformed
to certain underwriting standards. However, what
was new in the current decade was the extension
of securitisation to sub-prime loans and dilution of
the underwriting standards.
Box II.1
Originate-to-Distribute Model
The global banking system has seen a transformation in
terms of lending practices. Bank credit has evolved from
its traditional “relationship banking” model to the
“transaction-oriented” model. Bank credit has been
transformed from the “Originate-to-Hold (OTH)” model,
where the borrower’s loan remains on the balance sheet
of the lender till the time the loan gets matured/written off,
to an Originate-to-Distribute (OTD) model, where banks
can originate loans, earn their fees, and then distribute
them to other investors. The OTD model has emerged over
the past two decades in response to the explosive growth
in the secondary syndicated loan market3. The reliance
on the OTD model has increased over the period because
of the advantages associated with this model, such as
diversification of risk, capital relief and lower cost of capital.
Depending on the nature of a bank’s private information
about a loan, the uncertainty in a loan’s potential payoff
can be decomposed into two components: one for which
the bank’s informational advantage is relatively small and
the other for which such advantage is relatively large. The
bank can enter into a secondary syndicated loan market
and use a credit-derivative contract to transfer the former
risks to outsiders, while retaining the risks at the bank in
the case of the latter. As the bank’s informational
advantage is unlikely to be constant over the life of the
loan, there is scope to leverage upon the opportunity. Thus,
the OTD Model has the capacity to distribute risk widely
and efficiently.
It has been argued that the lack of transparency in the
OTD model has been one reason for the crisis in the credit
market. With the presence of secondary markets, lenders
were able to bundle the loans into securities in order to make money out of them, thus helping to spur the market
boom that was at the heart of the financial crisis.
Moreover, there was no incentive in ex-post monitoring
of the loans issued by the originating banks as there was
no direct link between the originator and the borrower of
the loan. If a bank holds a loan, it has a greater incentive
to monitor the loan (and thus increase its probability of
repayment) than if it sells it. The breakdown of lending
relationships is expected to have an adverse impact on
the decision-making of borrowers as they might start making sub-optimal investments and operating decisions.
Thus, even good loans might end up with bad performance.
Also, there were certain “unknown risks” originating from
the structured products created in recent years bundled
with traditional asset-backed securities and new products
based on sub-prime mortgages. This created pervasive
uncertainty about where the risks were concentrated and
how sensitive they might be to the economic cycle. In
this environment, everyone suddenly became suspect
when things turned wrong as a result of the crisis situation
in all segments of the economy. Empirical evidence also
supports the fact that the OTD model has resulted in the
origination of inferior quality mortgages and the
underperformance of borrowers involved in the active
secondary market (Brendt et al., 2009; Purnanandam,
2009).
 |
All this does not mean that OTD should be abandoned
as the secondary syndicated loan market. There is no
wisdom in throwing the baby out with the bath water. The
OTD model has several advantages and it provides
enhanced liquidity and leverage opportunities to financial
agents. Therefore, steps need to be taken to make this
model more resilient.
Measures to make OTD more resilient
-
Include additional disclosure requirements and make
available to investors relevant information about the
risks inherent in the securitisation structures.
-
Keep a certain proportion of loans on the balance sheet
of the originators to limit the moral hazard and adverse
selection problems.
-
Rebuild the risk management practices of banks so
that there is an effective analysis of all potential risks
involved in lending to a particular project. The turmoil
showed that institutions using the originate-todistribute
model poorly managed the non-credit risks associated with the securitisation business, such as
market risk, liquidity risk, concentration risk and, of
course, pipeline risk. This means that market participants
need to have adequate controls over their exposures,
including effective scenario analyses and stresstesting
procedures.
-
Align the incentives of all participants – originators,
arrangers, managers, distributors, credit rating agencies
and investors – so that no participant has an unfair
advantage.
-
Make the role played by the credit rating agencies more
responsible as their information creates the basis for
decision-making by various financial institutions.
References
-
Berndt, Antje and Anurag Gupta. 2009. “Moral Hazard
and Adverse Selection in the Originate-to-Distribute
Model of Bank Credit.” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 56.
-
Purnanandam, Amiyatosh K. 2009. “Originate-to-Distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis.”
AFA 2010 Atlanta Meetings Paper.
-
Duffee, Gregory R. and Chunsheng Zhou. 2001. “Credit
Derivatives in Banking: Useful Tools for Managing
Risk?” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 48.
-
Parlour, Christine A. and Guillaume Plantin. 2008.“Loan Sales and Relationship Banking.” The Journal of Finance, Vol. LXIII, No. 3.
-
_____ . 2008. “The Incentive Structure of the Originate
and Distribute Model.” European Central Bank,
December.
-
G20. 2008. ‘‘Study Group on Global Credit Market
Disruptions’’. Paper prepared by Australia, October.
Use of Complex Derivatives and Structured
Finance Products
2.34 The housing boom generated tremendous
interest in the market for MBS, collateralised debt
obligations (CDOs) and other complex derivative
instruments. The ferocious search for yield led to
the generation of new toxic financial instruments
through the process of securitisation and creation
of structured finance products.
2.35 The US housing market prior to the crisis
saw securitisation getting expanded to include a
gamut of new products ranging from standard MBSs
or, more generally, asset-backed securities (ABS),
to include a range of structured finance products,
including structured MBS and ABS, CDOs, and
asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP).
2.36 “Structured” finance normally entails
aggregating multiple underlying risks (such as
market and credit risks) by pooling instruments
subject to those risks (e.g., bonds, loans, or
mortgage-backed securities) and then dividing the
resulting cash flows into “tranches,” or slices paid
to different holders (IMF, GFSR, 2008). Unlike a
simple MBS (discussed earlier), complex MBS are
structured or sliced into different risk tranches. In a
simple three-tranche example, the structure for the
security might include (in order of increasing risk)
a ‘senior’, ‘mezzanine’ and an ‘equity’ tranche. Risk
and returns are lowest for the senior tranche and
accordingly have the highest credit rating. The
‘mezzanine tranche’ comes next, with much greater
risk and return in relation to the senior tranche, and
hence carry a below-investment grade rating. The
‘equity tranche’, the third and final layer from the
slicing, is the most risky and generally carries no
rating. Default on the underlying pool of MBSs
would imply maximum loss to the equity tranche.
In the absence of default, the return on the equity
tranche would be the highest. It is basically the
hedge funds which invested in the equity tranches
to get the highest returns. Structured finance
differs from securitisation in that the cash flows
are not “tranched” and are instead provided to
holders of securitised instruments on a pro rata
basis. In fact, securitisation diversifies risks by
pooling instruments.
2.37 Given the high risk of sub-prime mortgagebacked
securities, sometimes it became difficult to
entice investors to purchase such securities. In
such circumstances, the MBS were bundled up
again into CDOs with the support of a good rating.
The CDO issuances saw a substantial surge during
the period prior to the crisis (Table 2.7). High-rated
debt was again created from seemingly low quality collateral. The underlying asset exposures became
more opaque and investors increasingly relied on
credit ratings to assess credit quality. The
asymmetric information (or Akerlof’s lemon)
problem could be seen at its starkest in the case of
CDOs, with buyers having no information about the
underlying risk and blindly believing in the ratings,
while the sellers took advantage of this lack of
information to sell underlying assets with high risk
as highly-rated assets with low risk (Pattnaik, 2009).
This process of rebundling and restructuring was
repeated multiple times to produce CDO squared,
CDO cubed and even multiples. This created the
so-called Matryoshka or ‘Russian Doll’ structure
(Chart II.3). Thus, exposure to sub-prime risk was created in an almost unlimited way (G-20 Study
Group on Global Credit Market Disruptions).
Table 2.7: Global Issuance of Credit Debt Obligations (CDOs) |
(US$ billion) |
|
2005 |
2006 |
2007 |
2008 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
Underlying Guarantees |
271.8 |
520.6 |
481.6 |
56.1 |
High-Yield Loans |
71.2 |
171.9 |
138.8 |
23.7 |
Investment Grade Bonds |
4.0 |
24.9 |
78.6 |
14.7 |
High-Yield Bonds |
3.1 |
0.9 |
2.1 |
- |
Structured Finances |
176.6 |
307.7 |
259.2 |
16.6 |
Mixed Guarantees |
0.1 |
Neg. |
- |
- |
Other Swaps |
2.5 |
0.7 |
1.1 |
- |
Others |
4.3 |
14.4 |
1.7 |
1.0 |
Source: Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association, 2009. |
 |
2.38 In this context, concerns have been raised
about the ratings given by the rating agencies,
the models that they used as well as their role in the overall sub-prime crisis (Box II.2). Over 80
per cent of these sub-prime structured products
were rated with the highest ratings i.e., AAA by
the CRAs. Thus, the period prior to the crisis
witnessed the highest form of financial
sophistication that managed to turn lead into gold (Ferguson, 2008). Credit rating agencies are now
under scrutiny for giving investment-grade ratings
to derivative instruments like mortgage-based
CDOs. Rating agencies lowered the credit ratings
on US$ 1.9 trillion in MBSs between Q3 of 2007
to Q2 of 2008, another indicator that their initial
ratings were not accurate.
Box II.2
Credit Rating Agencies (CRAs): Boon or Bane?
Need for Credit Rating Agencies
Credit Rating Agencies (CRAs) are mainly commercial
institutions which earn revenue for the publication and
evaluation of the creditworthiness of their clients. They
have been playing an important role in the management
of financial market risk, particularly in global securities and
banking markets: they issue creditworthiness opinions that
help to overcome the information asymmetry that exists
between those issuing debt instruments and those
investing in these instruments. CRAs originated in the USA
at the turn of the 20th century and concentrated on rating
of corporate bonds. Their activities subsequently increased
in scope and scale. At present, no major type of security,
issuer or geographic area is excluded. CRAs now define
a truly global benchmark for credit risk. Since the Great
Depression, the CRA’s benchmark has also been used in
the regulation of financial markets. For example, banks
and certain other types of investors are only allowed to
hold lower risk securities rated ‘investment grade’ as per
the Basel norms. Over the past few decades these
companies have engaged in providing ratings for a wide
range of more complex financial instruments, known as
structured finance products.
Under the 2004 Basel Committee on Banking Supervision
(BCBS) new capital adequacy framework (Basel II), banks
can use ratings assigned by a recognised CRA in
determining credit risk weights for many of their institutional
credit exposures. Policymakers have been giving
increasing attention to CRAs over the past decade on a
number of occasions, generally coinciding with the
increase in stress in financial markets. Regulators
worldwide turned their attention to the role of CRAs
following their failure to weather the difficulties of East
Asian economies in July 1997, the corporate collapses at
the beginning of this century notably in the EU and the US
(Enron, Dotcom, and Parmalat), and the recent financial
crisis.
Role of Credit Rating Agencies in the Recent Financial
Crisis
CRAs were close to the origin of the problems with subprime
markets as they were giving favourable opinions on instruments that were financially engineered to give high
confidence to investors. The investors – relying on CRAs’
expertise – often took little or no interest in the risk
characteristics of these instruments, the performance of
underlying assets and the general market outlook. The
CRAs gave AAA ratings to numerous issues of sub-prime
mortgage-backed securities, many of which were
subsequently downgraded to junk status. Critics cite poor
economic models, conflicts of interest, and lack of effective
regulation as reasons for the rating agencies’ failure.
Another factor is the market’s excessive reliance on
ratings, which has been reinforced by numerous laws and
regulations that use ratings as a criterion for permissible
investments or as a factor in required capital levels.
CRAs helped to develop the Mortgage Based Securities
(MBS) and Collateralised Debt Obligations (CDOs) that
sparked the crisis. CRAs advised issuers on how to
structure and prioritise the tranches of an MBS or a CDO.
The goal was to help issuers squeeze the maximum profit
from a CDO or an MBS by maximising the size of its highest
rated tranches. The purpose of tranching was to create at
least one class of assets with a higher credit rating than
the average rating of a CDO or an MBS’s underlying asset
pool. CRAs rated each tranche based on the
creditworthiness of the loans in that tranche and its priority.
Tranches got higher credit ratings by “prioritisation”:
issuers guaranteed that the “senior” tranches would be
paid before “junior” or “subordinated” tranches. At the
height of the housing boom, almost all senior tranches
got the highest rating possible, namely, AAA.
The CRAs failed to adequately assess the credit risks in
MBSs and CDOs. The CRAs held an over-optimistic view
of the housing market. Their rating model assumed that
housing prices would continue to increase generally. CRAs
underestimated the complexity of the MBSs and CDOs.
The SEC found that the growth in the quantity and
complexity of structured finance deals since 2002 proved
too much for some CRAs.
In July 2008, the SEC concluded that the CRAs failed to
manage conflicts of interest between MBS and CDO issuers and the CRAs. CRAs were supposed to serve investors,
but conflicts of interest led some CRAs to cater to MBS and
CDO issuers by inflating ratings. The causes of the conflicts
of interest include: (i) Relationship conflicts: CRAs have had
a close, ongoing working relationship with the largest MBS
and CDO issuers; (ii) Issuer-paid ratings: 98 per cent of the
ratings produced by the CRAs have been paid for by issuers,
not investors. The pay incentive led some CRAs to try to
inflate ratings of paying issuers in hopes of gaining repeat
business from those issuers; and (iii) Advising-rating
combination: CRAs advised issuers on how to structure
MBSs and CDOs to get high ratings. Then CRAs “confirmed”
that advice by issuing the “promised” ratings.
The furore over Enron, Dotcom and the recent sub-prime
crisis has led to calls for regulatory changes in the rating
industry. Regulatory issues are always extremely complex
and interdependent. The IOSCO (International Organisation
of Securities Commission) in its consultation paper of March
2008 laid down some important recommendations on the
functioning of the CRAs. These include:
-
A CRA should take steps to ensure that the decisionmaking
process for reviewing and potentially downgrading the current rating of a structured finance product is conducted in an objective manner.
-
CRAs should establish an independent function responsible for periodically reviewing both the
methodologies and models and the changes to the
methodologies and models used in the rating process.
-
CRAs should adopt reasonable measures to ensure that the information they use is of sufficient quality to support a credible rating.
-
Where a CRA rates a structured finance product, it
should provide investors and/ or subscribers
(depending on the CRA’s business model) with
sufficient information about its loss and cash-flow
analysis so that an investor allowed to invest in the
product can understand the basis for the CRA’s rating.
Studies have also suggested moving towards a system
where credit ratings are paid for by investors, and where
arrangers and servicers disclose for free the complete
data on the individual loans underlying the structured
finance products. As a second-best policy, the current
practice of issuers paying the CRAs may be continued.
The payment, however, has to be made upfront (the socalled
“Cuomo Plan”), irrespective of the rating issued,
and credit shopping (and paid advice by rating agencies
to issuers) should be banned (Pagano et al, 2009). The
need to enhance transparency by determining the
information that issuers and rating agencies must
disseminate to the investing public has also been
emphasised.
References
-
International Organisation of Securities Commission
(IOSCO). 2008. Consultation Paper, March.
-
Pagano, Marco and Paolo Volpin. 2009. Credit Ratings
Failures: Causes and Policy Options. In M.
Dewatripont, X. Freixas and R. Portes (Eds.).
Macroeconomic Stability and Financial Regulation: Key
Issues for the G-20 (pp.129-148). Center for Economic
and Policy Research.
Role of Hedge Funds
2.39 As a result of the slicing of risk and the
support of credit ratings, the CDOs could be
marketed to investors with different appetites for
risk. Investors, particularly hedge funds, who
wanted to maximise yield with higher risk exposure
would buy the equity tranche of the CDOs. Hedge funds further created leverage by borrowing against
the assets they added to their investment portfolio
(like CDOs and MBSs). For example, in the United
States, two hedge funds of Bear Stearns had large
leveraged exposure to CDOs. When the sub-prime
default concerns gripped the market, the values of
the CDOs were marked down, requiring the hedge
funds to face margin calls from brokers (that is,
demands for more assets to back the leverage).
Investors in the hedge funds recognised the
potential for losses and suddenly asked the funds
to return their investments. For the hedge funds,
the options were either to borrow more (which was
difficult and costlier in the face of the credit
squeeze) and repay the impatient investors or to
go for a ‘fire sale’ (of CDOs at falling value) and face the investors’ call on their investment with
them. The more extreme option was to default,
meaning not to pay back the investors on demand.
This is what Bear Stearns had to face when it
closed down two of its hedge funds that were
ultimately bailed out by the US Federal Reserve
and taken over by JP Morgan. The agency-wise
sub-prime exposures and losses in the US are
given in Table 2.8.
Regulatory Weaknesses
2.40 The sub-prime crisis is also viewed as the
best example of several weaknesses in the
regulatory structure for financial institutions in terms
of lax supervisory oversight and relaxation of
normal standards of prudent lending. Several
issues have been highlighted in this regard – lack
of countercyclical regulation; inability to recognise
systemic risks; the need for prudential regulation;
non-recognition of off-balance-sheet items of
banks; operation of non-banks beyond the
regulatory purview; the complex and nontransparent
nature of new financial instruments; and regulatory oversight of systemically important
financial institutions. Regulators in the financial
sector did not have adequate skills to cope with
rapid growth in the variety and complexity of
innovations in financial products in the markets.
Despite the prevalence of a well-established
regulatory structure in terms of capital requirements
and risk assessments, financial institutions found
it relatively easy to move to activities outside the
regulatory perimeter. While the regulatory capital
requirement did limit the build-up of leverage on
bank balance sheets, bank managers engaged in
various off-balance sheet activities to increase risk
and return without increasing the capital they were
required to hold.
Table 2.8: U.S. Sub-prime Exposures and Losses |
|
Exposure* |
Losses |
|
2005 |
2006 |
2007+ |
2005 |
2006 |
2007+ |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
|
Total amount (in billions of US dollars) |
Banks# |
155 |
264 |
127 |
-9 |
-63 |
-29 |
Hedge Funds |
70 |
98 |
78 |
-7 |
-27 |
-20 |
Insurance Companies |
78 |
106 |
84 |
-2 |
-21 |
-15 |
Finance Companies |
25 |
30 |
24 |
-1 |
-5 |
-4 |
Mutual Funds/Pension Funds |
15 |
18 |
14 |
-0 |
-3 |
-2 |
Total |
343 |
516 |
326 |
-18 |
-118 |
-70 |
|
As a per cent of total |
Banks# |
45 |
51 |
39 |
49 |
53 |
41 |
Hedge Funds |
20 |
19 |
24 |
37 |
23 |
29 |
Insurance Companies |
23 |
20 |
26 |
9 |
18 |
22 |
Finance Companies |
7 |
6 |
7 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
Mutual Funds/Pension Funds |
4 |
4 |
4 |
2 |
2 |
3 |
Total |
100.0 |
100.0 |
100.0 |
100.0 |
100.0 |
100.0 |
* Par amounts for securities and notional amounts for derivatives.
+ As of Nov. 2007;
# Including investment banks.
Source : Global Financial Stability Report, 2008. |
Role of Off-Balance Sheet Entities (OBSEs)
2.41 One of the major reasons for originators to
leverage their loan portfolio was that soon after they
originated the loan, the same was sold in the
secondary market, which left them free of any
financial responsibility. Banks failed to identify the
risks involved in the complex securitisation process.
Indirectly, banks’ balance sheets remained
exposed to developments in the sub-prime market
through off-balance sheet entities (OBSEs) such
as Structured Investment Vehicles (SIVs) that were
investing in MBSs and CDOs by borrowing in the
short-term commercial paper (CP) market. OBSEs,
such as SIVs, are entities that allow financial
institutions to transfer risk off their balance sheet
and permit exposures to remain mostly undisclosed
to regulators and investors; and achieve relief from
regulatory capital requirements under Basel I.
Although financial institutions were required to
disclose the nature of the relationship between the
parent and a subsidiary when the parent did not
own, directly or indirectly through subsidiaries,
more than half of the voting power (International
Accounting Standards 27.40) of the OBSEs, such
information was often in a footnote in a firm’s report
(GFSR, IMF, 2008). Banks with the objective of
meeting Basel I norms were engaged in a process
of continuous shifting of risk to the market through
securitisation of loans and the use of credit default swaps (CDS) to buy protection in the market, thus,
freeing up capital for more lending. This created a
‘shadow banking system’, which remained almost
completely unregulated (Box II.3).
2.42 Financial institutions transferred the
mortgage claims to SIVs they had established and
then the SIVs, by issuing and selling securitised
products, transferred the risks and returns to investors, earning commissions in the process. By
doing so, financial institutions could maintain their
own financial soundness and circumvent
restrictions on capital adequacy ratios, while
earning a steady flow of income. To generate
greater profit from these commissions, each of
which was small, it became necessary to expand
the provision of mortgage loans and engage in
securitisation on a large scale. This business model seems to have led to a relaxation of lending
standards and excessive mortgage lending. SIVs
first came to light during the Enron scandal. Since
then, their use has become widespread in the
financial world. In the years leading up to the crisis,
the top four U.S. depository banks moved off the
balance sheet an estimated US$ 5.2 trillion of
assets and liabilities into special purpose vehicles
or similar entities.
Box II.3
The Concept of Shadow Banking
The shadow banking system or the shadow financial
system consists of non-bank financial institutions which
play an increasingly critical role in lending businesses the
money necessary to operate. The term “shadow banking
system” is attributed to Paul McCulley who coined it at the
Jackson Hole Conference in 2007, where he defined it as
“the whole alphabet soup of levered up non-bank
investment conduits, vehicles, and structures”, though the
concept of credit growth by unregulated institutions (if not
the terminology) dates back to 1935 by Friedrich Hayek
(1935). By definition, shadow institutions do not accept
deposits like a depository bank and, therefore, are not
subject to the same regulations. Some complex legal
entities comprising the system include hedge funds, SIVs,
conduits, monolines, investment banks, and other nonbank
financial institutions. Many “shadow bank”-like
institutions and vehicles emerged in American and
European markets, between the years 2000 and 2008, and
played an important role in providing credit across the
global financial system.
Operationally, shadow institutions, like investment banks,
borrowed from investors in short-term, liquid markets (such
as the money market and commercial paper markets),
meaning that they would have to frequently repay and
borrow again from these investors. At the same time, they
used the funds to lend to corporations or to invest in longerterm,
less liquid (i.e., harder to sell) assets. In many cases,
the long-term assets purchased were MBSs/CDOs. When
the housing market began to deteriorate and the ability to
obtain funds from investors through investments such as
mortgage-backed securities declined, these investment
banks were unable to fund themselves. Investor refusal
or inability to provide funds via the short-term markets was
a primary cause of the failure of Bear Stearns and Lehman
Brothers during 2008.
Technically, these institutions are subject to market risk,
credit risk and especially liquidity risk, since their liabilities
are short-term while their assets are more long-term and
illiquid. This creates a potential problem in that they are
not depositary institutions and do not have direct or indirect
access to their central bank’s lender-of-last-resort support.
Therefore, during periods of market illiquidity, they could
go bankrupt if unable to refinance their short-term liabilities.
They were also highly leveraged. This meant that
disruptions in credit markets would make them subject to
rapid deleveraging, meaning that they would have to pay
off their debts by selling their long-term assets.
In early 2007, lending through the shadow banking system
slightly exceeded lending via the traditional banking system
based on outstanding balances. Analysts have placed
significant blame for the freezing of credit markets on a
“run” on the entities in the shadow banking system by their
counterparties (Geithner, 2008). The run on the shadow
banking system has been described as the “core of what
happened” to cause the crisis (Krugman, 2009). It has also
been stated that the so-called shadow banking system,
including securitisation of loans, is likely to be smaller and
subject to more regulatory oversight than before the
financial crisis (Bernanke, 2009).
References
-
Hayek F.A. 1935. “Prices and Production and Other
Works.” Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, Alabama.
-
IMF. 2008. “Global Financial Stability Report: Structured Finance: Issues of Valuation and
Disclosure”, Chapter 2, April.
-
Bernanke Ben S. 2009. “Semiannual Monetary Policy
Report to the Congress.” Before the Committee on
Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, Washington, D.C., February 24.
-
Geithner, Timothy. 2008. “Reducing Systemic Risk in
a Dynamic Financial System.” Remarks at Economic
Club of New York, June.
-
McCulley Paul, 2007. “Teton Reflections: Global
Central Bank Focus.” Jackson Hole Conference; August/September.
-
Krugman, Paul. 2009. “The Return of Depression
Economics and the Crisis of 2008.” W.W. Norton
Company Limited.
Role of Basel Norms
2.43 The Basel I minimum capital adequacy
requirement has generally been instrumental in
encouraging banks to shift risk from their balance
sheets through securitisation or through shadow
banking conduits in the way described above. Some
believe that if Basel II had been in place in more
countries, the recent stressful episode could have
been less severe. Implementation of Basel II in
more countries prior to the crisis would have helped
in addressing certain, if not all, sub-prime-related
problems. This could have happened by ensuring
capital charges even for off-balance sheet
exposures that were assumed through shadow
banking conduits, more risk-sensitive treatment for
securitisation-related exposures, greater risk
differentiation while changing the exposure from
prime to sub-prime loans or from corporate lending
to leveraged lending, greater disclosures and more
rigorous risk assessment frameworks within the
banks. Under Basel I, capital charges were not
required to be applied to supporting liquidity
facilities that essentially represent loan assurances/
guarantees of financial support to back an OBSE
with less than a one-year commitment, while they
were required for those with longer terms. For most
banks in the US and Europe, the implications for
the originating banks of these supporting facilities
were not fully realised until difficulties arose in early
August 20074. Basel II requires banks to hold
regulatory capital for various liquidity and other support facilities, thus, enhancing the transparency
to investors and regulators.
2.44 Although there are elements in Basel II that
would have reduced some of the pressures, it is
difficult to conclude that the event could have been
avoided (GFSR, 2008). Considering that Basel II
encourages the banks’ hedging of risk exposures
to lower risk weights on asset holdings, the use of
credit default swaps (CDSs) would have expanded.
While hedging credit risk through CDSs could be
helpful, counterparty risk to those issuing such
swaps is still present. Besides, while the enhanced
disclosure and capital requirements of Basel II
could discourage the originating banks from issuing
below-investment-grade instruments as higher
leverage and riskiness of exposures will be
accounted for more clearly in the bank’s capital
requirements, it could not have prevented another
crisis. Basel II’s excessive emphasis on ratings and
models for valuation and calculation of risks very
often distorts the true picture. In a macroeconomic
context, it has been argued that the implementation
of Basel II capital requirements could have a procyclical
effect on the business cycle. Specifically,
in an economic downturn, anticipated losses would
require banks to increase their capital (depending
upon the sensitivity of rating models to economic
conditions), putting further downward pressure on
the provision of credit, and thereby accentuating
the downturn. Incidentally, against this backdrop,
Basel II provisions are being improvised to take into
account some of these factors.
2.45 Besides, there have been a host of nonbank
financial institutions such as insurance
companies, hedge funds, pension funds, and
mutual funds that were not directly affected by the
disclosure requirements for OBSEs under Basel II,
yet they remained potential channels for systemic
risks. Hedge funds that were holding the riskiest
tranches of structured products are de facto not
subject to any disclosure requirements. While the recent turmoil strengthens the case for mandatory
disclosures by hedge funds5 before regulators, one
cannot deny that there needs to be a balance
between disclosure that provides market and
regulatory confidence while not constraining hedge
fund flexibility in contributing to the smooth
functioning of the market.
2.46 Thus, regulatory arbitrage between banks
and non-bank financial institutions and lack of coordination
among regulatory structures could also
have contributed to the crisis. Regulatory arbitrage
across borders was also misused to the maximum.
In a bid to attract financial services, regulators in
international financial centres, such as London and
New York, adopted a policy of relatively soft
regulations or what has been described as light
touch regulation. The eagerness to develop some
centres as global financial centres resulted in a race
to the bottom in regulation (Reddy, 2009b).
Risk Measurement, Accounting and Incentive
Structure
Risk Measurement
2.47 Another microeconomic cause of the crisis
is related to problems in risk measurement. Five
issues are relevant in this context. First, the use of
historical data was restricted to the very recent
period (period of Great Moderation) for pricing new
financial instruments, which yielded misleading
results. Risk was reduced through (1) hedging,
whereby two risks were thought to offset each other
because their payoffs were negatively correlated; and
(2) diversification, whereby risk was spread among
assets whose returns were less than perfectly
correlated. Though generally true, at times historical
correlations may lead to misleading results. Thus,
even very sophisticated statistical models failed to
accurately measure and price risks, resulting in
mismanagement of risks on many occasions. The
limitations of historical correlation was one of the
problems associated with securitising sub-prime
mortgages in the United States, whereby large
numbers of what were objectively low-quality loans were pooled together out of which a mix of highquality
and low-quality securities backed by the pool
were created (originate) and sold to an entirely new
class of borrowers (distribute). The major flaw,
however, was that originators generally retained
little of the default risk and, as the boom developed,
the quality of the loans progressively worsened.
Before the crisis, the ‘originate-and-distribute’
model worked well as it provided diversification on
the assumption that asset prices in various regions
of the world would not move together. For example,
before the crisis, investing globally was thought to
reduce risk, as prices in various regions of the world
would not move together. This assumption turned
out to be false. When asset prices that previously
moved independently (providing diversification) or
in opposite directions (providing a hedge) started
to move together, the risks rose instead of falling.
When the bad times came, correlations became
large and positive. What was risk reduction became
risk concentration.
2.48 Second, it was difficult to assess the low
probability of such large events. Measuring, pricing
and managing risk require modern statistical tools
based largely on historical experience. Given its
simplicity, the natural assumption is that returns of
many different assets are normally distributed (and
so have thin tails). And, although tail events are
infrequent, in reality they are more frequent than is
predicted by a normal distribution. Even though the
problem with assuming a normal distribution was
well known, the assumption persisted with the notso-
surprising result that insurance against
infrequent catastrophes was underpriced.
2.49 Third, apart from problems in measurement,
there were also governance problems in risk
management practices in financial institutions. The
financial institutions found it relatively easy to move
activities outside the regulatory perimeter through
structured investment vehicles. More generally, the
crisis showed that the enlarged financial sector –
comprising both traditional banks and an
increasingly important parallel financial system
comprising non-bank intermediaries and off- balance sheet entities – had become much riskier
than in the past. The failure of governance is also
evidenced by the failure of all relevant institutional
defences against serious financial instability. Thus,
the Board, the management, risk management
practices and internal controls allowed excesses.
The rating agencies, the advisors, the analysts and
the auditors failed to give an alert on the build-up
of risks, possibly due to relevant incentives or
counterparty dealings. The financial regulators
allowed these excesses to occur. Finally, the
market discipline on which reliance has generally
been placed and which may include media and
public opinion did not prevent these excesses.
2.50 Fourth, more generally, the crisis showed
that the enlarged financial sector – comprising both
traditional banks and an increasingly important
parallel financial system composed of non-bank
intermediaries and off-balance sheet entities – had
become much riskier than in the past. The absence
of a national uniform regulatory authority resulted
in oversight of the mortgage market and the scale
of the financial sector’s involvement in sub-prime
mortgage products. Multiple regulators facilitated
regulatory arbitrage by the market participants and
thus exacerbated the risks. Despite the fact that
financial markets had globalised, the framework for
cross-border regulation was weak.
2.51 Fifth, there was a large disconnect between
the risk officers and the top executives who are
the decision-makers. With the former rarely having
sufficient day-to-day contact with top decisionmakers,
they often could not communicate their
assessments effectively. Besides, on certain
occasions when what was happening was
profitable, it was difficult to get managers and
directors to listen (BIS, 2009).
Accounting Procedures
2.52 It is generally perceived that the accounting
procedures that the market participants followed
also contributed to the crisis. The accounting
standards were pro-cyclical, especially due to the
policy of mark-to-market rules of valuation of assets
and liabilities. Mark-to-market (MTM) is an accounting act of recording the price or value of a
security or portfolio to reflect its current market value
rather than its book value. However, considering that
not all securities are liquid enough to have a tradable
market price, they are marked at the fair value usually
based on a model. The model is fed with inputs for
which there are market prices (prices of similar
securities, interest rates, etc.) or assumptions about
the input values. The problem with MTM accounting
is that it relies on the notion that the market is an
asset’s best arbiter of value. Most of the time, that
is a fair assumption, but it breaks down in a market
crisis. When investors are gripped by fear, panic
selling can produce prices that are out of sync with
underlying asset values. Worse, a market may stop
trading altogether.
2.53 Given the large size of the market for
structured finance products and related derivatives
in the Over-the-Counter (OTC) markets prior to the
crisis, it had become nearly impossible to determine
their fair value. As is clear, in the recent crisis, fair
value accounting was at fault not for the values
chosen to represent various on-balance sheet
positions, but for the various off-balance sheet
extensions of commercial and investment banks to
warehouse risks that, for reputational reasons,
would have to be brought back onto the balance
sheet if and when cumulative losses developed.
Besides, at large and complex financial institutions,
individual managers had strong incentives to
discover and to exercise reporting options that
overstate their capital and understate their
exposure to loss. This expands their ability to
extract implicit subsidies that risk-taking can
generate from implicit safety-net support.
2.54 It is this potential for a complete reversal of
fortunes for the best performing financial firms just
because of mark-to-market accounting that has
necessitated a review of international accounting
norms. There is also a viewpoint that in creating
and deepening the securitisation crisis, the role of
fair value accounting is being overstated. In the US,
a major purpose of adopting fair-value accounting
was to require some of the developing losses at
troubled financial firms to be recognised and resolved more promptly than in the past. But in
reality, under fair value accounting, portfolio
positions were “marked to model” rather than to an
actual transaction price, thus providing the
opportunity to clever managers to adjust model
outcomes until they produce pre-specified results
(Caprio et al., 2008). This had more to do with the
incentive structure of the firm managers than with
the accounting norms.
Incentive Structure
2.55 The crisis highlighted the faults in the
incentive structure faced by investors and fund
managers. First, with regard to investors, as
income/ earning levels were growing, they failed to
pay due attention to the balance sheets of the banks
where they were doing business or of the finances
of the firms in which they were invested through
the purchase of equity or debt securities. Apart from
lack of knowledge, the belief that someone else was
watching – be it a trusted manager, an equity
analyst, a credit rating agency or the regulator –
made them assume that the system was
sophisticated and that their investments were safe,
while in reality the system was complex and opaque.
The complexity of the financial system and the
financial products was mistaken for sophistication
of the system (BIS, 2009).
2.56 Second, managers of financial firms also
were functioning under a distorted incentive
structure. Compensation schemes based on the
volume of business encouraged managers to go
in for excessive risk-taking in financial firms. They
saw a need to drive up returns on their equity to
satisfy shareholders as well as to enhance their
pay packages and sometimes also to retain their
jobs in the race. Large annual bonuses running
into several million dollars indirectly provided the
incentive to take undue risk, innovate new financial
instruments and market them to investors in
search of higher yields, thus increasing leverage
and creating fragile institutions and also an
unstable financial system. Equity holders
(because of limited liability) and asset managers
(because of their compensation system) were unduly rewarded for risk-taking. Greed became the
accepted norm even if it meant giving up on the
firm’s credentials in the short run. Here one needs
to emphasise the role of animal spirits in
encouraging people to take rash decisions, not to
consider the future rationally in their decisions
about savings and ultimately in encouraging
corruption (Akerlof and Shiller, 2009). As a result,
even if managers recognised a bubble in the price
of some asset, they could not take advantage of
that knowledge by selling short for fear that
investors would withdraw funds. Such rewards
were inconsistent with performance since
governments invariably ended up providing
funding support to prevent systemically important
financial institutions from failing.
2.57 To sum up, while there is no single
explanation in the realm of macroeconomic
management that appears totally satisfactory, there
is a common thread to most of the explanations,
namely, serious underestimation of potential for
market failures as it relates to macro-economy in
general and the financial sector in particular
(Reddy, 2009c). The linkage of the different causes,
though not very obvious, seems to be as follows:
As a consequence of the global imbalances,
savings from Asia got invested in advanced
countries, driving down their real interest rates. This
led to massive expansion in credit quantity with
erosion of quality because of the predatory search
for yield. This, in turn, led to the generation of new
toxic financial products through slicing, hedging and
originating and distribution, all of which combined
to brew the crisis to an explosive dimension
(Subbarao, 2009). In light of the current global
financial crisis, it would be worth exploring the
history of financial crises in terms of their incidence,
causes and effects.
II. FINANCIAL CRISES IN A HISTORICAL
PERSPECTIVE
Definition and Categorisation
2.58 Financial panics or crises are as old as
capitalism itself and can be traced at least to the
Dutch tulip mania of 1636-37 and the South Sea Bubble of 1719-20. The primary objective of the
study of financial crises has been to better
comprehend the underlying analytics of a crisis so
that future occurrence may be predicted and
minimised. Thus in the present context, an analysis
of the financial crises witnessed by the global
economy in the past is crucial in understanding and
analysing the recent crisis.
2.59 One feature common to all financial crises
has been that they have often arrived with fierce
force and departed with important lessons for policy
makers. Kindleberger (1978) has aptly called
financial crisis a “hardy perennial”. Financial crises
are admittedly difficult to define and often have no
precise beginning or end. They may be defined as
episodes of financial market volatility marked by
significant problems of illiquidity and insolvency
among financial market participants that require
official intervention to contain such consequences.
Financial crises may alternatively be defined as
financial events that eliminate or impair a significant
portion of the banking system’s capital.
2.60 Some economists have also defined
financial crisis as a situation in which the supply of
money is outpaced by the demand for money. This
implies that liquidity evaporates quickly because
available money is withdrawn from banks (called a
run), forcing banks either to sell other investments
to make up for the shortfall or to collapse. Another
definition of financial crisis has been put forth by
Mishkin (1991a) who defines a financial crisis as a
disruption to financial markets in which adverse
selection and moral hazard problems become much
worse, so that financial markets are unable to
efficiently channel funds to those who have the
most productive investment opportunities. As a
result, a financial crisis can drive the economy away
from equilibrium with high output in which financial
markets perform well to one in which output
declines sharply.
2.61 The literature on financial crisis can be split
into two schools of thought, one view expounded
by the monetarists and the other more eclectic view
put forth by Kindleberger and Minsky. Monetarists
like Freidman and Schwartz (1963) have linked financial crises with banking panics and concluded
that banking panics result in monetary contractions
which, in turn, lead to severe contractions in
economic activity. Financial crisis events which did
not result in banking panics were not classified as
a financial crisis by the monetarists and they termed
these events “pseudo- financial crises”. The
opposite view of financial crises has been outlined
by Kindleberger (1978) and Minsky (1972) whose
definitions of financial crises are broader. In their
view, financial crises either involve sharp declines
in asset prices, failures of large financial and nonfinancial
firms, deflations or disinflations,
disruptions in foreign exchange markets, or some
combination of all these. One may conclude from
these definitions that financial crises indicate stress
on the financial system, on banks and other
financial intermediaries, usually resulting in failures
of systemically important institutions and sharp
contractions in the national economy.
2.62 The literature has, in general, categorised
financial crises into the following: debt crises,
banking crises, currency crises, and crises due to
financial contagion. An economy may be affected
by any of these crises or may simultaneously
experience the occurrence of more than one variant
of the economic crisis. Financial crises experienced
in the past 150 years can be classified as one of
these variants.
Debt Crises
2.63 Debt crises are the earliest known variant
of financial crises and have been very frequent. A
debt crisis occurs either when the borrower defaults
or lenders perceive this as significant risk and
therefore withhold new loans and try to liquidate
existing loans. Debt crisis can apply to commercial
(private) and/or sovereign (public) debt. If there is
a perceived risk that the public sector will cease to
honour its repayment obligations, this is likely to
lead to a sharp curtailment of private capital inflows,
in part because it casts doubt on the government’s
commitment to allowing private sector debt
repayment. By contrast, if (part of) the private sector
is unable to discharge its external obligations, this need not lead to a wider crisis; but in practice, if
private sector default is on a significant scale,
commercial debt often becomes sovereign debt
through guarantees, bank bailouts, and so on. A
government may fail to repay its sovereign debt.
This often leads to a sudden decline in capital
inflows and a spike in capital outflows.
Banking Crises
2.64 A banking crisis is triggered by a sudden
withdrawal of bank deposits by several clients, a
situation known as a ‘bank run’. Banks may not
have sufficient funds to simultaneously pay back
numerous depositors, since they loan their funds.
Thus, a banking crisis occurs when actual or
potential bank runs or failures induce banks to
suspend the internal convertibility of their liabilities
or compel the government to intervene to prevent
the collapse of the bank by extending assistance
on a large scale. There can be a bank run as
suggested by Radelet and Sachs (1998), i.e., a
self-fulfilling collapse via either literal bank runs –
a view promulgated by Chang and Valesco (1998a,
1998b) – or some kind of balance sheet-driven
financial contraction. Banking crises tend to be
protracted and have severe effects on economic
activity through their impact on financial
intermediation, confidence, capital flight, currency
substitution and public finances. A banking crisis
generally results in the erosion of most or all of
aggregate banking system capital. Banking crises
were relatively rare during the Bretton Woods era,
due to capital and financial controls, but have
become increasingly common since the 1970s
often in tandem with currency crises (Kaminsky and
Reinhart, 1999).
Currency Crises
2.65 A currency crisis occurs when a speculative
attack on the exchange rate results in a devaluation
or sharp depreciation, or forces country authorities
to defend the currency by expending large volumes
of reserves or by significantly raising interest rates.
A currency crisis is normally the result of a forced
change in parity, abandonment of a pegged exchange rate, or an international rescue (Bordo
et al., 2001). Currency crises can either be an ‘old
style’ currency crisis where a cycle of overspending
and real appreciation weakens the current account,
often in the context of extensive capital controls,
and ends in devaluation, or a ‘new style’ crisis
where investor concerns about the credit
worthiness of the balance sheet of a significant part
of the economy (public and private) lead to a rapid
build-up of pressure on the exchange rate in an
environment of more liberal and integrated capital
and financial markets (Dornbusch, 2001). There is
no generally accepted definition of a currency crisis.
The key element is a sort of circular logic, in which
investors flee a currency because they fear that it
might be devalued, and in which much (though not
necessarily all) of the pressure for such a
devaluation comes precisely from capital flight.
Currency crises played a large role in the economic
turmoil of the Inter-War era, in the break-up of
Bretton Woods, in the early stages of the Latin
American debt crisis of the 1980s and the Asian
financial crisis in 1997.
Contagion
2.66 Considering the increasingly enhanced
linkages in both trade and capital across nations,
the issue of financial contagion, the process by
which a shock in one part of the financial system
spreads to other parts through a series of ‘linkages’,
has also become important. The channels of
contagion generally include flow of information and
interbank claims. A fall in prices in one market may
be interpreted as a negative signal about
fundamentals. If these fundamentals are common
to other markets, the expected returns and, hence,
prices in those markets will also fall. Similarly, if
one currency depreciates, other countries with
common fundamentals may also experience a
depreciation of their currency. Besides, considering
that it is optimal for banks to hold deposits in banks
in other regions or sectors in order to provide
liquidity if demand is unusually high, when one
region suffers a banking crisis, the other regions
suffer a loss because their claims on banks in the troubled region fall in value. If this spillover effect
is strong enough, it causes a crisis in adjacent
regions. The crisis gets stronger as it passes from
region to region and becomes a contagion (Allen
and Gale, 2000b; Kodres and Pritsker, 2002). The
East Asian crisis is an example of how contagion
can affect several economies in the region.
2.67 Many of the recent financial crises in
emerging market economies, such as the Mexican
crisis and the East Asian crisis, have been
characterised by currency, debt and banking crises
occurring at the same time or in rapid succession.
An analysis of the financial crises suggests that in
countries with capital controls, currency crises are
more frequent while banking crises are less
frequent. The relationship between banking crises
and currency crises has also been explored
empirically (Kaminsky and Reinhart, 1999). It has
been observed that in the 1970s, when financial
systems were highly regulated, currency crises did
not coincide with banking crises. After the financial
liberalisation of the 1980s, currency crises and
banking crises have become more intertwined.
Although banking crises typically precede currency
crises, their common cause is usually a fall in asset
values caused by a recession or weakness in the
economy. Often, the crisis is part of a boom-bust
cycle that follows financial liberalisation.
2.68 Indeed, as international capital and
domestic financial markets have become
increasingly integrated with increasing
globalisation, the distinction between different types
of financial crises has become blurred. Recent
analyses focus on the linkages between the
corporate, banking and public sectors during times
of internal financing pressure. Attention is paid to
crisis dynamics and spillover effects propagated
through more traditional flow variables, such as the
current account and fiscal deficits. Thus, creditors
may lose confidence in a government’s ability to
service its debt, in the banking system’s ability to
finance deposit outflows or in the corporate sector’s
ability to service its loans. Problems in one sector
are liable to spread to other sectors; for example;
concerns about the government’s balance sheet could undermine confidence in banks that hold
government debt and could spark a run on deposits;
or banking sector problems could expose large
contingent liabilities that could lead to difficulties
for the government in servicing its debt and could
even give rise to solvency concerns that could
cause a run on the currency. Thus, increasingly the
distinction between the different types of crises is
getting blurred due to increased integration of
markets within the shores as well as across borders.
Incidence of Financial Crises
2.69 The nature of financial crises has changed
over the years with changes in the economic
landscape. The earliest recorded episodes of
financial crises generally took the shape of external
default. During the period 1300-1799, Europe
witnessed around 19 incidents of external default.
The defaulting countries included Austria, England,
France, Germany, Portugal and Spain. With the
development of the banking sector in the eighteenth
century, banking crises were witnessed by a
number of developed countries as well as emerging
markets. The earliest advanced economy banking
crisis occurred in France in 1802; early crises in
emerging markets befell China (several episodes
during the 1860s-1870s) and Peru in 1873 (Reinhart
and Rogoff, 2008).
2.70 Reinhart and Rogoff (2008) have given a
wider view of the history of financial crises during
the period 1800 to 2006. According to them, there
were 239 episodes of sovereign default during the
period 1800-2006, of which 126 episodes of
sovereign default were witnessed in Latin America
followed by 73 episodes of sovereign default in
Europe, 26 in Africa and 14 in Asia. There were
five pronounced peaks or default cycles during the
period 1800-2006 when a high percentage of all
countries were in a state of default or restructuring.
The first spike took place during the Napoleonic
war. The second took place during the 1820s-1840s
when nearly half the countries in the world including
all of Latin America were in default. The third
episode is placed between the 1870s and the
1890s. The 1873 global financial crisis originated in the German and Austrian stock market collapse.
The fourth episode began in the Great Depression
of the 1930s to 1950s when again nearly half of all
countries stood in default. The most recent default
cycle encompassed the emerging market debt
crises of the 1980s and 1990s.
2.71 The history of financial crises during the
period 1880-2000 has been examined in detail by
Bordo et al. (2001) as well. Drawing from their
analysis, the period between 1875 and 2007 can
be broadly divided into four periods: Gold Standard
Era: 1875-1913; Inter-War Years: 1919-1939;
Bretton Woods Period: 1945-1971; and Recent
Period: 1973-2007.
Gold Standard Era: 1875-1913
2.72 The Gold Standard Era has been relatively
benign of the four periods even though capital markets were globalised during this period. The
occurrence of crises was low during the Gold
Standard Era (1873-1913). During this period there
were 35 episodes of sovereign default. The
defaulting nations were largely Latin American with
some European countries like Greece (1893),
Portugal (1890), Russia (1885) and Spain (1882).
Banking crises were relatively infrequent during this
period; the most notable banking crisis was in the US
which started in 1873. The US faced another major
banking crisis in 1893 and once again in 1907.
Inter-War Years: 1919-1939
2.73 The Inter-War Years (1919-1939) were
quite turbulent. This is not surprising as the Great
Depression took place during this period (Box II.4).
Banking crises and currency crises were
widespread during the Inter-War years. There were 21 episodes of banking crises during this period
and they spread across all continents including
North America, Europe, Africa and Latin America.
Asia was the only exception. Sovereign defaults
were also common during this period with 30
episodes of external debt crisis.
Box II.4
The Great Depression
The worldwide economic downturn which has come to be known
as the Great Depression began in 1929 and lasted until about
1939. It has been the longest and the most severe depression
witnessed by the industrialised western world. The Depression
originated in the United States and its outcome was severe
decline in output and employment, and acute deflation in almost
the entire global economy (Romer, 2003).
Backdrop
The US economy had experienced rapid economic growth and
financial excesses in the late 1920s and initially the economic
downturn was seen as simply part of the boom-bust-boom cycle.
There was over-production in agriculture, leading to falling prices
and rising debt among farmers. During the mid-1920s Wall Street
attracted a sizeable number of middle-class investors.
Speculation was rising and in February 1929, the Federal
Reserve issued statements to curb lending for speculative
purposes by the banks. This led to a decline in stock prices. The
stock markets bounced back again by March 1929; however, in
September 1929, there was a sharp decline. At the same time
there was a major banking crisis including the ‘Wall Street Crash’
in October 1929.
Causes
The fundamental cause of the Great Depression in the United
States was the decline in aggregate demand which led to a
decline in production and a pile-up of inventories. Several factors
led to the contraction in aggregate demand which varied during
the course of the Depression. The main factor depressing
aggregate demand was a worldwide contraction in world money
supplies. This monetary collapse itself was the result of a poorly managed and technically flawed international monetary system
(the gold standard as reconstituted after World War I). Monetary
shocks played a major role in the Great Contraction and these
shocks were transmitted around the world primarily through the
working of the gold standard (Bernanke, 2000).
The fall in output in the United States which started in the summer
of 1929 is widely attributed to the tight US monetary policy to
stem the rise in stock market speculation. Stock prices in the US
had risen more than four-fold between 1921 and 1929 when the
stock prices peaked. The Federal Reserve raised interest rates
between 1928 and 1929 with the aim of limiting stock market
speculation. This hike in interest rates led to a decline in interest
rate-sensitive spending in areas such as construction and
automobile purchases which resulted in reduced production. By
September 1929, the speculative bubble had built up in the US
stock market and prices had reached levels that could not be
justified by reasonable anticipations of future earnings. This
bubble burst in October 1929. This was preceded by minor
declines in stock prices which dented investor confidence leading
to panic selling. Panic selling began on Black Thursday, i.e.,
October 24, 1929. US stock prices spiralled downwards and fell
by 33 per cent during September 1929 to November 1929. This
stock market crash led to a sharp contraction in the aggregate
demand in the US. The reduction in consumer and firm spending
led to rapid declines in real output in late 1929 and 1930.
In addition to the reduction in aggregate demand due to the stock
market crash, banking panics and the resultant monetary
contraction led to a further decline in demand. The United States
experienced widespread banking panics in the fall of 1930, spring of 1931, fall of 1931 and fall of 1932. Finally a National Bank
Holiday was declared on March 6, 1933 which closed all banks,
permitting them to reopen only after being deemed solvent by
government inspectors. Default and bankruptcy plagued almost
every class of borrower except the Federal Government.
During 1930-33, around 20 per cent of the banks in the US failed.
These bank failures led to a dramatic rise in the demand for
currency vis-à-vis bank deposits. Money supply contracted by
31 per cent between 1929 and 1933 due to the steep rise in the
currency-to-deposit ratio. In September 1931, the Federal
Reserve effected an interest rate hike leading to further
contraction of money supply and a subsequent contractionary
effect on output.
Friedman and Schwartz (1963) identified four main policy
mistakes made by the Federal Reserve that led to a sharp and
undesirable decline in the money supply :
1) Tightening monetary policy (resulting in increasing interest
rates) beginning in the spring of 1928 and continuing until
the stock market crash of October 1929.
2) Raising interest rates to defend the dollar in response to
speculative attacks, ignoring domestic banking panics and
failing to act as lender of last resort to domestic banks in
September and October 1931.
3) Despite lowering interest rates early in 1932 with positive
results, raising interest rates in late 1932.
4) Ongoing neglect of problems in the US banking sector
throughout the early 1930s, and failing to create a stable
domestic banking environment.
According to some economists, the Federal Reserve’s decision
to allow huge declines in the money supply in the US was to
preserve the gold standard. Under the gold standard, imbalances
in trade or asset flows gave rise to international gold flows. There
have been other international linkages as well. US lending abroad
fell in 1928 and 1929 as a result of high interest rates and the
booming stock market in the United States. This reduction in
foreign lending may have resulted in further credit contractions
and declines in output in borrower countries like Germany,
Argentina and Brazil (Romer, 2003).
The economic downturn was further compounded by the 1930
enactment of the Smoot-Hawley tariff in the United States and
the worldwide rise in protectionist trade policies. In addition, the
Revenue Act of 1932 increased tax rates in America in an attempt
to balance the Federal Budget, which led to further contraction
of the economy by discouraging spending.
Manifestation
The timing and severity of the Great Depression varied
substantially across countries. In the United States, the downturn
began in the summer of 1929 which became markedly worse in
late 1929 and continued until early 1933. Real output and prices
fell sharply and during this period, the United States witnessed a
decline of 47 per cent in industrial production, 30 per cent in the
real GDP and 33 per cent in the wholesale price index.
Virtually every industrialised country witnessed declines in
wholesale prices of 30 per cent or more between 1929 and 1933.
Commodity prices declined even more dramatically during this
period.
Recovery
Recovery in the US economy set in from early 1933. Between
1933 and 1937, real GDP rose at an average rate of 9 per cent
per year. US output finally returned to its long-run trend level in
1942. Recovery in other parts of the world varied greatly. Britain
started recovering from the end of 1932. Early 1933 witnessed
recovery in Canada and other smaller European countries.
France could enter the recovery phase only around 1938.
The recovery was primarily led by currency devaluations and
monetary expansion as monetary contraction and the gold
standard had played a key role in the Great Depression. Worldwide
monetary expansion resulted in lower interest rates and improved
credit availability which, in turn, stimulated spending. Devaluations
allowed countries to expand their money supplies without concern
about gold movements and exchange rates.
Legacy
The impact of the Great Depression was steep declines in world
output and employment. The Depression and the policy response
also impacted the world economy. The Great Depression led to
the demise of the international Gold Standard. In many countries
it resulted in increased government regulation of the economy,
particularly financial markets. It led to the establishment of the
Securities and Exchange Commission in 1934 in the United
States to regulate new stock issues and stock market trading
practices. The Banking Act of 1933 (Glass-Steagall Act)
established deposit insurance in the United States and prohibited
banks from underwriting or dealing in securities. The Depression
also played a crucial role in the development of macroeconomic
policies intended to temper economic downturns and upturns.
The Depression led to the development of Keynesian theory that
underscored the importance of increases in government
spending, tax cuts and monetary expansion in staving off
downturns and depressions. This insight, combined with a
growing consensus that government should try to stabilise
employment, has led to a more activist policy since the 1930s.
References:
-
Bernanke, Ben S. 2000. “Essays on the Great Depression.”
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
-
Bernanke, Ben S. 1983. “Non-Monetary Effects of the
Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression.”
NBER Working Paper No. 1054.
-
Eichengreen, Barry and Kevin H. O’Rourke. 2009. “A Tale
of Two Depressions”. www.voxeu.org.
-
Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz, 1963. “A Monetary
History of the United States.” Princeton, Princeton University
Press.
-
Romer, Christina D. 2003. “Great Depression Revisited.”
Bretton Woods Period: 1945-1971
2.74 There was relative calm during the late
1940s to the early 1970s (Bretton Woods period).
The first post-1945 global crisis was the breakdown
of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange
rates. This calm may be partly explained by
booming world growth, repression of domestic
financial markets (in varying degrees) and the use
of capital controls that followed for many years after
World War II. The financial markets were not very
open till the end of the 1960s due to a combination
of regulation, lack of capital mobility, diverse
standards, and the limits of technology that created
geographic barriers in the global economy. Banking
regulation was made stringent and many banks
were brought under state control. There was strict
regulation of competition between banks and other
types of financial institutions, and many countries
used their financial systems to directly promote
export industries and protect domestic producers
and distributors. As a result, there were few banking
crises during this period, with the exception of the
twin crises in Brazil. However, currency crises were
a regular feature of the financial landscape during
the Bretton Woods Period as a fixed exchange rate
was almost inconsistent with the macroeconomic
policies followed during the period. The controls
on capital flows in suppressing currency crises were
less efficacious. During this period, 14 countries
faced external debt/currency crises; the majority
of the countries were in Latin America.
2.75 The situation changed dramatically after the
breakdown of the Bretton Woods system of fixed
exchange rates in 1971-72. After the collapse of
the Bretton Woods System, developed countries
in North America, Europe and Japan moved over
to a floating exchange rate system. In addition, they
also simultaneously embarked upon a programme of liberalising their capital accounts and allowing
cross-border financial investments. At the same
time, they began deregulating their national
financial institutions to allow more competition and
new forms of financial activity. These developments
paved the way for the steady growth of capital flows
across borders including rapid growth of
international banking credit during the 1970s and
1980s, but it was limited mainly to the industrialised
economies.
Recent Period: 1973-2007
2.76 The post-Bretton Woods Period (1973-
2007) has, however, been crisis-prone. An analysis
of the data regarding the incidence of financial crisis
reveals that the number of financial crises around
the world has risen during this period, and even
more sharply over the past thirty years. Since the
early 1970s, with the liberalisation of capital
account in the advanced countries, episodes of
banking crises have increased. After a long hiatus,
the number of countries facing banking difficulties
first began to increase in the 1970s (Reinhart and
Rogoff, 2008). The 1970s were characterised by
the Latin American debt crisis and its impact on
banks. Apart from the break-up of the Bretton
Woods system of fixed exchange rates, sharp
spikes in oil prices also catalysed a prolonged
global recession, resulting in financial sector
difficulties in a number of advanced economies as
well. There were seven episodes of banking crises
during the 1970s, viz., in Uruguay (1971), UK
(1974), Chile (1976), Central African Republic
(1976), Germany (1977), South Africa (1977) and
Venezuela (1978).
2.77 In the early 1980s, the collapse of global
commodity prices combined with high and volatile
interest rates in the United States contributed to a
spate of banking and sovereign debt crises in
emerging economies, most famously in Latin
America and then Africa. There were 40 episodes
of banking crises during the decade of the 1980s
compared with 73 episodes during the 1990s. The
early 1980s witnessed crises in Chile and Morocco.
The 1980s saw the United States experiencing the ‘savings and loan associations’ (S & L) crisis. In
the 1990s, many economies including Nordic
countries like Sweden, Finland, and Norway and
most of the transitional socialist economies were
hit by the crisis. The Nordic countries witnessed
banking crises following a sharp surge in capital
inflows and real estate prices. India faced a balance
of payments crisis in 1991 in the wake of domestic
imbalances, the Gulf War and the break-up of the
USSR. Several countries including UK that formed part of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism
suffered crises in 1992-93 and were forced to
devalue or withdraw from the mechanism. In
1994-95, it was the Tequila crisis that impacted
Mexico followed by Brazil and Venezuela; in
1997, Thailand, Indonesia, Korea, and Malaysia
faced crises popularly known as East Asian crisis
(Box II.5). In 1998, Russia’s default sent tremors
that had an impact as far away as Brazil. Following
the asset price bubble burst in the late 1980s and early 1990s, Japan also experienced a banking
crisis which started in 1992 and lasted for almost a
decade. In the current decade, various emerging
market economies, viz., Turkey (2001), Paraguay
(2002), Uruguay (2002), Argentina (2001, 2002)
and Moldova (2002) experienced financial crises.
Notably, Argentina, Uruguay and the Dominican
Republic faced triple crises. The US witnessed the
dot-com meltdown in 2001 which impacted world
demand severely.
Box II.5
East Asian Crisis
The East Asian financial crisis which impacted the fastgrowing
economies of South Korea, Malaysia, Thailand
and Indonesia is remarkable in several ways. The crisis
hit the most rapidly growing economies in the world, and
prompted the largest financial bailouts in history. It was
the least anticipated and sharpest financial crisis to hit
the developing world since the 1982 debt crisis (Radelet
and Sachs, 1998).
Backdrop
The fundamental aspects of macroeconomic management
in the affected economies remained sound throughout the
early 1990s. Government budgets regularly registered
surpluses in each country and sovereign debt was at
prudent levels. Inflation rates were below 10 per cent
during the 1990s in the region. Domestic savings and
investment rates were very high. Conditions prevalent in
the global financial markets also did not portend a crisis
as the world interest rates were unusually low and key
commodity prices were relatively stable. The crisis was
largely unanticipated by international lenders and most
market observers and rating agencies also did not signal
increased risk until after the onset of the crisis itself. Longterm
sovereign debt ratings remained unchanged
throughout 1996 and the first half of 1997 for each of the
Asian countries except the Philippines, where the debt was
actually upgraded in early 1997.
The only indication of growing concern was that stock
prices witnessed a bearish trend, with prices in the Thai,
Seoul and Malaysian stock markets witnessing a
continuous downslide. In Indonesia, however, both stock
market and bank lending showed continued confidence
until mid-1997.
Other areas of concern were the growing current account
deficits, overvalued exchange rates and the slowdown in
exports. Other important indicators of growing financial vulnerability were the rapid expansion of commercial bank
credit and growing short-term foreign debt.
The financial sector exhibited signs of growing risk as
financial institutions became increasingly fragile
throughout the 1990s. Credit to the private sector
expanded very rapidly with much of it financed by off-shore
borrowing by the banking sector. The credit was utilised
primarily for speculative investments.
Banks became increasingly vulnerable. Banks borrowed
in foreign exchange and lent in local currencies and were,
therefore, exposed to the risk of foreign exchange losses
from depreciation. Moreover, banks borrowed off-shore
in short term maturities and lent on-shore with longer payback
periods. The financial fragility was further
exacerbated by the fact that the countries’ short-term debt
exceeded available foreign exchange reserves.
With this background, bank failure in Thailand, corporate
failures in Korea and political uncertainty in the region
hastened credit withdrawals, leading to panic runs. This
was further worsened by a contagion effect where the
economic and political stability of the entire region was
considered vulnerable by the creditors.
Causes
The Asian crisis was caused by a boom in international
lending followed by a sudden withdrawal of funds. At the
core of the Asian crisis were large-scale foreign capital
inflows into financial systems that became vulnerable to
panic (Radelet and Sachs, 1998).
According to estimates, the reversal of flows for the five
East Asian countries hit hardest by the crisis (Indonesia,
Korea, Malaysia, Philippines and Thailand) dropped from
$ 93 billion to -$12.1 billion, a swing of $ 105 billion on a
combined pre-shock GDP of approximately $ 935 billion or a swing of 11 per cent of GDP. The sudden drop in
bank lending followed a sustained period of large increases
in cross-border bank loans.
Manifestation
The sudden and sharp withdrawal of foreign capital had
several macroeconomic and microeconomic effects. First,
the nominal as well as the real exchange rates depreciated
dramatically after the initial defence of a pegged exchange
rate in Thailand and the Philippines and a crawling peg in
Indonesia, Malaysia and Korea. Domestic interest rates
increased sharply due to the reversal of foreign inflows,
resulting in a tightening of domestic credit conditions.
The combination of real exchange rate depreciation and
high interest rates led to a surge in the level of nonperforming
loans (NPLs) in the banking sector, especially
as real estate projects went into bankruptcy. The
combination of sharply rising NPLs and direct balance
sheet losses due to currency depreciation wiped out a
substantial portion of the market value of bank capital in
Indonesia, Thailand and Korea.
Impact
The sudden withdrawal of foreign financing had an
enormous contractionary impact. The collapse of domestic
bank capital further compounded the contraction by
severely restricting bank lending. Banks cut back their own
lending, both because the banks themselves were illiquid
(as a result of the withdrawal of foreign credits and, in some
cases, deposits) and because they were decapitalised. The
decapitalised banks restricted their lending in order to move
towards capital adequacy ratios required by bank
supervisors and reinforced by the IMF.
In December 1997, Moody’s downgraded the sovereign
debt of Indonesia, Korea and Thailand, putting them below
investment grade. As a result of creditor panic, bank runs,
and the sovereign downgrades, Korea, Indonesia and
Thailand were thrown into partial debt defaults. The
economies in the affected countries experienced severe
downturns. In Thailand, 97.7 per cent of GDP was the
estimated output loss and GDP declined by 10.5 per cent.
In Korea, output loss was 50.1 per cent and GDP declined
by 6.9 per cent. In Malaysia, non-performing loans peaked
between 25-35 per cent of banking system assets and fell
to 10.8 per cent by March 2002. Output loss was 50.0 per
cent of GDP and GDP declined by 7.4 per cent.
Legacy
The East Asian crisis brought into focus the vulnerability
associated with short- term capital flows. It highlighted how
balance sheet vulnerabilities can impact the financial
stability of an economy. Post-crisis, the economies made
a dramatic turnaround, turning the capital account deficit
into surplus and built up huge foreign exchange reserves
as an insurance against sharp capital reversals.
References
-
Corsetti, G., P. Pesenti, and N. Roubini. 1998. “What
Caused the Asian Currency and Financial Crisis: The
Policy Debate”. NBER Working Paper 6834.
-
Kane, Edward J. 2000. “Capital Movements, Banking
Insolvency, and Silent Runs in the Asian Financial
Crisis”. NBER Working Paper 7514.
-
Radelet, S. and J. Sachs. 1998. “The Onset of the East
Asian Financial Crisis”. NBER Working Paper 6680.
2.78 The incidence of financial crisis has been
the highest over the past three decades or so
(Table 2.9). According to the database compiled by Laevan and Valencia (2008), there were 124
episodes of banking crisis, 211 episodes of
currency crisis and 64 episodes of sovereign debt crisis. Of these 42 were twin crises and 10 were
triple crises (Table 2.10).
Table 2.9: Incidence of Financial Crisis |
Period |
Number of Crises |
1 |
2 |
1875-1913 |
58 |
1919-1939 |
51 |
1945-1971 |
17 |
1973-2007 |
399 |
Source : Laeven and Valencia (2008).
Reinhart and Rogoff (2008). |
2.79 The incidence of crises has been frequent
under different monetary and regulatory regimes.
Financial crises have impacted both advanced as
well as emerging market economies in varying
degrees (Table 2.11). An analysis of the incidence
of financial crisis over the past 150 years reveals
that though crisis occurs without warning, the
incidence can largely be explained in terms of the
prevailing macroeconomic conditions, the financial
regulatory regime, currency regime, fiscal discipline
and global capital and trade flows.
Table 2.10: Frequency of Financial Crisis : 1973-2007 |
|
Banking
Crisis |
Currency
Crisis |
Sovereign
Debt Crisis |
Twin
Crisis |
Triple Crisis |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
1970s |
4 |
26 |
7 |
– |
– |
1980s |
40 |
74 |
42 |
11 |
4 |
1990s |
73 |
92 |
7 |
27 |
3 |
2000s |
7 |
19 |
8 |
4 |
3 |
Note : Twin crisis indicates a banking crisis in Year t and a currency crisis in Year (t-1, t+1). Triple crisis indicates a banking crisis in Year (t-1, t+1) and a debt crisis in Year (t-1,t+1).
Source : Laeven and Valencia (2008). |
Table 2.11: Major Financial Crises: 1873-2007 |
Name/Country/Year |
Nature of the crisis |
Impact of the crisis |
1 |
2 |
3 |
German and Austrian Stock Market Collapse, May 1873 |
French war indemnity paid to Prussia in 1871 led to speculation in Germany and Austria. In early 1873, a speculative movement in the stock market led to tripling of stock prices in a few months. On May 9, 1873 two big banks failed in Austria. Following this, the German and Austrian stock market collapsed in 1873. The crises were connected due to the international capital markets. A large infusion of cash in the US railroad industry took place leading to the build-up of a speculative bubble. Capital flows to the US fell in the wake of the German crisis. Jay Cooke's investment banking firm failed in September 1873, setting off panic. |
The recession which ensued after the crises in Germany, Austria and the US resulted in a dramatic fall in trade and capital flows. The failure of Jay Cooke Bank set off a chain reaction of bank failures. The New York Stock Exchange closed for 10 days starting September 20, 1873. A total of 18,000 business houses failed between 1873 and 1875. Unemployment reached 14 per cent by 1876. Real estate values fell and corporate profits declined sharply. The ensuing world recession (1873- 1879) led to debt servicing problems in the other countries through reduced exports and tax revenues. Initial defaults in Central American nations in January 1873 led to a fall in bond prices. The crisis quickly spread to Italy, Holland and Belgium, England, France and Russia. By 1876, the Ottoman Empire, Egypt, Greece and 8 Latin American countries had defaulted. |
Barings Crisis, 1890 |
It was triggered by central bank tightening in England, France and Germany. Argentina stopped dividend payments in April 1890, leading to a domestic bank run. The House of Baring, a major lender to Argentina, declared itself insolvent in November 1890. This crisis soon spread to other Latin American countries. |
It impacted Britain as Argentina and Britain had strong economic links through trade and financial integration. The crisis impacted Uruguay which defaulted in 1891. This led to a series of sudden stops and current account reversals. |
USA 1907 |
Rapid industrial and economic growth took place during 1897-1906, with lots of mergers and corporate consolidations. The San Francisco earthquake of April 1906 led to tightening of Eastern US and international financial markets. There was rapid expansion of trust companies, i.e., lightly regulated banks. A speculative attempt to corner the market in a copper company's stock in October 1907 collapsed; some banks and trust companies were implicated. Runs on trust companies and banks in New York City set off the panic in the latter half of October 1907. |
JP Morgan organised a co-operative arrangement of trust companies to pool $ 10 million to support the banks and trust companies facing runs. In 1908, Congress passed the Aldrich-Vreeland Act. The crisis of 1907 occurred during a lengthy economic contraction lasting from May 1907 to June 1908. The interrelated contraction, bank panic and falling stock market resulted in significant economic disruption. Industrial production dropped, and 1907 saw many bankruptcies. Production fell by 11 per cent, and imports by 26 per cent, while unemployment rose to 8 per cent from under 3 per cent. |
USA 1929 |
The 1920s experienced a major stock market boom associated with massive investment. It also saw major innovations in industrial organisations and corporate finance. The US stock market crashed in 1929 following a tight Federal Reserve policy after a speculative buildup. The financial crisis began in the fall and winter of 1930-31, when large numbers of US banks failed, leading to a deflationary downward spiral and deepening recession. In May 1931, the Austrian Creditanstalt failed. The crisis then spread to Germany which defaulted on its large foreign debts and left the Gold Standard. Pressure then shifted to the US which saw a run on its gold. |
The recession began in 1930. It reduced output via wealth effects on consumption, reduced investment and reduced velocity. A series of banking panics erupted in 1930-33. The banking panics in turn impacted the real economy through the collapse in money supply, which produced massive deflation and financial disintermediation. The deflation spread abroad through the fixed exchange rate links of classical gold standard. The year 1932 is considered to be the worst year in US economic history. |
Latin American Debt Crisis 1980s |
In the 1960s and 1970, many Latin American countries notably Brazil, Argentina and Mexico borrowed huge sums of money from international creditors for industrialisation, especially in infrastructure programmes. Between 1975 and 1982, Latin American debt to commercial banks increased at an annual cumulative rate of 20.4 per cent. Debt service grew even faster. When the world economy went into recession in the 1970s and 1980s, countries started facing a liquidity crunch. Interest rates increased in the US and Europe in 1979, making it harder for borrowing countries to pay back their debts. In August 1982, Mexico defaulted on its debt. In the wake of the Mexican default, commercial banks halted new lending to Latin American countries. |
More than 70 institutions (accounting for 16 per cent of commercial bank assets and 35 per cent of finance company assets) were liquidated or subjected to intervention between 1980 and 1982. In March 1980 a number of financial institutions were forced to rely heavily on Central Bank financial assistance when faced with deposit withdrawals. Failed institutions included the largest investment bank and the second largest private commercial bank. Massive capital outflows took place, particularly to the US. The exchange rates of the affected countries depreciated sharply, thereby raising real interest rates. Real GDP growth for the region was only 2.3 per cent during 1980-85 but in per capita terms the affected countries experienced a negative growth of almost 9 per cent. |
Savings and Loan Crisis USA 1980 |
The savings and loan crisis of the 1980s and 1990s was the failure of 745 savings and loan (S&L) associations in the US. In an effort to take advantage of the real estate boom and high interest rates of the late 1970s and early 1980s, many S&L associations lent far more money than was prudent, and lent to risky ventures. In 1982 a large number of customers' defaults and bankruptcies ensued. The US FSLIC had insured S&L accounts. From 1986 to 1989, FSLIC closed or otherwise resolved 296 institutions with total assets of $ 125 billion. The failure of S&L associations resulted in many other bank failures. |
The US government paid $ 105 billion to resolve the crisis. There was a net loss to taxpayers of approximately $ 124 billion. The concomitant slowdown in the finance industry and the real estate market may have been a contributing cause of the 1990-91 recession. |
World 1987 |
Black Monday refers to Monday, October 19, 1987, when stock markets around the world crashed, shedding a huge value in a very short time. The crash began in Hong Kong, spread west through international time zones to Europe, hitting the United States after other markets had already declined by a significant margin. The Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) dropped by 508 points to 1738.74 (22.6 per cent). |
By the end of October, stock markets in Hong Kong had fallen 45.8 per cent, Australia 41.8 per cent, Spain 31 per cent, the United Kingdom 26.4 per cent, the United States 22.7 per cent, and Canada 22.5 per cent. New Zealand's market was hit especially hard, falling about 60 per cent from its 1987 peak, and taking several years to recover. |
UK 1991 |
The first major crisis of the 1990s was the collapse of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) in 1992. The British pound-under massive speculation from hedge funds-was withdrawn from the ERM and the Scandinavian banking system faced overnight interest rates of more than 100 per cent. In September 1992, the British government was forced to withdraw the pound from the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) after they were unable to keep the sterling above its agreed lower limit. From the beginning of the 1990s, high German interest rates set by the Bundesbank to counteract inflationary effects caused significant stress across the whole of the ERM. UK and Italy had additional difficulties as they had twin deficits, while depreciation of the US dollar in which UK's exports were priced hurt it even more. |
The effect of high German interest rates and high domestic interest rates put the UK into recession and a large number of businesses failed. The housing market crashed. Other ERM countries whose currencies had breached their bands returned to the system with broadened bands. |
Nordic Countries (Finland, Nor- way and Sweden) 1991 |
The three Nordic countries, i.e.,. Finland, Norway and Sweden, went through a financial liberalisation process that led to a lending boom. However, they suffered the adverse consequences of higher German interest rates. |
Savings banks were badly affected; the government took control of three banks that together accounted for 31 per cent of system deposits. In Finland, output loss was placed at 59.1 per cent of GDP and GDP declined by 6.2 per cent. In Sweden, output loss was placed at 30.6 per cent of GDP and GDP declined by 1.2 per cent in the crisis year. |
Mexican Crisis 1994 |
The following factors led to the financial fragility of the Mexican economy: (1) a semi-fixed exchange rate; (2) a sizeable current-account deficit resulting to a large extent from a huge credit expansion; (3) a substantial rise in U.S. interest rates; and (4) a trigger, consisting of the political tensions accumulated during 1994. The combination of the exchange-rate regime with a rapid expansion of credit, a substantial part of which was of poor quality, led to the crisis. The surge of bad credits was due to flimsy bank capitalisation and the failure to ensure that some bankers met the ``fit and proper'' criteria to own or manage the institutions. Thus, the original sin that led to the Mexican crisis was the expropriation of commercial banks that weakened them and rendered them a fragile conduit for privatisation and credit expansion The crisis was the result of severe constraints on monetary policy that arose as the government wanted to maintain a fixed or quasi-pegged exchange rate. Hoping to avoid an economic slowdown, Mexico tried to limit the amount of monetary tightening during 1994 while maintaining its quasi-pegged exchange rate by engaging in massive sterilised intervention. Such a policy could not be sustained for long and resulted in a collapse of the exchange rate, soaring interest rates, and recession. |
Of 34 commercial banks in 1994, 9 were intervened and 11 participated in the loan/ purchase recapitalisation programme. The nine intervened banks accounted for 19 per cent of financial system assets and were deemed insolvent. By 2000, 50 per cent of bank assets were held by foreign banks. The output loss amounted to 4.2 per cent of GDP and the real GDP growth declined by 6.2 per cent in the affected year. |
East Asian Crisis 1997 |
Under the framework of a pegged exchange rate regime, Thailand had enjoyed a decade of robust growth performance, but by late-1996 pressures on the baht emerged. Pressure increased through the first half of 1997 amidst an unsustainable current account deficit, a significant appreciation of the real effective exchange rate, rising short-term foreign debt, a deteriorating fiscal balance, and increasingly visible financial sector weaknesses, including large exposure to the real estate sector, exchange rate risk and liquidity risk. Finance companies had disproportionately the largest exposure to the property sector and were the first institutions affected by the economic downturn. Following mounting exchange rate pressures and ineffective interventions to alleviate these pressures, the baht was floated on July 2, 1997. In light of weak supportive policies, the baht depreciated by 20 per cent against the U.S. dollar in July. The devaluation of the Thai baht in July 1997, the subsequent regional contagion, and the crash of the Hong Kong stock market sent shock waves to the Korean financial system. Korea's exchange rate remained broadly stable through October 1997. However, the high level of short-term debt and the low level of usable international reserves made the economy increasingly vulnerable to shifts in market sentiment. In Korea, while macroeconomic fundamentals continued to be favourable, the growing awareness of problems in the financial sector and in industrial groups (chaebols) increasingly led to difficulties for the banks in rolling over their short-term borrowing. In Malaysia the persistent pace of credit expansion at an annual rate of nearly 30 per cent to the private sector, in particular to the property sector and for the purchase of stocks and shares, exposed the financial system to potential risks from price declines in property and other assets that occurred in 1997. In the wake of market turbulence and contagion effects in the second half of 1997, concerns among market participants about the true condition and resilience of the financial system increasingly became a central issue, highlighted by known fragilities among finance companies. |
By May 2002, the Bank of Thailand had closed 59 (of 91) financial companies that in total accounted for 13 per cent of financial system assets and 72 per cent of finance company assets. It closed 1 (out of 15) domestic bank and nationalised 4 banks. Non- performing loans peaked at 33 per cent of total loans and were reduced to 10.3 per cent of total loans in February 2002. 97.7 per cent of GDP was the estimated output loss and GDP declined by 10.5 per cent. In Korea, through May 2002, 5 banks were forced to exit the market through ';purchase and assumption'; and 303 financial institutions shut down (215 were credit unions); another 4 banks were nationalised. Output loss was 50.1 per cent and GDP declined by 6.9 per cent. In Malaysia, the finance company sector was restructured, and the number of finance companies was reduced from 39 to 10 through mergers. Two finance companies were taken over by the Central Bank, including the largest independent finance company. Non-performing loans peaked between 25-35 per cent of banking system assets and fell to 10.8 per cent by March 2002. Output loss was 50.0 per cent of GDP and GDP declined by 7.4 per cent. |
Russia 1998 |
From mid-1997 to April 1998, the Central Bank of Russia (CBR) was relatively successful in defending the fixed exchange rate policy through a significant tightening of credit. However, the situation became increasingly untenable when significant political turmoil in Russia - starting with the President's dismissal of the government of Prime Minister Chernomyrdin and prolonged by a stalemate over the formation of a new cabinet - cast increasing doubt on the political resolve to come to grips with Russia's fiscal problems. However, well before the crisis, there was widespread recognition that the banking system had a series of weaknesses. In particular, bank reporting and bank supervision were weak, there was excessive exposure to foreign exchange rate risk, connected lending, and poor management. From mid- July, when the Duma refused to pass key fiscal measures, the situation deteriorated rapidly, leading to a unilateral restructuring of ruble-denominated treasury bills and bonds on August 17, 1998. The ruble was allowed to float three days later despite previous announcements that it would not be devalued. |
A large devaluation in real effective terms (over 300 per cent in nominal terms), loss of access to international capital markets, and massive losses to the banking system ensued. Two key measures implemented were a 90-day moratorium on foreign liabilities of banks and the transfer of a large fraction of deposits from insolvent banks to Sberbank. Nearly 720 banks, or half of those operating, were deemed insolvent. These banks accounted for 4 per cent of sector assets and 32 per cent of retail deposits. The GDP declined by 5.3 per cent in the crisis year. In 1998 inflation reached 84 per cent and welfare costs grew considerably. Other countries like the Baltic States, Belarus, Kazakhstan, Moldova, Ukraine and Uzbekistan were badly affected. |
Dot.com bubble 2000 |
The ';dot-com bubble'; (or the ';I.T. bubble';) was a speculative bubble covering roughly 1998-2001 (with a climax on March 10, 2000 with the NASDAQ peaking at 5132.52) during which stock markets in Western nations saw their equity value rise rapidly from growth in the recent Internet sector and related fields. The period was marked by the founding (and, in many cases, spectacular failure) of a group of new Internet-based companies commonly referred to as dot-coms. A combination of rapidly increasing stock prices, market confidence that the companies would turn future profits, individual speculation in stocks, and widely available venture capital created an environment in which many investors were willing to overlook traditional metrics such as price-toearnings ratios in favour of confidence in technological advancements. Over 1999 and early 2000, the Federal Reserve increased interest rates six times, and the economy was beginning to lose speed. The dot-com bubble burst, on March 10, 2000, when the technologyheavy NASDAQ Composite index peaked at 5,048.62 (intra-day peak 5,132.52), more than double its value just a year before. The massive initial batch of sell orders processed on Monday, March 13 triggered a chain reaction of selling that fed on itself as investors, funds, and institutions liquidated positions. In just six days the NASDAQ lost nearly 9 per cent, falling from roughly 5,050 on March 10 to 4,580 on March 15. |
The financial Internet bubble finally burst in the spring of 2000. The Nasdaq plunge erased 62 per cent of the Nasdaq's value, which plummeted from a high of 4,260 to a low of 1,620 12 months later. Many dot-coms ran out of capital and were acquired or liquidated; Various supporting industries, such as advertising and shipping, scaled back their operations as demand for their services fell. Telecoms loan defaults totalled $ 60 billion; there were redundancies in the thousands at investment banks; more than 300,000 jobs were destroyed in six months at telecoms equipment manufacturers and as many as 200,000 jobs in components suppliers and associated industries. The stock market value of all telecom operators and manufacturers fell by $ 3800 billion since its peak of $ 6300 billion in March 2000. In comparison, the combined cost of the crisis of the late 1990s was only $ 813 billion. |
Argentina 2001 |
In March 2001, a bank run started due to increasing doubts about the sustainability of the currency board, strong opposition from the public to the new fiscal austerity package sent to the Congress, the resignation of president of the Central Bank, and the amendment to the convertibility law (change in parity from being pegged to the dollar to being pegged to a basket composed of the US dollar and Euro). During the second half of 2001, bank runs intensified. On December 3, 2001, as several banks were on the verge of collapse, partial withdrawal restrictions (corralito) were imposed on transactional accounts while fixed-term deposits (CDs) were reprogrammed (corralon) in order to stop outflows from banks. On February 4, 2002, bank assets were asymmetrically pacified, adversely affecting the solvency of the banking system. |
In 2002, two voluntary swaps of deposits for government bonds were offered but received little interest from the public. In December 2002, the corralito was lifted. By August 2003, one bank had been closed, three banks nationalised, and many others had reduced their staff and branches. The output loss was 42.7 per cent of GDP and real GDP declined by 10.9 per cent in the crisis year. |
Causes of Financial Crises
2.80 In the literature, two broad approaches
have been used to describe the causes of the
crises. The first view, expounded by Kindleberger
(1978), is that crises occur spontaneously as the
result of mob psychology or panic. If everyone
expects a crisis and acts as if one is about to
occur, then the crisis becomes a self-fulfilling
prophecy and vice versa. The second view asserts
that crises are an intrinsic part of the business
cycle and result from shocks to economic
fundamentals (Mitchell, 1941). When the
economy goes into a recession or depression,
asset returns are expected to fall, borrowers have
difficulty in repaying loans and depositors,
anticipating an increase in defaults or nonperforming
loans, try to protect their wealth by
withdrawing bank deposits. Banks are caught
between the illiquidity of their assets and their
relatively liquid liabilities and may become
insolvent. This results in panic though the actual
cause is different. Empirical evidence on the
cause of crises is mixed. While some support the
panic view (Friedman and Schwartz, 1963), many
counter it and provide a wider range of evidence
that crises are fundamental based rather than panic based. (Calomiris and Gorton, 1991;
Calomiris and Mason, 2003a). In the literature,
several explanations for the causes of crises are
given. In this section, some of these debates are
captured under the following heads:
Financial and Panic Dimensions of Crises
2.81 A crisis normally has two fundamental
dimensions – one is financial and the other is panic,
which is often the trigger. First, shocks to bank
liquidity, payments systems, and solvency are
obvious characteristics of financial crises. Second,
a panic strike – a sudden and dramatic loss of
depositor and investor confidence – is often the
precipitating event. When both financial and panic
dimensions collide, they set off a chain reaction
and a country begins to spiral downward, as panic
and loss of confidence increase problems in the
banking system as well as the real economy at the
microeconomic level (Barton et al., 2003). Contagion
between countries occurs as well. Financial crises
are largely attributed to rapid reversals in
international capital flows and prompted chiefly by
changes in international investment conditions.
Flow reversals are likely to trigger sudden capital
account adjustments and, subsequently, currency and banking crises (Eichengreen and Rose, 1998;
Frankel and Rose, 1996).
Imbalances in Domestic Economy
2.82 An analysis of the history of financial crises
indicates that five elements contribute to a crisis:
the real economy; the financial sector; the macroeconomy;
international money and capital flows;
and asset pricing. When these elements are in
balance, the economy generally runs well but when
any of these elements run out of balance and affect
other elements, the conditions become ripe for a
financial crisis (Barton et al, 2003).
(i) Imbalances can be caused by real sector
under-performance, leading to a gradual
erosion of the value of assets over time when
companies fail to earn adequate return above
their cost of capital.
(ii) Imbalances can be caused by much needed but
poorly executed market liberalisation, where
aggressive reforms are introduced that outpace
the economy’s ability to absorb them.
(iii) Unsustainable imbalances can also build up in
the financial systems of countries with the
uneven opening up of the market to foreign
capital flows or deregulation in the financial
sector. This was the case in most of the
emerging market crises during the 1980s and
1990s and most notably the East Asian crisis.
(iv) Imbalances can also arise as a result of
unsustainable macroeconomic policies such as
untenable fiscal deficits, overvalued currencies
and too rapid credit growth in the economy
fuelled either by foreign funding flows or
unsustainable monetary policies.
2.83 Most of the debt crises can be attributed to
these factors. All these factors acted as precursors
to the Latin American debt crisis. The pattern over
time starts with trouble in the real and banking
sectors and then builds until either external shocks (such as currency attacks) or internal shocks (such
as bank runs by depositors) finally trigger a fullblown
crisis.
Crisis Led by Financial and Technical Innovation
2.84 Historians, notably Charles Kindleberger,
have pointed out that crises often follow soon after
major financial or technical innovations that present
investors with new types of financial opportunities,
which he called “displacements” of investors’
expectations. Unfamiliarity with technical and
financial innovations may help explain how
investors sometimes grossly overestimate asset
values. Also, if the first investors in a new class of
assets (for example, stock in dot-com companies)
profit from rising asset values then, as other
investors learn about the innovation, more people
may follow their example, driving the price even
higher as they rush to buy in hopes of similar profits.
If such “herd behaviour” or “climbing onto the
bandwagon” causes prices to spiral far above the
true value of the assets, a crash becomes
inevitable. If for any reason the price briefly falls
so that investors realise that further gains are not
assured, the spiral may go into reverse, with price
decreases causing a rush of sales, reinforcing the
decrease in prices. Early examples include the
South Sea Bubble6 and Mississippi Bubble of 1720,
which occurred when the notion of investment in
shares of company stock was itself new and
unfamiliar, and the crash of 1929, which followed
the introduction of new electrical and transportation
technologies. More recently, many financial crises
followed changes in the investment environment
brought about by financial deregulation; the crash
of the dot-com bubble in 2001 began with “irrational
exuberance” about Internet technology.
Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard in Financial
Markets
2.85 Mishkin (1991b) examined episodes of
financial crisis from 1857 to 1987. According to this analysis, five factors in the economic environment
can lead to substantial worsening of adverse
selection and moral hazard in financial markets,
which then cause a financial crisis and shift the
economy from equilibrium with high output to one
with low output because the financial system is
unable to channel funds to those with the best
investment opportunities. The factors causing
financial crises are increase in interest rates, stock
market declines, increase in uncertainty, bank
panics, and unanticipated declines in aggregate
price level as elaborated below :
(i) Increases in interest rates are generally the
precursors of crises as individuals and firms
who are willing to pay the highest interest rates
are those with the riskiest investment projects.
Generally, market interest rates experience a
sudden spike driven up by increased demand
for credit or a decline in the money supply. In
this scenario, those with bad credit risks are still
willing to borrow while those having good credit
risks lose their appetite to borrow. The resultant
adverse selection possibly leads to a steep
decline in lending as lenders are not willing to
extend credit which, in turn, leads to a
substantial decline in investment and aggregate
economic activity.
(ii) As emphasised by Greenwald and Stiglitz
(1988), Bernanke and Gertler (1990), and
Calomiris and Hubbard (1989), a sharp decline
in the stock market can increase adverse
selection and moral hazard problems in financial
markets because it leads to a large decline in
the market value of the firms’ net worth. This
results in decline in lending, which in turn
causes investment and aggregate output to
decline. The Great Depression of the 1930s was
preceded by a sharp decline in the stock market
in October 1929.
(iii) A dramatic increase in uncertainty in financial
markets, due perhaps to the failure of a
prominent financial or non-financial institution,
a recession, or a stock market crash, makes it
harder for lenders to screen good from bad credit risks. It increases the severity of adverse
selection problems in credit markets, while the
decline in net worth stemming from the stock
market crash also results in increased moral
hazard problems. This makes them less willing
to lend, leading to a decline in lending,
investment and aggregate economic activity.
(iv) Bank panics also result in financial crises as
banks are important financial intermediaries. A
financial crisis which results in a bank panic and
the simultaneous failure of many banks, reduces
the amount of financial intermediation
undertaken by banks, and will thus lead to a
decline in investment and aggregate economic
activity (Bernanke, 1983).
(v) Finally, an unanticipated decline in price levels
causes a substantial decline in real net worth
and an increase in adverse selection and moral
hazard problems facing lenders. The resulting
increase in adverse selection and agency
problems causes a decline in investment and
economic activity.
2.86 Most financial crises in the US have begun
with a sharp rise in interest rates, a stock market
crash and an increase in uncertainty resulting from
a failure of major financial or non-financial firms
(for example, the Ohio Life Insurance & Trust Co. in
1857, the Northern Pacific Railroad and Jay Cooke
and Company in 1873, Grant & Ward in 1884, the
National Cordage Company in 1893, the
Knickerbocker Trust Company in 1907, and the
Bank of United States in 1930). Based on this
analysis, it can be concluded that stock prices
decline and the spread between interest rates for
low- and high-quality borrowers rises in the run-up
to the panic. Second, most of the panics are
preceded by substantial increases in interest rates.
Third, most panics follow a major failure of a
financial institution. This failure is often the result
of financial difficulties experienced by a nonfinancial
corporation. Financial panics generally
occur after the onset of a recession and finally the
rise in the interest rate spread associated with panic
is soon followed by a decline. However, in several cases, most notably after the 1873 panic, the 1907
panic, and the Great Depression, the interest rate
spread rises again if there is deflation and a severe
recession.
Free Capital Mobility and Banking Crisis
2.87 The economic literature has also found a
striking correlation between freer capital mobility
and the incidence of banking crises. Historically,
periods of high international capital mobility have
been followed by international banking crises.
Another striking correlation has been between
inflation and default. Recently, moral hazard-driven
investment, which leads to an excessive build-up
of external debt and collapse, bank runs and
balance sheet implications of currency depreciation
have emerged as major causes of financial crisis.
In addition to these three explanations for currency
crises, there are contagion effects. Moreover,
devaluation by one country could lead its trading
partners to devalue in order to avoid a loss of
competitiveness. Other channels such as financial
linkages can also serve to transmit contagion
effects (Calvo and Reinhart, 1996; Eichengreen et
al., 1995). Financial crises have always had an
international dimension as Morgenstern (1959),
Kindleberger (1978) and Bordo (1986) have shown.
Contagion spreads quickly through asset markets,
through international banking and through
monetary standards. Stock market crashes and
banking panics have often occurred in many
countries within a few months of the original shock.
Monetarist Dimension
2.88 The monetarist literature adds an additional
channel for how financial crises that involve bank
panics could lead to a severe downturn in the
aggregate economy. Friedman and Schwartz
(1963) document how bank panics in the United
States led to a sharp contraction in the money
supply as a result of depositors’ movement out of
deposits into currency and banks’ movement out
of loans into reserves. These contractions lead to
substantial declines in economic activity and the
price level. Most of the crises during the period 1876 to 1970 can be attributed to the reasons outlined
above, including the crises of 1876, 1907 and the
Great Depression.
First, Second and Third Generation Models
2.89 The first generation of currency crisis
models, pioneered by Krugman (1979), explained
the collapse of exchange rate regimes on the
grounds that weak fundamentals lead foreign
investors to pull resources out of the country, and
as a result, the depletion of foreign reserves needed
to sustain the currency leads to the collapse of the
exchange rate regime. The first generation models
attributed a central role to fiscal imbalances as a
fundamental determinant of crises. But this first
generation view could not explain the exchange
rate crisis faced by the UK in 1991 and the East
Asian crisis as in these crises the crucial fiscal
disequilibria were absent.
2.90 The crises in Mexico, Asia, Russia and
Brazil have underscored that a satisfactory
explanation for financial crises in emerging
markets remained elusive. The second generation
models emphasised the possibility of self-fulfilling
speculative attacks and multiple equilibria.
Currency crises have sometimes occurred even
though central banks had more than enough
resources to prevent them (Obstfeld, 1994).
Central banks may decide to abandon an
exchange rate peg when the unemployment cost
of defending it becomes too large. This new
perspective implied that crises could be driven by
self-fulfilling expectations, since the costs of
defending the peg will be maintained. An example
is the events in Europe in the early 1990s which
could be largely explained by the second
generation of models which suggest that currency
crises may occur despite sound fundamentals, as
in the case of self-fulfilling expectations (Obstfeld,
1996), speculative attacks, and changes in market
sentiment (Flood and Marion, 1996; Frankel and
Rose, 1996). In this case, seigniorage was not an
issue; the governments involved retained access
to capital markets throughout and monetary policy
was dictated by macroeconomic policy considerations and not budget needs. It was a
matter of policy choice with macroeconomic
tradeoffs and decisions. The Exchange Rate
Mechanism (ERM) crisis was caused by a conflict
between the austerity needed to defend a fixed
exchange rate and the expansion needed to
remove high unemployment, leading to Britain’s
forced exit from the ERM in 1992 (Eichengreen
and Wyplosz, 1993).
2.91 The second generation crisis models
emphasised not the mechanical exhaustion of
foreign exchange but the problems of
macroeconomic policy. In this case a currency
crisis can develop because doubts about the
government’s willingness to defend the parity force
it to raise interest rates, and the need to keep
interest rates high, in turn, raises the cost of
defending the parity to a level that the government
finds unacceptable. Obstfeld argued that crises
involve a strong element of self-fulfilling prophecy
and exchange regimes that could have survived
indefinitely nonetheless collapse if subjected to
an essentially random speculative attack. But this
explanation of mounting unemployment and
domestic recession, while appropriate for the ERM
1992 crisis, was at odds with the facts in Mexico
in 1994 and East Asia in 1997 (Chang and
Velasco, 2001). During the East Asian crisis, there
were implicit government guarantees which fuelled
moral hazard-driven excess investment. Second,
the government’s limited willingness or ability to
honour these guarantees implied that they may
not be fully credible. In the initial build-up to the
crisis, the government was able to honour these
guarantees but with the level of debt rising, there
were self-fulfilling expectations that the
government would renege, resulting in a sudden
collapse with a sharp fall in output and capital
stock. This was the third generation currency crisis
in which there was large currency depreciation
which created havoc with balance sheets and the
economy plunged into crisis equilibrium. The third
generation model stressed how financial fragility
can lead to a currency crisis.
Common Elements in Crises
2.92 There are, however, some elements that are
common to the financial crises in emerging markets
witnessed in recent years. Elements in common
include a dramatic swing in the current account, a
large real depreciation and a significant decline in
real output. The pattern in all these crises and a
number of historical crises appears to involve three
broad elements.
2.93 First, after a period of substantial capital
inflows, investors (both domestic and foreign)
decided to reduce their stock of assets in the
affected country in response to a change in its
fundamentals. This could be attributed to reasons
such as concerns about the viability of the exchange
rate regime, as in most of these cases, concern
about large fiscal deficits, as in Russia and Brazil,
concern about large current account deficits, as in
Thailand and Brazil; and the increasing salience of
long-standing financial sector weaknesses, arising
from some combination of insufficient capitalisation
and supervision of banks and excessive leverage
and guarantee (Summers, 2000).
2.94 Second, after this process continued for
some time in these emerging market economies,
investors shifted their focus from evaluating the
situation in the country to evaluating the behaviour
of other investors. The rate of withdrawal increased
as a bank-run psychology took hold.
2.95 Third, the withdrawal of capital and the
associated sharp swing in the exchange rate and
reduced access to capital exacerbated fundamental
weaknesses, in turn exacerbating the response of
the financial market. The real depreciation of
exchange rate reduced real incomes and spending.
Extrapolative expectations regarding a falling
exchange rate increased pressure for capital flight.
And, most importantly, the increased domestic
value of foreign currency liabilities and reduced
credit worthiness of domestic borrowers further
degraded an already ailing financial system, in turn
causing further reductions in lending and worsening
of fundamentals.
2.96 In nearly all recent crises, serious banking
and financial sector weaknesses played an
important role. Fixed exchange rates without the
concomitant monetary policy commitments were
present as antecedents to the crisis in all cases.
Traditional macroeconomic fundamentals in the
form of overly inflationary monetary policies,
large fiscal deficits or even large current account
deficits were present in all episodes. National
balance sheet weaknesses, including large shortterm
liabilities either of the government or the
private sector were important elements in each
of the crises.
2.97 In short, among the many causes of
financial crises the important ones are: a
combination of unsustainable macroeconomic
policies (including large current account deficits and
unsustainable public debt), large capital inflows and
balance sheet fragilities, and excessive credit
booms, combined with policy paralysis due to a
variety of political and economic constraints. In
some financial crises, currency and maturity
mismatches were a salient feature, while in others
off-balance sheet operations of the banking sector
are prominent. An analysis of the causes of the
financial crises reveals that though the trigger
points differ, some common threads run through
the financial upheavals: first, an excessive use of
credit; second, a discernible lowering of credit
standards; and third, heavy reliance on leverage.
Institutional weaknesses typically aggravate the
crisis and complicate crisis resolution. Bankruptcy
and restructuring frameworks are often deficient
and disclosure and accounting rules for financial
institutions and corporations are also weak. Many
financial crises, especially those in countries with
fixed exchange rates, turn out to be twin crises with
currency depreciation exacerbating banking sector
problems through foreign currency exposures of
borrowers or banks themselves (Laeven and
Valencia, 2008).
Effects of Crisis
2.98 Financial crises can be damaging and
contagious and have often been followed by the economies experiencing deep recessions and
sharp current account reversals. Most
macroeconomic and financial variables exhibited
procyclical behaviour during recessions, except for
two key policy-related variables – short-term
interest rates and fiscal expenditures – which often
behaved countercyclical during recessions. An
analysis of the impact of financial crises which
occurred in the past 150 years reveals that there
are several channels through which the financial
crisis, the associated increase in risk aversion and
the ensuing recession have affected the macro
economy. Financial and macroeconomic variables
closely interacted through wealth and substitution
effects, and through the impact that they had on
the balance sheets of firms and households
(Blanchard and Fischer, 1989; Obstfeld and
Rogoff, 1999).
2.99 It was found that the recessions were often
characterised by sharp declines in investment,
industrial production, imports, and housing and
equity prices, modest declines in consumption and
exports, and some decrease in employment rates.
After any financial crisis, most countries generally
experienced an increase in both corporate and
sovereign bond rates, indicating an increase in risk
premiums. The resulting increase in the cost of
borrowing affected investment activity. There was
a general decrease in the availability of credit.
Liquidity constraints affected not only the price of
credit, but also the quantity available as financial
institutions rationed credit, regardless of price.
Banks became wary of extending loans. Moreover,
the real effects of the economic slowdown and
lower demand affected revenue cash flows which
had knock-on effects for debt servicing capacity and
overall profitability. Generally, countries
experiencing financial crises witnessed unforeseen
exchange rate movements. These movements also
had an impact on the balance sheet and debt
servicing capacity of the economic entities.
2.100 Some financial crises have had little effect
outside the financial sector, like the Wall Street
crash of 1987, but other crises have had a
substantial adverse impact on growth in the rest of the economy. Over the past 120 years, on average,
crises have been followed by economic downturns
lasting from two to three years and costing 5 to 10
per cent of GDP (Bordo et al., 2001). Twin crises
(both banking and currency) generally resulted in
large output losses. Recessions that coincided with
crises turned out to be more severe than recessions
that did not coincide with crises. More often than
not, the aftermath of severe financial crises shared
three characteristics. First, asset market collapses
were deep and prolonged. Real housing price
declines averaged 35 per cent stretched out over
six years, while equity price collapses averaged 55
per cent over a downturn of about three and a half
years. Second, the aftermath of banking crises
resulted in profound declines in output and
employment. The unemployment rate rose by an
average of 7 percentage points over the down
phase of the cycle, which on an average lasted
more than four years. Output fell (from peak to
trough) by an average of over 9 per cent. The
duration of the downturn, averaging roughly two
years, was considerably shorter than for
unemployment. Third, the real value of government
debt rose sharply, rising by an average of 86 per
cent in the major post–World War II episodes
(Reinhart and Rogoff, 2008). The major drivers of
debt increases were the inevitable collapse in tax
revenues that governments suffered in the wake
of deep and prolonged output contractions, as well
as often ambitious countercyclical fiscal policies
aimed at mitigating the downturn.
2.101 In the aftermath of a financial crisis,
commercial banks, the most common source of
credit, generally imposed more stringent credit
standards and also increased interest rate spreads
and fees. In addition, deteriorating financial
positions in both the business and the household
sectors reduced the creditworthiness of business
enterprises and thereby constrained their access
to credit. A financial crisis implies poor functioning
of financial markets. The inadequate performance
of financial markets led to the limited entry of new
firms, low production in the firms, and greater
financial constraints for business enterprises (Anna and Robert, 2005). According to Milesi-Ferreti and
Razin (1998), currency crises and the resultant
currency crashes in emerging market economies
have normally led to sharp declines in output. Bank
runs have been a common feature of currency
crises, with 62 per cent of crises experiencing
momentary sharp reductions in total deposits. The
result of a banking crisis associated with a currency
crisis was large-scale capital flight, forcing official
intervention to support the banking system and the
imposition of capital controls to prevent the collapse
of the currency. Severe bank runs have often been
system-wide; however, a flight-to-quality effect
within the system from unsound banks to sound
banks has generally been witnessed. During the
Indonesian crisis in 1997, private national banks
lost 35 trillion rupiah in deposits between October
and December 1997, while state-owned banks and
foreign and joint venture banks gained 12 and 2
trillion rupiah, respectively (Batunanggar, 2002).
2.102 A financial crisis and the resultant
recession quite often led to a drop in imports. The
weakening or collapse of the financial system, in
particular the banking system, weakens the
country’s export capability, affecting overall trade.
During a currency crisis, the exchange rate
scenario also becomes more uncertain. Due to
sharp currency depreciation, consumers suffer
wealth losses due to money holdings, forcing
consumers to decrease their consumption.
Furthermore, financial crises (including currency
crises, banking crises or both) have also affected
trade, besides the exchange rate. Reinhart (1999)
pointed out that financial crises usually caused
capital account reversal (“sudden stop”) and
triggered an economic recession. Mendoza (2001)
showed that in an economy with imperfect credit
markets these sudden stops could be an equilibrium
outcome. The economic recession reduced not only
domestic demand, but also total output. Several
Latin American countries (e.g., Mexico, Brazil and
Venezuela) stopped repaying their foreign debt
during debt crises in the 1980s.
2.103 In the early models, crises were thought
of as monetary events with few real consequences. However, an analysis of the history of financial
crises reveals that most of the recessions have
been caused for the most part by financial crises.
One important example is the Great Depression,
which was preceded in many countries by bank
runs and stock market crashes. The most severe
panic episodes were in 1857, 1873, 1893, 1907
and 1930-33, which resulted in the most severe
economic contractions in 1857-58, 1873-79, 1893-
94, 1907-08 and 1929-33.
2.104 To sum up, financial crises have been a
part of the economic landscape since the
beginning. The definition and categorisation of
financial crises has evolved with time. The crisis
chronologies suggest that financial crises have
been chronic problems not only in the present era
but in earlier periods as well. An analysis of the
history of financial crises indicates that imbalance
in the real economy combined with weakness in
the financial sector, ebbs and flows in international
money and capital, and asset mis-pricing generally
contribute to a crisis. Financial crises have
generally been followed by severe economic
contractions.
III. HOW THE RECENT CRISIS DIFFERS FROM
EARLIER CRISES
2.105 The recent global financial crisis that had
turned into an economic crisis is the first major
financial crisis of the 21st century and it is essential
to understand how it differs from the crises of the
20th century. While there is still considerable
debate on the appropriate policies to be adopted
to set the world house in order, there are now
ample indications and an almost unanimous view
that the recent global crisis is the worst since the
Great Depression of the 1930s in terms of
geographical spread and intensity. With all the
advanced economies in a synchronised recession,
global GDP is estimated to have contracted for
the first time since the Second World War. Though
the recent crisis is being compared with the Great
Depression, this crisis is different because it is
the first truly global crisis. Amongst the crises that
have originated in the United States or elsewhere, this is the first crisis that has affected the whole
world which even the Great Depression did not
(Table 2.12). The United States and Europe, which
had become dependent on the financial sector as
their engine of growth, were at the epicentre of
the crisis. Asia got affected because of the sharp
decline in demand for their exports from the
developed world, Eastern Europe was hit by the
reversal of capital flows, and African and South
American economies suffered through the huge
drop in commodity prices and deterioration in their
terms of trade. India was impacted both during
Great Depression as well as during the recent
financial crisis. However, India being a British
colony, the nature of impact during the Great
Depression was more complex (Box II.6).
2.106 Cross-crisis comparisons are usually
based on the duration and depth of the crises
(Bordo et al., 2001; Cecchetti et al., 2009). Duration
is defined as the number of quarters it takes for
output to recover to its pre-crisis level. Crisis depth
is defined as the peak-to-trough percentage decline
in GDP; in addition, crisis depth is proxied by the
cumulative loss in GDP over the length of the crisis,
taken as a fraction of its peak (pre-crisis) level.
Estimates suggest that while the recent crisis is
comparable with some of the previous crises in
terms of crisis duration, the cost of the recent crisis
in terms of cumulative GDP loss has undoubtedly
been more severe than that of the Great Depression or any other crisis (Table 2.13). This is despite
unprecedented monetary and fiscal measures and
unprecedented international co-ordination.
Table 2.12: Global Crises Originating in the USA |
|
Affected Countries |
|
Advanced |
Developing |
1 |
2 |
3 |
New York Panic of
October 1907 |
US, Denmark,
France, Italy, Japan, Sweden |
Mexico |
Great Depression
of 1929 |
US, France, Italy,
Belgium, Finland,
Germany, Greece, Portugal, Spain, Sweden |
Brazil, India,
Mexico, Argentina,
China |
Global financial
crisis of 2007 |
US, UK, Euro
zone, Japan |
Asia, Africa, Latin
America and
Eastern Europe |
Box II.6
The Great Depression and India
The Great Depression of 1929 had a very severe impact
on India, which was then a colony of Britain. India was
one of the earliest countries to have been hit by the Great
Depression. The Depression started in India around the
fourth quarter of 1929, just one quarter after the US. India
was impacted through both direct and indirect channels.
First, the US-originated Great Depression impacted India
directly as the Indian economy was more open to trade
and financial flows. Estimates indicate that preindependent
India’s share in world trade was about 10
per cent unlike around 1 per cent in recent times. Second,
India being a British colony was also impacted indirectly
as the United Kingdom was hit by the Depression. The
fact that the Indian economy functioned under the colonial
aegis further added complexity to the whole issue. The
agricultural sector and the railways were the most affected.
The international financial crisis combined with
detrimental policies adopted by the Government of India
resulted in the soaring prices of commodities. Farmers
who were cultivating food crops had earlier moved over
to cash crop cultivation in large numbers to meet the
demands of the textile mills in the United Kingdom. Due
to the high prices, farmers were unable to sell their
products in India; nor could they export the commodities
to the United Kingdom which adopted a protective policy
prohibiting imports from India. Unlike food grains like rice
and wheat, cash crops could not be used for private
consumption. As there was little sale of indigenous
manufactures and limited exports, commodities
accumulated and the flow of cash was restricted.
During the period 1929–1937, exports and imports fell
drastically, crippling seaborne international trade. Due to
a decline in exports and imports, and, thereby, in the
transportation of goods, railway revenues decreased
exponentially. All the expenses for the years 1930–31 and
1931–32 were paid from the Railway Reserve Fund.
In British India, apart from existing imports and exports, there
was also a particular amount of money which colonial India
contributed towards administration, maintenance of the army, war expenses, pensions to retired officers and other
expenses accrued by Britain towards maintenance of her
colony called ‘Home charges’. Due to the drastic collapse
of international trade and the very little revenues generated,
India had to face a severe balance of payments crisis. India
could only pay for her invisible imports through home
charges by selling off her gold reserves. From 1931–32 to
1934–35, India exported Rs. 2,330 million worth of gold.
Like all agricultural countries, India also experienced
deterioration in terms of trade. Export prices declined faster
than import prices. Most agricultural countries such as
Australia, New Zealand, Brazil and Denmark reacted by
depreciating their exchange rates. However, the British Raj
did not opt for this course of action. Another recommended
policy action during this period could have been an increase
in government expenditure. But the colonial Government
did just the opposite, making the incidence of the Great
Depression even more severe (Manikumar, 2003).
The policies of the Government of India during the Great
Depression resulted in widespread protests all over the
country. High prices along with the stringent taxes
prevalent in British India increased the extent of discontent
amongst farmers. The Salt Satyagraha of 1930 was one
of the measures undertaken as a response to heavy
taxation during the Great Depression. Furthermore, as the
national struggle intensified, the Government of India
conceded some of the economic demands of the
nationalists, including the establishment of a central bank.
Accordingly, the Reserve Bank of India Act was passed in
1934 and a central bank came into being on April 1, 1935
with Sir Osborne Smith as its first Governor.
References
-
Manikumar, K. A. (2003), ‘A Colonial Economy in the
Great Depression, Madras (1929–1937)’. Orient
Blackswan.
-
Balachandran, G. (1996), ‘John Bullion’s Empire:
Britain’s Gold Problem and India Between the Wars’.
Global Imbalances in the Past
2.107 While global imbalances have existed in
the past, the unique feature of the recent situation is that the emerging economies have been the
creditor countries financing the deficit in advanced
countries. In the past, the reverse scenario was
observed when capital flowed from rich to poor
nations. For example, during the gold standard era
(until 1914), a large flow of capital took place from
industrial countries (mostly the United Kingdom and France) to the (then) emerging markets, such as
Canada or Australia with significant stability in
exchange rates and no evidence of disorderly
unwinding (Table 2.14). A similar nature of capital
flow was observed during the 1990s when the
advanced countries had invested in the EMEs in
Asia, Latin America and Russia. Many of these
EMEs, however, faced severe financial debt crises
on account of the composition of their debt,
marking a disorderly unwinding though the
creditors did not suffer much. In addition, there
were episodes where capital moved within
emerging markets or among advanced economies.
In the 1970s, a major terms of trade shock
occurred in the world economy, implying a net
transfer of resources from oil-importing countries
(mostly in Latin America) to oil-exporting countries
of the Gulf. The unwinding, however, was not smooth for either. On the contrary, the widening
of the US deficits in the 1980s financed by
surpluses in Japan, Germany and Netherlands
saw a relatively orderly unwinding of the
imbalances with the gradual depreciation of the
US dollar (Bracke et al., 2008).
Table 2.13: Duration and Depth of Financial Crises |
Period |
Average Duration of Crisis in Years |
Average Crisis Depth (in terms of cumulative GDP loss relative to peak in per cent) |
1 |
2 |
3 |
1880-1913 (includes Baring crisis of
1890, New York panic of 1907) |
2.4 |
9.8 |
1919-1939 (includes period of
Great Depression) |
2.4 |
13.4 |
1945-1971 |
1.8 |
5.2 |
1973-1997 (includes Latin American
crisis of 1980s, ERM crisis of 1992 and
Asian and Russian crisis of 1997-98) |
2.5-2.6 |
7.8-8.3 |
2007-08 (Global Recession of 2008) |
2.5 |
20 |
Source: Estimates from Bordo et al., 2001; Cecchetti et al., 2009. |
2.108 No country in the world today – neither
the advanced nor the emerging market economies
– has been spared from the consequences,
although the impact has varied across nations. The
recent crisis, in fact, can be considered either as
an ‘advanced country’ crisis, an ‘emerging market
economies’ crisis, a truly ‘global crisis’ or
combination of all. Hence, studies have mostly
attempted to compare the recent crisis with previous
advanced country crises, EME crises of the recent
past, and the Great Depression of the 1930s.
Recent Crisis vs. Advanced Country Crises
2.109 Each financial crisis has certain distinctive
characteristics. Yet a comparison reveals that most
of them at times exhibit remarkable similarities. The
majority of historical crises are preceded by
financial liberalisation (Kaminsky and Reinhart,
1999). While financial liberalisation has been an
inherent feature of the US economy for years, the
run-up to the recent crisis has generally been
marked by several financial excesses that went
beyond the regulatory purview. In addition, the
current crisis exhibits several similarities to the
previous advanced country crises with regard to
the behaviour of asset prices, credit expansion,
debt accumulation and current account deficits,
though the extent has varied.
2.110 Reinhart and Rogoff (2008) compared the
recent US sub-prime crisis with 18 other bankcentred
advanced country financial crises from the
post-War period. These crisis episodes include the
Big Five Crises of Spain (1978-79), Norway (1987-
88), Finland (1990-93), Sweden (1990-93) and
Japan (1992-93) that are protracted large-scale
financial crises associated with major declines in
economic performance (recessions) for an
extended period. The list also includes 13 other banking and financial crises in advanced countries
that were relatively milder with limited impact; these
include Australia (1989), Canada (1983), Denmark
(1987), France (Credit Lyonnaise bail-out in 1994),
Germany (1977), Greece (1991), Iceland (1985),
Italy (1990), New Zealand (1987), the United
Kingdom (1973, 1991, Barings Investment Bank
crisis of 1995), and the United States (Savings and
Loan crisis of 1984).
Table 2.14: Previous Episodes of Global Imbalances |
Era |
Region |
Orderly Unwinding for |
|
Creditor |
Debtor |
Creditors |
Debtors |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
Gold Standard (<1914) |
Advanced |
Emerging |
Yes |
Yes |
1970s |
Emerging |
Emerging |
No |
No |
1980s |
Advanced |
Advanced |
Some |
Yes |
1990s |
Advanced |
Emerging |
Yes |
No |
2000s |
Emerging |
Advanced |
? |
? |
Source: ECB Occasional Paper Series, January 2008. |
2.111 As regards the impact on real per capita
GDP, the average growth decline has been around
5 percentage points for the Big Five crises and
about 2-3 percentage points for the other banking crises of the advanced countries. The cumulative
output losses have varied amongst countries. The
cumulative loss of GDP for the recent crisis is
generally estimated to be greater than in some of
the advanced country crises7, though in terms of
duration the recent crisis is expected to be milder
than other advanced country crisis (Table 2.15).
2.112 As regards the initial conditions among
advanced economies, the imbalances in the buildup
to most of these crises were minor when
compared with the recent crisis. The average
current account balances for banking crises in
advanced countries rarely exceeded 3 per cent of GDP on the eve of crises, while US deficits reached
over 6 per cent of GDP prior to the recent crisis
(Table 2.16, also refer to Table 2.3). Most advanced
country banking crises were associated with
significant increases in housing prices in the period
prior to the crisis though the increase has been
much sharper in the United States during 2006 than
in other episodes. Further, the public debt as a
share of GDP has risen much more slowly in the
United States in the years preceding the crisis than
it did either in the run-up to the Big Five crises/
ERM or other advanced country banking crisis. This
is essentially because unlike other episodes, the
recent crisis has seen a substantial build-up of
private US debt.
Table 2.15: Systemic Crises: Broad Indicators |
(in per cent) |
Crisis/Countries |
Starting Date |
Average
Duration of
the Crisis
(No. of
quarters) |
Average
Crisis
Depth* |
Cumulative
Loss
relative
to Peak |
Minimum
Real GDP
Growth
Rate |
Gross
Fiscal Cost
(as % of
GDP) |
Share of
NPL at
Peak |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
Latin American Crisis (1980s) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Argentina |
Mar 1980 |
28 |
14.1 |
-44.5 |
-5.7 |
55.1 |
9 |
Chile |
November 1981 |
21 |
20.2 |
-60.1 |
-13.6 |
42.9 |
35.6 |
Columbia |
July 1982 |
0 |
0.0 |
0.0 |
0.9 |
5 |
4.1 |
Latin American Crisis (1990s) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Argentina |
January 1995 |
7 |
6.1 |
-5.2 |
-2.8 |
2 |
17 |
Brazil |
December 1994 |
7 |
2.5 |
-1.9 |
2.1 |
13.2 |
16 |
Mexico |
December 1994 |
9 |
10.4 |
-10.7 |
-6.2 |
19.3 |
18.9 |
ERM Crisis |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Estonia |
November 1992 |
33 |
27.3 |
-116.8 |
-21.6 |
1.9 |
7 |
Finland |
September 1991 |
25 |
11.8 |
-40.7 |
-6.2 |
12.8 |
13 |
Norway |
October 1991 |
3 |
1.5 |
-0.6 |
2.8 |
2.7 |
16.4 |
Sweden |
September 1991 |
16 |
5.8 |
-11.0 |
-1.2 |
3.6 |
13 |
Banking Crisis of Spain |
1977 |
20 |
– |
– |
0.2 |
5.6 |
- |
Japanese Crisis of 1990s |
November 1997 |
15 |
3.4 |
-6.7 |
-2 |
14 |
35 |
United States Savings and Loan Crisis |
1988 |
– |
– |
– |
-0.2 |
3.7 |
4.1 |
Asian Crisis |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Indonesia |
November 1997 |
21 |
18.1 |
-50.7 |
-13.1 |
56.8 |
32.5 |
Thailand |
July 1997 |
23 |
14.9 |
-33.2 |
-10.5 |
43.8 |
33 |
Malaysia |
July 1997 |
9 |
11.2 |
-13.8 |
-7.4 |
16.4 |
30 |
Korea |
August 1997 |
7 |
9.2 |
-9.3 |
-6.9 |
31.2 |
35 |
Philippines |
July 1997 |
6 |
2.7 |
-2.2 |
-0.6 |
13.2 |
20 |
Current Global Crisis |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
United States |
August 2007 |
10 |
5 |
-20 |
-2.7 |
– |
4.8 |
United Kingdom |
August 2007 |
10 |
5 |
-20 |
-4.4 |
– |
– |
* : Peak-to-trough decline in GDP in per cent.
Source: Ceccheti et al (2009), Laeven and Valencia (2008) and IMF database. |
2.113 Another similarity is the mechanism of
recycling petro dollars during the 1970s vis-à-vis the 2000s. During the 1970s, the US banking
system stood as an intermediary between oilexporting
surplus countries and emerging market
borrowers in Latin America and elsewhere that
ultimately culminated in the 1980s’ debt crises
of the EMEs. In the recent crisis, a large volume
of petro-dollars was again flowing into the United
States; however, with many emerging markets
running current account surpluses a large chunk
of these petro-dollars got recycled to a
developing economy that existed within the
United States in the form of a “developing subprime
mortgage economy” (Reinhart et al., 2008).
Thus, there were several qualitative, if not
quantitative, parallels with the formative years of
the previous post-war financial crises in
industrialised countries.
Table 2.16: Cross-Country Crises: Initial Conditions |
|
Starting Date (t) |
Currency
Crisis
(Y/N)
(t-1, t+1) |
Fiscal
Balance/
GDP
at t-1 |
Public
Sector
Debt/
GDP
at t-1
(per cent) |
Inflation
at t-1 |
Net
Foreign
Assets /
M2 at t-1 |
Current
Account/
GDP
at t-1 |
Significant
bank runs
(Y/N) |
Credit
Boom
(Y/N) |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
Latin American Crisis (1980s) |
Argentina |
March 1980 |
Y |
-2.7 |
10.2 |
139.7 |
34.2 |
0.6 |
Y |
Y |
Chile |
Nov 1981 |
Y |
5.0 |
0.0 |
31.2 |
42.2 |
-6.4 |
Y |
Y |
Columbia |
July 1982 |
N |
-2.3 |
– |
26.3 |
46.0 |
-4.1 |
N |
N |
Latin American Crisis (1990s) |
Argentina |
Jan 1995 |
N |
0.0 |
33.7 |
3.9 |
25.9 |
-2.8 |
Y |
Y |
Brazil |
Dec 1994 |
Y |
0.3 |
23.0 |
2477.2 |
22.7 |
-0.1 |
Y |
N |
Mexico |
Dec 1994 |
Y |
-2.5 |
27.3 |
8.0 |
18.1 |
-5.8 |
Y |
Y |
ERM Crisis |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Estonia |
Nov 1992 |
Y |
5.3 |
– |
– |
57.6 |
59.7 |
Y |
– |
Finland |
Sept 1991 |
N |
5.6 |
14.0 |
4.9 |
12.7 |
-4.9 |
N |
N |
Norway |
Oct 1991 |
N |
2.5 |
28.9 |
4.4 |
10.3 |
2.5 |
N |
N |
Sweden |
Sept 1991 |
Y |
3.4 |
– |
10.9 |
4.8 |
-2.6 |
Y |
– |
Japanese Crisis of 1990s |
Nov-1997 |
N |
-5.1 |
100.5 |
0.6 |
1.6 |
1.4 |
N |
N |
Asian Crisis |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Indonesia |
Nov 1997 |
Y |
-1.1 |
26.4 |
6.0 |
21.6 |
-2.9 |
Y |
N |
Thailand |
July 1997 |
N |
2.4 |
14.2 |
4.8 |
25.1 |
-7.9 |
N |
Y |
Malaysia |
July 1997 |
Y |
2.0 |
35.2 |
3.3 |
23.2 |
-4.4 |
Y |
N |
Korea |
August1997 |
Y |
0.2 |
8.8 |
4.9 |
15.6 |
-4.1 |
Y |
N |
Philippines |
July 1997 |
Y |
-0.2 |
– |
7.1 |
19.0 |
-0.2 |
N |
Y |
Current Global Crisis |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
United States |
Aug-2007 |
N |
-2.6 |
60.1 |
2.6 |
1.0 |
-6.2 |
N |
N |
UK |
Aug-2007 |
N |
-2.6 |
43.0 |
2.8 |
1.4 |
-3.6 |
N |
N |
Y : Yes. N: No
Source: Laeven and Valencia (2008) and IMF database. |
2.114 In the case of advanced countries, studies
show that recessions associated with financial
crises have typically been more severe and
protracted, whereas recoveries from recessions
associated with financial crises have typically been
slower, held back by weak private demand and
credit. Highly synchronised recession episodes
among advanced countries are generally longer
and deeper than other recessions, and recoveries
are very weak. Also, developments in the United
States have generally played a pivotal role in both
the severity and duration of these highly
synchronised recessions (IMF, 2009b). The
recent recession is also highly synchronised as is
the case with some other previous episodes in 1907
and 1939. The rapid drop in consumption in the
United States resulted in large declines in external
demand in many other economies. Hence,
recovery in the US has significant implications for
advanced countries.
Recent Crisis vs. EME Crises
2.115 EMEs across the world have faced several
crises that are either regional – the Latin American
and Asian crises – or individual country crises as
in Argentina, Russia and Turkey. At the macro level,
these EMEs having learnt lessons from their own
past currency and financial crises, built up reserves
and strengthened their financial systems apart
from consciously developing their financial
markets. They have also been careful to ensure
that their banks were not involved excessively in
toxic assets or innovative transactions (Thorat,
2009). Even so, these countries have had to face
the consequences of the recent crisis and the
consequent fall in global trade and GDP,
unemployment and slowing credit growth.
2.116 The recent crisis turned out to be more
severe, affecting large parts of the world along with
EMEs simultaneously and, hence, traditional coping
mechanisms at national and sub-national levels
became less effective than they were in the past.
During previous EME crises that remained confined
to individual countries or to a particular region,
countries tended to rely on large exchange-rate depreciations to adjust to macroeconomic shocks.
During the 2009 global crisis, however, the scope
for real exchange-rate depreciation was more
limited, leaving less room for the developing
economies to adjust to the rapidly changing
economic conditions. Besides, most of the previous
EME crises were essentially traditional retail
banking and currency crises. During these crises,
richer countries buffered the fall by bailing out the
troubled regions. In contrast, the recent crisis hit
at the very heart of global finance with no buffer to
fall back on. In fact, the major factor that
differentiates the recent crisis from those of the past
is that developing countries have become more
integrated, both financially and commercially, into
the world economy than they were 20 years ago.
As a consequence, they were more exposed to
changes in the international market.
2.117 Although the recent financial crisis did not
originate in the EMEs, it has impacted capital flows
to EMEs more severely than in earlier crises that
actually originated in the EMEs (for instance, the
Latin American and Asian crises). Net capital flows
to EMEs fell from 4.2 per cent of GDP in 1981 to
1.6 per cent of GDP in 1986. They fell from above
5 per cent of GDP in 1996-97 to a trough of around
3 per cent in 1998-99. The recent crisis has seen a
much sharper fall in capital flows from a peak of
about 7.5 per cent of GDP in 2007 to an estimated
marginal inflow in 2009 (Chart II.4). This decline
has taken place over a very short time-frame
compared with previous EME crises. This reflects
the impact of greater financial integration of EMEs
with the global economy, the increasing role of
capital flows in meeting the external financing
requirements of these economies and the
substantial deleveraging in the US and other
advanced economies. The peak capital flow in 2007
was much higher than those in earlier episodes of
capital flows to EMEs. Also, unlike the earlier
episodes, the surge in capital flows to EMEs prior
to the recent crisis has generally been associated
with surpluses in the current account as discussed
in the section on global imbalances. A region-wise
comparison reveals that the flow of capital flows was the maximum to the Latin American region in
the early 1980s and to the Asian region since the
mid-1990s. During the period prior to the crisis,
capital flows surged to all regions in 2007 before
contracting sharply in all regions in 2008, though
the contraction has been relatively sharper for
‘Emerging Europe’, amounting to more than 10 per
cent of GDP.
 |
2.118 While comparing the various financial
variables of the EMEs between the recent crisis
and the previous episodes of crises, in the previous
episodes there were frequent currency crises which
often translated into debt crises because of the
impact of large-scale devaluations of the local
currency of foreign debt (Table 2.16). In the recent
crisis, currency depreciations, though prevalent,
generally did not have an adverse impact except
in Eastern European EMEs. This could be attributed
to stronger external financial positions than in the
earlier episodes with large foreign exchange
reserves and relatively strong domestic financial
institutions8. Nonetheless, the impact on growth via
trade and capital flows has been quite severe in
the recent crisis. The volume of trade of EMEs has
seen a dip in the recent period that is much sharper than during the Asian crisis (Chart II.5).
Weaknesses in the equity market and export
markets have played a bigger role in the recent
crisis than in crises that hit the emerging world in
the recent past. While in the episodes of earlier
crises domestic demand collapsed more than the
external demand, it is the other way round in the
recent crisis. China, the largest and the leading
emerging market economy that had remained
virtually unaffected in the previous episodes, has
been affected in the recent crisis.
 |
Recent crisis vis-à-vis The Great Depression
2.119 The closest parallel to the recent crisis has
been the Great Depression. In both cases, the
United States has been at the epicentre of the crisis.
Second, both crises had a global impact. Third, both
crises were preceded by asset and credit booms.
Fourth, rapid credit expansion and financial
innovations accompanied the boom in both crises.
Fifth, liquidity and funding problems of banks and
financial intermediaries have been at the core of
both episodes. Sixth, both crises were essentially
banking and financial sector crises that turned into
economic recessions/depressions. The transmission channel from the financial sector to the real sector
that operated in both the episodes has been similar.
Problems in the financial sector reduced the
availability of funds for borrowers, led to a rise in
the marginal cost of funds, and losses from falling
asset prices reduced the net worth of borrowers.
Seventh, large similarities exist between the paths
and the levels of financial and economic variables
such as loan ratios and stock prices during both
crises (IMF, 2009b). Finally, both crises have
changed the intellectual framework of managing
economies and have revived the debate on the role
of public policy in avoiding a crisis, the so-called
Keynesianism.
2.120 Despite these similarities, the recent crisis
differs from the Great Depression in several
aspects. First, although both have been global
crises, the scale of impact in terms of the number
of countries affected has been much larger for the
recent crisis than for the Great Depression. This is
attributed to the levels of financial and economic
integration today that are much higher than in the
period prior to Great Depression, thus leading to a
larger and faster transmission of shocks from the
US to the rest of the world. Second, macroeconomic
conditions were more favourable in the recent crisis
vis-à-vis the Great Depression. The recent crisis was
preceded by a period of high growth and low
inflation with macroeconomic stability. On the other
hand, global economic conditions were weaker in
mid-1929; Germany was already in recession and
consumer prices had either stagnated or had
already started falling in Germany, UK and the US
before the start of the recession. Third, while the
credit boom prior to the Great Depression was more
US-specific, the boom prior to the recent crisis was
more global with increased leverage and risk-taking
prevalent in advanced countries and in many EMEs
(IMF, 2009a). Fourth, the origins of the recent crisis
were in wholesale banking (and, therefore, more
difficult to contain) rather than in retail banking
which was the case with the Great Depression.
Fifth, unlike in the 1930s, there is no gold standard,
which could serve to restrict how much the money
supply can be expanded. Finally, counter-cyclical policy responses were absent in the early stages
of the Great Depression. Policies were initiated only
by 1933, after the Gold Standard was given up. In
contrast, the recent downturn has seen strong and
swift monetary and fiscal policy support, which was
both global and well co-ordinated, to revive the
world economy.
Table 2.17: United States: Great Depression vs. Recent Crisis |
(Per cent) |
|
Great Depression |
Recent Crisis |
1 |
2 |
3 |
Peak Real GDP Decline |
13 in 1932 |
6 |
Unemployment Rate |
3 in 1929
to 25 in 1933 |
4.6 per cent in 2007
to 9 in 2009;
10 projected in 2010 |
Decline in Prices |
24 |
4 |
Stock Price Decline |
85 |
43 |
Increase in Fiscal Deficit |
1.5 |
3.0 |
2.121 A comparison with the Great Depression
solely on the basis of macroeconomic indicators
for the US gives the impression that the recent crisis
is not as bad as the Great Depression (Table 2.17).
The decline in GDP in 2009 is the sharpest since
the post-World War II period, yet the decline in GDP
is less than that of the post-Great Depression and
post-World War II periods (Chart II.6). However, a comparison based on world indicators such as the
world output, world stock market, world trade and
aggregate money supply indicates that the recent
crisis is worse than the Great Depression
(Eichengreen and Rourke, 2008). The only factor
that places the recent crisis better than the Great
Depression is in terms of the length/ duration of
the crisis. This is because of the swift, large, lasting
and the co-ordinated way in which the central
bankers and policymakers across the world have
responded to the recent crisis, probably learning
from the lessons of the Great Depression for
economic recovery today (details on policy
responses in Chapter 4). It is these measures that
have prevented the recent recession from
deteriorating into a depression. While a Depression
has been avoided, the recent problems in Greece
and euro area highlight the fact that the recovery
is still fragile. It may be noted here that while problems in Greek economy have been aggravated
due to the recent financial crisis, the weaknesses
in the Greek system are more structural (Box II.7).
2.122 To sum up, the recent crisis seems to be
less adverse than the previous episodes of crises
in terms of duration, although the extent of output
loss for the recent crisis is estimated to be larger.
The Great Depression seems to be the closest
equivalent to the recent crisis. Though the US has
been at the centre of both crises and both have
been essentially financial and banking crises, the
recent crisis has been more global due to the
enhanced financial linkages that prevail today.
While the Great Depression shifted the geopolitical
and economic balance from the United Kingdom
and Europe to North America, a similar shift is being
talked about from America to Asia as a
consequence of the recent crisis (Reddy, 2009b).
Box II.7
Genesis of Crisis in Greece
Greece faced a deep, structural and multifaceted crisis
characterised by large fiscal deficit, enormous public debt
and consistently eroding competitive position manifested
in a gradually deteriorating current account balance. The
economy faced a twin deficit - a general public deficit of
around 13 per cent of GDP and public debt to GDP ratio at
115 per cent in 2009; and a current account deficit of 14.6
per cent of GDP in 2008 with a moderate decline to 11.2
per cent of GDP in 2009 (Table 1).
The country’s heavy dependence on foreign borrowing
amidst slowing growth and reduced global risk appetite had
heightened concerns over long standing fiscal and external
imbalances. The country’s incapacity to correct the situation through changes in the exchange rate coupled with no fiscal
latitude has raised questions about Greece’s ability to
honour its outstanding debt obligations undermining global
confidence in Greek economy. The large fiscal and current
account deficits in other EU economies namely Portugal,
Ireland, Italy and Spain have raised concerns since early
this year (Table 2). The intensity of the problem in the
Eurozone periphery may be gauged from the systemic
concerns emanating from the large holdings of sovereign
debt paper with European banks.
Table 1: Select Macroeconomic Indicators of the Greek Economy |
Indicators |
2005 |
2006 |
2007 |
2008 |
2009 |
2010(P) |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
GDP Growth (%) |
2.2 |
4.5 |
4.5 |
2.0 |
-2.0 |
-2.0 |
Inflation (%) |
3.5 |
3.3 |
3.0 |
4.2 |
1.4 |
1.9 |
Unemployment (% of labor force) |
9.9 |
8.9 |
8.3 |
7.6 |
9.4 |
12.0 |
Gross Fiscal Deficit (% of GDP) |
-5.1 |
-3.1 |
-3.7 |
-7.8 |
-12.9 |
-8.7 |
Current Account Balance (% of GDP) |
-7.5 |
-11.3 |
-14.4 |
-14.6 |
-11.2 |
-9.7 |
Exchange Rate (Euros/US$) |
0.80 |
0.80 |
0.73 |
0.68 |
0.72 |
0.74 |
Government Bond Yield (%) |
3.6 |
4.1 |
4.5 |
4.8 |
5.2 |
6.2 |
P: Projection.
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, April 2010. |
The problems of Greece are mostly structural and they
existed even prior to the crisis. The global crisis only
amplified the chronic weaknesses in the system and
accelerated the downturn in the economy.
Fiscal Problem
-
A large part of its fragile fiscal position is attributable to its low domestic saving rate. Domestic saving rate
amounted to only 5.0 per cent of GDP in 2009 partly because of rapid rise in private consumption and largely
due to high fiscal deficit.
-
Expenditure on retirement benefits due to an ageing population, tax evasion coupled with steady depletion
of growth promoting expenditure in education, research
and infrastructure has resulted in a bloated public sector
structure in Greece over the years.
-
Debt remains high not only due to annual deficits but
also “deficit-debt” adjustments.1 The frequent initiation
of the ‘Excessive Deficit Procedure (EDP)’2 also raises skepticism about the right size of the fiscal debt. For
example, EDP was initiated in March 2009 whereby debt to GDP ratio was revised upwards to 115.1 per
cent from erstwhile 95.4 per cent in 2008.
-
The weighted average borrowing cost of the Greek government rose from 3.8 per cent in 2006 to 4.4 per cent in 2007 and 4.6 per cent in 2008 and then flared
up to 5.0 per cent in First quarter of April 2010.
Current Account Deficit
-
Due to low domestic saving rate, public debt has to be
financed from foreign sources, resulting in wide current
account deficit and a growing external debt. Thus the
fiscal problem gets intertwined with the external deficit
and debt problem and the twin deficits fed each other
in self fulfilling cycle.
-
This is directly traceable to a large trade deficit, an average 20 per cent between 2001-09, reflection of its
continuously depleting price and product competitiveness in international markets.
-
According to Bank of Greece Annual Report 2008-09,
lower productivity is due to poor penetration of new
technologies in most sub-sectors; low vocational on the
job training and the inefficiency of public administration.
Greece ranks 96th among 181 countries in terms of
World Bank ‘Ease of Doing Business’. It is the last
among OECD countries.
Greece slipped into the path of recession since 2009
as GDP contracted by 2 per cent and unemployment rate
rose to 9.4 per cent. The debt crisis deepened in October
2009 and further in mid April 2010 when it became clear
that budget deficit has blown up to unsustainably high
levels. Assessing the situation, on April 22, 2010, Moody’s
downgraded Greece’s sovereign rating to A3 followed by
Standard & Poor’s which downgraded Greece’s and
Portugal’s long-term debt to BB+ (junk) and A-, respectively
sparking off a marked dip in confidence in global equity
markets. Several Greek banks were also downgraded
subsequently which delimited their access to international
financial markets. The probability of losing access to their
most important refinancing source, European Central Bank
also rose exponentially. The possible loss of the ECB
funding source pushed up CDS premia and yield spreads
in Greek sovereign bonds.
Table 2: Current Account, Government Deficit and Public Debt in the Euro Area |
Country |
CAD/GDP (%) |
GFD/GDP (%) |
Public Debt (% of GDP) |
2000 |
2005 |
2009 |
2000 |
2005 |
2009 |
2000 2005 2009 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
Austria |
-0.7 |
2.0 |
1.4 |
-1.9 |
-1.7 |
-3.6 |
66.5 |
63.9 |
66.5 |
Belgium |
4.0 |
2.6 |
-0.3 |
0.0 |
-2.7 |
-5.8 |
107.9 |
92.1 |
96.7 |
Cyprus |
-5.3 |
-5.9 |
-9.3 |
-2.3 |
-2.4 |
-6.1 |
48.7 |
69.1 |
56.2 |
Finland |
8.1 |
3.6 |
1.4 |
6.8 |
2.6 |
-2.4 |
43.8 |
41.8 |
44.0 |
France |
1.6 |
-0.4 |
-1.5 |
-1.5 |
-3.0 |
-7.9 |
57.3 |
66.4 |
77.6 |
Germany |
-1.7 |
5.1 |
4.8 |
1.3 |
-3.3 |
-3.3 |
59.7 |
68.0 |
73.2 |
Greece |
-7.8 |
-7.5 |
-11.2 |
-3.7 |
-5.1 |
-12.9 |
103.4 |
100.0 |
115.1 |
Ireland |
-0.4 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
4.8 |
1.6 |
-11.4 |
37.8 |
27.6 |
64.0 |
Italy |
-0.5 |
-1.7 |
-3.4 |
-0.9 |
-4.4 |
-5.3 |
109.2 |
105.8 |
115.8 |
Luxembourg |
13.2 |
11.0 |
5.7 |
6.0 |
0.0 |
-1.1 |
6.2 |
6.1 |
14.5 |
Malta |
-12.5 |
-8.8 |
-3.9 |
-6.2 |
-2.9 |
-4.1 |
55.9 |
70.2 |
69.1 |
Netherlands |
1.9 |
7.3 |
5.2 |
2.0 |
-0.3 |
-4.9 |
53.8 |
51.8 |
60.9 |
Portugal |
-10.2 |
-9.5 |
-10.1 |
-3.0 |
-6.1 |
-9.3 |
50.5 |
63.6 |
76.8 |
Slovak Rep. |
-3.5 |
-8.5 |
-3.2 |
-8.7 |
-2.8 |
-6.3 |
50.3 |
34.2 |
35.7 |
Slovenia |
-3.2 |
-1.7 |
-0.3 |
-1.2 |
-1.0 |
-6.1 |
.. |
27.0 |
35.9 |
Spain |
-4.0 |
-7.4 |
-5.1 |
-1.0 |
1.0 |
-11.4 |
59.3 |
43.0 |
53.2 |
Memo |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
United Kingdom |
-2.6 |
-2.6 |
-1.3 |
1.3 |
-3.3 |
-10.9 |
41.0 |
42.2 |
68.1 |
Source: World Economic Outlook Database, IMF. |
1 These are financial transactions of the Government which are not recorded in the deficit, but increase public debt.
2 Excessive Deficit Procedure (EDP) is initiated by the Economic and Financial Council of European Union when a Euro zone country records government deficit in excess of the 3 per cent reference value.
IV. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
2.123 The recent global financial crisis that finally
engulfed almost all economies marked a painful
adjustment of a variety of imbalances at the macro
level coupled with micro-level distortions and
incentives created by past policy actions. The
analysis of the various causes of the crisis has
initiated a whole new debate on the relevance of
various economic tenets and has challenged the
economic doctrine that assumed the self-correcting
mechanism of the markets. At the fulcrum of the
crisis was excessive leverage. This was combined
with inadequate regulation and flawed credit
ratings. The low interest rate regime, which was
the result of accommodative monetary policy, led
to the debt levels acquiring unsustainable
proportions. The global savings glut combined with
aggressive marketing by the housing finance
institutions and under-pricing of risks fuelled the
build-up of sub-prime mortgages.
2.124 Thus, the crisis had its roots in
macroeconomic causes that fed into the functioning
of the financial markets as both investors and the
financial institutions were induced to take excessive
risks in their search for higher yields. Easy credit
combined with under-pricing of risks, both by
households as well as financial intermediaries,
created speculative bubbles in real estate, energy
and other sectors. However, in many cases
domestic macroeconomic policies could not take
into account the build-up of systemic risks in the
financial system or domestic economic imbalances
and asset price bubbles, thereby contributing to the
crisis. This is because many central banks either
focused or were mandated to focus exclusively on
price-stability, through inflation-targeting regimes.
In other cases, although central banks perceived
that there were excessive risks in the system, they
believed that risks were dispersed widely,
especially among those who could afford to bear
them, through the emergence of new intermediaries
like hedge funds and new instruments like
derivatives, and therefore sensed no major risks
to the financial system as a whole, and hence, did
not act appropriately. Regulatory bodies could not anticipate that the rapid innovation in financial
instruments had not resulted in risk mitigation; on
the contrary, it had concentrated and magnified risk.
No public institution had a formal mandate to
maintain financial stability and, hence, such stability
in public policy was neglected. Moreover, the
shadow banking sector remained beyond the
purview of effective regulation. Furthermore,
multilateral institutions like the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) who were charged with the
responsibility of surveillance failed to diagnose or
bring out the vulnerabilities both at the global level
and at the level of systemically important advanced
economies (Reddy, 2009c).
2.125 The final trigger for the crisis came from
the decline in U.S. home prices by mid-2006 and a
gradual rise in the Fed Funds target rate that led to
massive losses and foreclosures in the sub-prime
mortgage market. The consequent crisis in global
financial markets, the extreme level of risk aversion,
the mounting losses of banks and financial
institutions and the sharp correction in a range of
asset prices, led to a sharp slowdown in growth
momentum in the major advanced economies,
especially from the second half of 2008.
Globalisation rendered the international financial
markets vulnerable especially in terms of
syndication of debt and global supply chains,
resulting in rapid transmission of the downturn.
Highly integrated global financial markets were
instrumental in the rapid spread of this turmoil to
other emerging markets and countries.
2.126 The recent crisis has rekindled interest in
the history of financial crises. An analysis of the
history of the global economy reveals that financial
crises are not a recent phenomenon and economic
history is replete with several such episodes.
Several definitions of financial crises have been put
forth, but the common thread is severe stress on
the financial markets/intermediaries. Financial
crises have generally been categorised as a
banking/currency/debt crisis and contagion,
depending upon the underlying causes and the
manifestation of the crisis. These have differed
across a range of features, i.e. , the role of fundamentals, exchange rate regimes and history,
underlying structure and dynamics and the relative
importance of bank/securitised debt or private/
sovereign debt. Financial crises have been a
regular occurrence. However, their incidence has
been highly erratic and has varied depending on
the prevailing macroeconomic conditions,
regulatory regime, financial structure, exchange
rate regime and global capital flows. The causation
of crisis has always been quite complex. There is
no uni-causal theory and, in each crisis, the nature
of the interaction among the underlying causes has
been unique. These have generally been caused
by a combination of unsustainable macroeconomic
policies, balance sheet fragilities, heavy reliance
on leverage, credit booms and asset price bubbles.
Financial crises have generally been followed by
severe economic contractions. Most of the
economic parameters exhibit pro-cyclical behaviour
during the crisis. The macroeconomy has generally
been affected by the financial crisis through several
channels. Increase in risk aversion and
deleveraging results in reduced availability of credit
and investment activity which, in turn, reduces the
aggregate demand and culminates in the downturn
of the economy. The recessions have often been
characterised by sharp declines in investment
activity, industrial output, trade specially imports,
and asset prices, modest declines in consumption
and exports, and aggregate employment.
2.127 There is now a consensus that the recent
crisis is the worst-ever since the Great Depression
of the 1930s in terms of its depth and extent. The
recent crisis might be characterised as an example
of the well-known boom-and-bust pattern that has
been repeated many times in the course of economic
history. Some resemblance can be found between
the recent crisis and past episodes when one
analyses the underlying causes. As in the past, the
main causes of the recent crisis are linked to
systemic fragilities and imbalances that contributed
to the inadequate functioning of the global economy.
Major underlying factors in the recent situation
include inconsistent and insufficiently co-ordinated
macroeconomic policies. These factors were made
acute by major failures in financial regulation, supervision and monitoring of the financial sector,
and inadequate surveillance and early warning.
These regulatory failures, compounded by overreliance
on market self-regulation, overall lack of
transparency, financial integrity and irresponsible
behaviour, led to excessive risk-taking,
unsustainable high asset prices, irresponsible
leveraging and high levels of consumption which
were fuelled by easy credit and inflated asset prices.
2.128 There are, nevertheless, some aspects that
make the recent crisis different from its
predecessors. The recent financial and economic
crisis is different in nature and magnitude from
those experienced earlier. First, the crisis originated
in the US and the preceding boom was fed – at
least to a large part – by the savings in the emerging
market economies. Earlier episodes of global
imbalances were largely confined to advanced
economies in the role of creditor in contrast to the
recent crisis with the US as the debtor nation.
Second, the recent crisis has been more global in
terms of reach; it has rapidly impacted the world
economy as a whole due both to its unusual scale
and to the existence of large diffusion channels
related to globalisation. The global dimension of
the recent crisis is due to increased linkages
between the financial system both within and across
economies which resulted in rapid transmission of
the crisis from the epicentre to the periphery. The
estimates of output loss place the recent crisis
above most of the episodes in the past, with the
majority of the advanced and emerging market
economies facing a ‘globalised synchronised
slowdown’. The recent crisis has been more ‘global’
and more ‘rapid’ when compared with the Great
Depression, yet one cannot deny that the better
initial conditions together with swift policy
responses may succeed in preventing the recent
recessionary phase from turning into a depression
as in the 1930s. The immediate impact of the crisis
on advanced countries and EMEs seems to have
been worse than that of the previous ‘advanced
country crises’ and ‘EMEs crises’. However, a
detailed assessment of the impact of the crisis in
terms of individual economic parameters is critical
to understand the overall nature of the crisis.
1 Even if some central banks perceived that there were excessive risks in the system, they concluded that such risks were dispersed widely
due to the emergence of new intermediaries, like hedge funds, and new instruments, like derivatives, with no impact on the financial
system as a whole.
2 The real interest rate is the US Fed Funds rate less consumer price inflation.
3 From 1997 to 2007, the secondary syndicated loan market has grown from $60 billion to $342 billion in annual trading volume, fueled by
securitisation and the tremendous growth in collateralised debt obligation (CDO) and collateralised loan obligation (CLO) funds.
4 Using the standards of Basel I, Fitch Ratings estimated that, under a worst-case scenario, if liquidity lines were to be fully drawn down,
declines in the Tier 1 capital ratio of European banks would peak at 50 per cent and for U.S. banks at almost 29 per cent (Fitch Ratings, 2007).
5 One needs to mention here the UK hedge fund industry initiative, which launched a working group backed by 14 of the largest UK hedge
funds to develop a set of guidelines for the industry.
6 Incidentally, Isaac Newton who lost heavily in South Sea Bubble is reported to have said that he could calculate the movement of heavenly
bodies but not the madness of the people.
7 The exceptions are Estonia and Finland in early 1990s.
8 Korea is one exception to this where short term external bank liabilities posed some problems leading to large depreciations. |