Click here to Visit the RBI’s new website

BBBPLogo

publications

PDF document (1635 kb)
Date : Jan 29, 2016
Trade Policy and Manufacturing Performance: Exploring the Level of Trade Openness in India’s Organized Manufacturing in the Period 1990-2010

by
Deb Kusum Das1

Contents
Acknowledgements
Executive Summary
1. Introduction
1.1 Objective of the Study
1.2 Sample and Time Period
1.3 Plan of the Study
2. Trade Liberalization and Indian Manufacturing- Review of Literature.
2.1 Quantifying Trade Barriers- A Review
2.2 Trade Liberalization and Manufacturing Dynamics
3. Methodology of the Study:
3.1: Measuring Nominal Tariffs
3.2: Measuring Effective Rate of Protection
3.3: Measuring Non-tariff Barriers
3.4: Measuring Import Penetration Rates
Section 4: Empirical Measures of Trade Liberalization
4.1: Tariff Based Trade Liberalization - Trends and Patterns
4.2 Non-tariff Based Trade Liberalization - Trends and Patterns
4.3 Combined Tariff and Non-tariff Trade Liberalization - Import Penetration Rates
5: Exploring the Link Between Trade Openness and Industrial Performance
5.1 Modeling the Impact of Trade Liberalization on Productivity Growth
5.2 Data Base and Descriptive Statistics
5.3 Methodology for Model Selection and Diagnostics
5.4 Empirical Results
6: Conclusion
Annexure
References
List of Abbreviation

Acknowledgements

My first and foremost gratitude is for the team of young scholars who helped me in the compilation work of trade database by industry groups - Stuti Rawat wanted to learn about databases and did a commendable job of leading the creation of a trade data base by industry by mapping several thousands of tariff lines at six digit ITC (HS) codes for total manufacturing and its sub-groups at NIC 1987 and compiling for the 20 years beginning 1990-91. I can never repay my debts to her for her commitment and tireless hard work till the very last minute when she left to pursue research at National University of Singapore. Several others assisted and worked to take this forward at various stages - Pilu Chandra Das who anchored the database creation after Stuti left. Shyamaditya Singh for compiling the export-import data and creating the non-tariff barriers and Keshav Parthasarathy did a summer intern with me on trade dataset. Words cannot express my gratitude.

Discussions with Gunajit Kalita helped me to derive several patterns of trade policy behavior and to understand the nuances of panel data econometrics and its applications to examining trade openness for Indian manufacturing. I thank Professor K L Krishna for his insights and comments which helped to improve the presentation of the econometric analysis. I owe special gratitude to B N Goldar and Kunal Sen for encouraging me to update and expand the trade database so that new research issues on aspects of trade liberalization can be addressed. Homagni Choudhury assisted in cross checking several aspects of trade policy statements to see if they tally with the way ITC codes have figured in various documents for tariff and non-tariff barriers- customs tariff manual, DGCI&S data of the Government of India. I owe them a deep gratitude. The estimates of total factor productivity used in the study were provided from a study by Pilu Chandra Das. I thank him for allowing me to use this series for my econometric research.

Shri Arunachalaramanan and his colleagues at the RBI for believing that a short study research project on quantifying trade barriers across Indian manufacturing would be a valuable study for India’s apex monetary authorities - the Reserve Bank of India and enabling the funding of this study as a short study research grant. In particular, I would like to thank Dr Ananthaswamy, Balbir Kaur, B M Misra and others for their continued support to the project. I thank participants at RBI for comments received at both work in progress and project ending presentations. These comments have enriched the quality of the final report.

Finally, to push forward further research on a Ph.D dissertation completed at the Delhi School of Economics more than a decade back were many. The inspiration I drew when Kaushik Basu asked me to contribute a chapter on “Trade Barriers in Manufacturing” on Oxford Companion to Indian Economy based on my Ph.D work and to several scholars like Rodrik and Subramanian (2005), Kunal Sen (2009) and Kotwal et al (2011) who cited estimates of trade liberalization based on my trade data base for scholarly articles to document India’s efforts at trade liberalization, egged me to push for some new evidence on “Has protection declined substantially in Indian Manufacturing?”

Deb Kusum Das


Executive Summary

Trade interventions in Indian manufacturing have been of two types: tariff and non-tariff barriers (NTBs). The former remained the most pervasive form of import protection, although NTBs of various forms were often listed as the major constraint. Over the last 40 years, trade barriers in India have fallen to historically low levels, however the role of trade policy reforms in the process of India’s industrial growth and development continues to be widely debated.

This study presents industry-level evidence regarding the connection between trade policy reforms and manufacturing performance. It contributes to the existing literature in several respects. The study documents the level of trade liberalization at the level of individual sectors of manufacturing using explicit measures of trade policy orientation. This is done via computation of nominal and effective rates of protection, frequency and import coverage ratios of non-tariff protection and finally imports penetration ratios to assess the joint lowering of both tariff and non-tariff protection. The analysis centers on examining both trends and pattern of trade policy reforms. The impact of trade openness on manufacturing performance is examined via a panel data econometric modeling of trade-industrial productivity linkage alongside incorporating other policies-industrial and macroeconomic environment. The coverage of the study is the organized manufacturing sector and use-based sectors of organized manufacturing and the period extends from 1990-91 to 2009-10 giving us twenty years of trade liberalization efforts.

The study observes that removal of restrictions in trade - in terms of lowering of tariff barriers and dismantling of import licensing regime has been substantial since 1990-91 but gain in terms of import penetration has not been of the similar order. In particular, trade protection measured by Nominal import tariff as well as Effective rate of protection (ERP) were brought down substantially in 1990s. Non-tariff protection got almost halved by 1992-93 and become less than 10 per cent by the beginning of 2000-01. Two, Capital goods saw faster reduction in ERP as well as NTBs during 1990s compared to intermediate & consumer goods. Three, at the level of organized manufacturing the change in import penetration rates show a near doubling within 20 years from around 9.7 per cent in 1990-91 to around 18 per cent by the end of 2009-10. We have also compared the period of 1990s versus 2000s in order to understand the manner of lowering of tariff as well as non-tariff barriers. We confirm that there was a sharp fall in tariff levels as well as quantitative restrictions in the 1990s as compared to the 2000s. The periods of 2000s were more aimed at simplifying the trade procedures as well as boosting exports.

The examination of the impact of trade openness as captured by various measures of trade policy reforms indicates that a decrease in tariff barrier (captured by effective rate of protection) on industrial productivity is mainly felt with one year lag and the reduction of NTBs captured by import coverage ratio has relatively smaller impact on increase in TFP. The biggest impact of rise in TFP has actually comes from improvement in domestic industrial policy. Therefore, greater internal competitive pressure brought about by reforms in industrial policy acts a spur to productivity growth. We also find a positive impact of increase in capital intensity in capital goods sector and this is mainly driven by substantial lowering of tariff rates on capital goods imports as well relaxing of import controls on machines and equipments since 1991-92. Our quantitative result reinforces not only the role of trade policy reforms but also the literature on roles of industrial as well as trade reforms as complementarities in enhancing manufacturing performance.

Our findings have strong policy implications as we have already seen substantial reduction in levels of trade protection across manufacturing groups. Further, the trade policy changes have also been followed by reforms in industrial policy. However, manufacturing performance still remains far below that of other emerging countries especially China. Therefore, we need to address issues which can further magnify the benefits of trade and industrial policy reforms such as easing of supply constraints- transport bottlenecks, power shortages, erratic supply of energy (water and electricity), labor regulations etc. Appropriate policy actions on these fronts along with further easing of trading environment will make India’s manufactured goods internationally competitive.


Trade Policy and Manufacturing Performance: Exploring the Level of Trade
Openness in India’s Organized Manufacturing in the Period 1990-2010

Deb Kusum Das

1. Introduction

The Trade regimes in India have remained heavily distorted by both tariff and non-tariff barriers (NTBs) for more than four decades and the actual system of trade restrictions have been pervasive and highly complex. Trade policy reform in the 1990s, given its economy wide impacts, was considered as a key component of the reform process initiated in India. Such reforms were conceived to contribute to improved economic performance in the industrial sector as well as the overall economy.2

To better understand the dynamics of the manufacturing sector and its performance in India, it is important to examine the role of trade in Indian industrialization. It is now well known and documented that trade policy based on import substitution was at the core of India’s attempt at industrialization in 1947. After more than four decades of practicing of an inward looking trade policy, reforms in trade policies formed a significant part of this economic liberalization process in India. The 1980s saw changes in the external and the industrial sector in matters pertaining to licensing for scale and technology as well as quantitative restrictions on imports and tariff rates. The 1990s brought about comprehensive trade liberalization encompassing abolition of non-tariff barriers, reduction of peak tariff rates and dispersion along with devaluation of the rupee. However contrasting views have been documented regarding the impact of trade policy regime changes on Indian manufacturing.3

The manufacturing sector in India underwent a transformation from a highly regulated business environment in Nehru-Mahalanobis framework of planned industrialization to a partially de-licensed regime in the late 1980s. With the advent of reforms in 1990s, manufacturing performance registered a decline in early years; growth rate picked up but decelerated in the late 1990. Currently India’s manufacturing share still remains low compared to other developing countries especially China. Two specific points of manufacturing performance are in order - First, manufacturing productivity still remains very low despite reforms aimed at making this sector competitive (Das et al (2014)). Two, employment generation ability of the manufacturing sector has always remained a question mark. Today the issue is not only about “puzzle of jobless growth”. The creation of good jobs in Indian manufacturing is an important challenge (Kapoor 2014). Apart from issues connected to growth and employment aspect, poor performance of manufacturing in India still continues to be plagued by low technological depth due to very low R & D activities, issues of skill development and labor regulations (Manufacturing Plan - Strategies for Accelerating Growth of Manufacturing in India in the 12th Five Year Plan and Beyond, Planning Commission, Government of India).

1.1 Objective of the Study

In the Indian context, there has been extensive research on assessing the levels of protection for the Indian economy. Given the complex nature of trade barriers, most studies have endorsed the adverse impact of protection on the performance of Indian industries.4 Two issues that emerge out of the prevailing studies is that – one, very few studies have attempted to quantify trade barriers by industry using outcomes of trade policy reforms- lowering of tariff and or abolishing of quantitative restriction (QR) [Das (2003) is the only study that have attempted to quantify measures of trade liberalization by select industry groups.5]. Two, though there have been numerous econometric studies trying to assess the impact of trade liberalization on Indian industry most of them use dummy variables as proxy for trade liberalization without using a quantified measure of trade policy by industries.6

Further, India’s attempt at trade liberalization in the 1980s and 1990s resulted in overall changes in the trading regime with substantial lowering of tariffs and near abolition of import control except for a few groups of industries on grounds of health, environment and defense. Further, the trade policies of 1997-98 and 2003-4 attempted to further consolidate the trade liberalizations of 1991-92. The trade regime in India was not only distorted with high tariff rates but there continued to be several exemptions as well as additional charges/surcharges at several points in time which continued to complicate the trading environment despite the lowering of peak rates of customs duty etc. These continued to remain as hurdles in the path of trade liberalization. Further, it is well known by now that both the ad hoc changes in 1980 and the changes in 1990s were mostly limited to tariff lines of intermediate and capital goods, agricultural consumer products and consumer products – durable and non-durables continue to remain with import controls and somewhat higher tariffs in relation to capital and intermediate goods. It was only after 2002-03 we find that substantial changes – tariff as well as NTBs were removed from tariff lines belonging to consumer goods. This is important and hence India’s reforms of its trade regime continued beyond 1990s. This makes it imperative to examine the level of trade liberalization beyond the 1990s into the period of 2000s, 2000-2010 which forms the core of this research.

It is generally believed that industrial de-regulations on manufacturing sector along with changes in trading rules and regulations - tariffs, import controls stimulate competitive behavior amongst firms and in turn enhance industrial performance. As indicated earlier numerous studies have attempted to examine the trade- industrial performance for Indian economy. However a major limitation of many of these studies is that they have used a time dummy variable to capture the effect of reforms, which tends to pick up the effect of other changes taking place in the economy and may not properly show the effect of trade reforms. We attempted to overcome this limitation in using quantified measures of trade policy reforms as explanatory variables in our econometric exercise to discern if trade policy changes do have an impact on industrial performance?

Objective of the Study is two fold

  1. To re-examine India’s efforts at trade liberalization for the 20 year period beginning 1990-91 at the level of manufacturing sector, especially in organized manufacturing. We will examine trends and patterns of lowering tariff as well as non-tariff barriers (QRs) at the total manufacturing as well as use-based sectors of manufacturing- intermediate, capital and consumer goods. To do this end, we compute and estimate - nominal as well as effective rate of protection, proxies for NTBs - frequency ratio as well as import coverage ratio. Finally, to assess the impact of simultaneous lowering of tariffs and non-tariff restrictions, we compute and analyze the patterns of import penetration rates.

  2. An assessment will be made of the impact of these measures on manufacturing performance for the period 1990-2010 through a quantitative framework. In particular, an econometric model based on panel data to explore the impact of trade liberalization on manufacturing indicators for the manufacturing sector in India covering the several phases of trade reforms beyond 1990-91. To assess the impact on manufacturing performance, we use variables that represent trade liberalization along with industrial policy reforms and macroeconomic business environment (including exchange rate uncertainty)7.

Both the above objectives cover all sectors of organized manufacturing as well as the time period 1990-2010. The first objective is accomplished at the level of three digit industrial classifications based on NIC 1987 and the second is based on three digit industrial classification based on NIC 1998. Our reasons for using the two industrial classifications are the following- It is well known that Indian industries faced high levels of customs duties and import controls for almost four decades of inward looking development strategy of the Government of India, however when documenting levels of protection by manufacturing categories, it is very important that we acknowledge the differences in tariff rates when examining on the basis of tariff lines. Tariff lines are available at 6 or 8 digit level of disaggregation and a detailed breakdown of manufacturing groups into sub-groups as deep as three and four digit NIC allows a better documentation and examination of protection levels. NIC 1987 in our opinion has a better spread of sub-groups as compared to NIC 1998 three digit levels and hence the preference for NIC 1987. As regards, quantitative exploration through an econometric study, NIC 1987 cannot be extended further as concordance between the two classifications at three digit level is not comparable. Further, indicators of manufacturing performance like productivity, price-cost margins cannot be constructed further as no extension of NIC 1987 through mapping is possible, thereby forcing us to use NIC 1998 database for constructing our dependent variable (TFP in this case)

1.2 Sample and Time Period

We compute measures of trade policy reforms- nominal and effective rates of protection (NRP and ERP), non-tariff barriers (FR and MCR) and import penetration ratio (MPR) for all sub-groups of organized manufacturing at three- digit NIC 1987. The three digit industries are covered under the following two digit heads as depicted in the annexure. In all, we have covered the entire organized manufacturing sector. Further, we have also made an attempt to document trade policy indicators by use-based sectors of organized manufacturing based on three digit sub-groups.

The period of study extends from 1990-91 to 2009-10 to undertake an analysis of the impact of trade liberalization on manufacturing performance in Indian industry during the period when significant changes took place in the trade and industrial policy framework (trade policy statements of 1991-92) and consolidation of changes took place (trade policy statements of 1997-98 and 2002-03). The significance of the time period lies in the fact that though substantial reforms in trade policy happened in 1991-92, but the 2000s is important as trade policy document of 2003-04 to-2009-10 continues to simplify procedures on customs duties and lessen controls along with measures to boost exports [(Kowalski and Dihel (2009)] which address issues at India’s continued efforts at lowering protection levels in manufacturing.

1.3 Plan of the Study

This study is structured in several sections. In the next section, we provide an overview of the research that has already examined the issues mentioned in the two fold objectives. We also highlight some of the major limitation of those studies so that we are put the present research in a better perspective. The methodology of the study is presented in section 3 and we outline the formulas which are used to compute the four measures of trade policy reforms. In section 4, we quantify the trade liberalization attempted so far in terms of the estimates of levels of trade barriers and outline the trends and patterns. The final section provides a detailed examination of the impact of trade reforms on manufacturing performance for the period 1990-2010. The final section concludes the study and lists avenues for future research.

2. Trade Liberalization and Indian Manufacturing - Review of Literature

It is well understood by now that India’s attempt at trade liberalization was to create a trade regime devoid of import licensing as well as high rate of tariff on one hand and on the other to boost manufactured exports. Several scholarly writings have addressed the issue of trade policy changes in Indian economy (Panagariya (2004), among others). We attempt here to review the literature on trade liberalization and Indian manufacturing in two parts. First, we document the available literature on quantifying trade barriers and second, we examine the studies which have studied the impact of reforms in trade policy on Indian manufacturing.

2.1 Quantifying Trade Barriers - A Review

India has had a very restrictive trade regime since the late 1950s. The major instruments of protection that have been used to regulate import demand have been an extensive import licensing system and high levels of tariffs. The economic costs of India’s trade regime have been a recurring theme in academic research [Bhagwati and Srinivasan (1978), Rao (1985), Pursell (1988)]. Further, the recommendations of official committees [Alexander (1977), Hussain (1984) and Narsimham (1984)] and policy statements have been influential in shaping the Indian thinking on trade liberalization. Starting from the early 1980s, there have been important import policy changes such as expansion of OGL list, shifting of goods from more to less restrictive lists, swifter and less administrative judgments and some reduction in the scope of canalization. In particular, there has been a relaxation of restrictions on capital and intermediate goods import, though primarily of commodities not competing with domestic production. The overall scenario that emerges from the major studies on Indian trade policies is that, the protectionist regime created a large and diversified industrial base and neglected the considerations of costs and comparative advantage, the consequence of which was the inefficient use of resources in Indian industries.

There have been several studies documenting the protection accorded to Indian industry. These can be grouped as: (1) studies exploring the structure of nominal tariffs, (2) studies trying to analyze the level and structure of inter-industry protection and (3) those that attempt to quantify the extent of NTBs in Indian industry. Goldar, Narayana and Hasheem (1992) examine the pattern of tariff, statutory and realized during the 1980s at the level of broad groups and detailed product classes whereas Mehta (1999) documents the tariff rates for the 1990s by different sections and chapters of HS classification. The level and structure of inter-industry protection have been examined using both nominal tariffs and effective rate of protection [World Bank (1989), Aksoy (1991), Aksoy and Ettori (1992), Goldar and Hashim (1992), Gang and Pandey (1998) and Hashim (2001)]. Despite attempts to liberalize India’s import trade regime, the structure of import licensing has remained restrictive and complex. There have however been a few attempts to quantify NTBs according to the manufacturing sectors [Aksoy (1991), Mehta (1997), Pandey (1999), Hashim(2001), Das(2006) and Sen (2007)]. Table 2.1 highlights the studies that addressed a range of issues pertaining to the effects of the protectionist trade regime on industrial performance.

Table 2 1: Synoptic view of Studies of Import Protection in Indian Industries
Study Objective Coverage Measures Main Findings
World Bank (1989) To study the level and structure of protection Manufacturing
Sub-sectors
1986-87
NRP and ERP based on Price Comparison High levels of protection and inability to undertake process and product innovation
Aksoy (1991) To quantify the structure of import licensing regime and analyze the structure of tariffs Input-Output Sectors
1987-88
Nominal Tariff
& Frequency Ratio
Licensing system does not provide any additional protection. Absolute levels of tariffs are high and high tariffs on capital goods
Aksoy and Ettori (1992) To estimate the structure of incentives and protection Three sectors:
Iron & Steel
Petrochemicals
Capital goods
1986-87 to
1988-89
Nominal
Rate of Protection
High magnitude and variance of protection rates.
Goldar and Hashim (1992) To document the protection Input-Output Sectors
1980-81;
1983-84;
1988-89.
NRP & ERP
[ Corden Measure]
Increase in Protection across I-O sectors; input based sectors & trade based sectors between 1980-81 to 1988-89
Mehta (1997) To quantify changes in trade protection Manufacturing sectors
1989-90
1993-94
1995-96
NRP & ERP [Corden’s Method]
& Frequency Ratio
Significant decline in the level of protection; No QRs on more than 55%
Tariff lines.
Gang and Pandey (1998) To study the inter-industry structure of protection Input-Output Sectors
1979-80
1984-85
1991-92
1996-97
NRP & ERP
[Balassa and
Corden
Method]
Level of protection varies according to the notion of tariff rate used.
ERP levels indicate positive protection for 32 manufacturing sectors
Pandey (1999) To document NTB’s in Indian manufacturing Input- Output sectors
1994-95
1996-97
1997-98
Frequency Ratio & Tariff Equivalence
of NTB
Incidence of NTB shows a decline. The tariff equivalence calculated gives an indication of what the tariff rates should be
Mehta (1999) To document Tariff
and Non-Tariff
Barriers in the Indian
Economy
Sections of
and Chapters
of HS classification
1993-94 to
1998-99
Average
Tariff Rate
& Frequency Ratio
Significant decline in average tariff rates, though the dispersion of the tariff rates has not declined. Only 28% of product lines subject to NTB by 98-99
Hashim (2001) To examine the structure of tariffs and NTB’s Input-Output
Sectors
1987-88
1992-93
1994-95
1997-98
NRP and ERP
& Imports by Licensing Category
Steady decline in both NRP and ERP. Level and pattern of protection is dependent on choice of tariff rates.
Source: World Bank (1989), Aksoy (1991), Aksoy and Ettori (1992), Goldar and Hashim (1992), Mehta (1997), Gang and Pandey (1998), Pandey (1999) and Hashim (2001)

Evidence from the studies covering tariff as well as NTBs suggests that there has been a conscious effort to dismantle the import licensing regime via reductions in the number of products listed under banned/ restricted category. The effective tariff structure throughout the 1980s and 1990s has been very complex due to the presence of various exemptions applicable on the basic duty rate. Further, the tariff rates have not only been high but have been covering almost all product categories in intermediate, capital and consumer goods sectors. Efforts have however been made in the 1990s to rationalize the structure of tariffs. Majority of the studies reviewed here have estimated nominal as well as effective rate of protection. Most of the estimates of ERP are either based on tariff data or the collection rate8. One particular study has attempted to use both published and realized tariff data for arriving at ERP estimates. The Corden measure of ERP is used very widely [Goldar and Hasheem (1992b), Gang and Pandey (1998), Mehta (1997), Hashim (2001 and Das (2003)]. The popularity of the Corden’s measure is reflective of the fact that it takes into account both the direct and indirect value added, while the Balassa measure accounts for only the direct value added.9. The extremely high tariffs apart from fulfilling the primary purpose of providing protection were aimed at generating revenue.

In the pre-90 period, India’s policy regime for imports was complex and cumbersome. There were different categories of importers, several types of licenses and alternative ways of importing. This made the quantification of QRs very difficult.10 Majority of the studies computed either the frequency ratio or the import coverage ratio. These have been worked out for the whole -economy as well as manufacturing sub branches. Mehta (1997) and Pandey (1999) compute the NTB indices for the use- based sectors, whereas Aksoy (1991) and Hashim (2001) provided estimates of share of imports according to licensing categories for broad manufacturing sub-sectors. A major limitation of these exercises is that all these studies pertain to select time points. The review of the empirical findings points towards substantial reduction in the NTB levels across manufacturing sectors in the 1990s as compared to 1980s.

We conclude that tariffs and quantitative restrictions have been important instruments of trade policy and played a crucial role in providing protection to domestic industry throughout the 1980s and part of 90s. It is also widely held that the protective regime has been responsible for inefficiency in resource-use, which constrained the growth performance of Indian industries. These studies however did not explore the effect of the protection on industrial growth and efficiency.11

2.2 Trade Liberalization and Manufacturing Dynamics

Several studies have attempted to document trade openness impact on Indian manufacturing sector (Krishna & Mitra (1998), Balakrishnan et al. (2000), (Goldar and Kumari (2003), Topolova (2004), Das (2006), Mitra and Ural (2008), Sivadasan (2006, 2009) Topolova and Khandelwal (2011]. The early generation studies namely- Krishna and Mitra (1998) as well as Bala et al (2000) found a positive impact of trade reforms on manufacturing, but a major limitation of these studies is that it used dummy variables to represent trade policy changes and it may very well have captured other policy changes also. Both studies of Das (2006) and Mitra and Ural (2008) show favorable impact of trade policy reforms on manufacturing – Das (2006) attributes the lowering of NTBs enhances industrial productivity, whereas Mitra and Ural finds tariff cuts as well as lowering of NTBs impacting positively on industrial productivity. Topolova (2004), Topolova and Khandelwal (2011) and Trivedi et al 2011 find significant impact of tariff reduction on productivity growth.

The complementarities between trade and industrial polices is well-known.12 Studies have also examined the impact of other policies on manufacturing performances - Mitra and Ural find that industrial deregulation impacts positively on industrial productivity, more so in cases where the labor market institutions are flexible. There is also evidence that fall in capacity utilization can counterbalance the positive impact of changes in trade policy (Goldar and Kumari (2003). Sivadasan (2006, 2009) find significant impact of FDI liberalization on firm level productivity.

Our review of the studies based on countries from these studies point towards three important issues encompassing the trade-productivity literature. One, what is the appropriate measure of trade liberalization - use of dummy variables or a properly quantified trade policy outcome variable - like nominal tariffs, effective rates of protection, import penetration ratios! Two, whether the impact holds at all levels of disaggregation-firms versus industrial sub-groups? Finally, what is the nature of specification of the relationship between trade liberalization and performance indicator? Our assessment is the following. The review of the trade liberalization indicators confirms that it is not easy to combine different aspects of trade policy with a single measure. Further, in most developing countries, lowering of both tariff and NTB holds the key to successful trade liberalization. Thus, we ought to construct appropriate “measures” of trade orientation reflecting both the above aspects of trade policy changes. The inter-industry studies confirm that the trade-productivity is not specific to the level of disaggregation, as we observe both positive and negative impact at various levels of disaggregation. Finally, many of the studies recognized the role of non-trade policies particularly the possible influences of industrial structure as well as reforms in industrial policies in explaining productivity growth.

3. Methodology of the Study

Trade interventions in developing countries are of two types: tariff and non-tariff barriers.13 The former remains the most pervasive form of import protection, although non- tariff barriers of various forms are common. Import tariffs are simply indirect taxes, which apply on a discriminatory basis, to imports. They may be ad-valorem or specific.14 The range of instruments that qualify as NTB is diverse, with some being fiscal, some quantitative, some involving monitoring and so on. Moreover depending on how one defines NTB, the list could be still longer.15 Findings of Balassa (1982) and Krueger et al. (1981) confirm that the use of NTBs is more pervasive in developing countries than in developed countries. Section 3.1 outlines the method for computing the nominal tariff. The Corden measure of effective rate of protection is discussed in section 3.2. The various measures of NTBs are presented in section 3.3. The final subsection outlines a combined measure of both tariff and non-tariff restrictions-import penetration rates.

3.1: Measuring Nominal Tariffs

In terms of frequency, tariffs remain the most widely used instrument of commercial policy in developing countries. A tariff is an indirect tax; its rate is set by the fiscal authorities and is published in the tariff schedule. There is however practical problems involved in measuring nominal tariff.16 A number of methods have been suggested for measuring the nominal rate of protection. First, the published or statutory tariff-rates (the ex-ante rate). Second, the realized tariff rate, which is the amount of import duty actually collected, divided by the value of imports (collection rate). There are certain advantages to each of these measures, and the choice of a tariff measure depends upon the purpose to which these rates are going to be put. The ex-ante tariff gives an idea about the potential protective structure adopted by the Government policy, whereas the ex-post tariff accounts for all the duty exemptions that the Government allows. The protection afforded by the explicit tariff structure is modified by the presence of factors such as QRs, price controls, smuggling and under invoicing [Goldar and Hasheem (1992)]. Ex-post tariffs allow for the possibility of understating protection due to prohibitive tariffs [Greenway (1988)].

With nominal rates, the difference between domestic and world prices is assumed to result from Government policies that affect domestic prices. If nominal protection is positive, the Government is protecting the domestic industry through tariffs. If nominal protection is negative, the Government is taxing local producers. However, the nominal rates, by not taking account of how protection on intermediate products affects the incentive structure, do not accurately portray the degree of protection.

The present study computes the nominal tariff rates for the three-digit industries (NIC 1987) by mapping tariff codes (HS)17 to the three-digit industries.18 The nominal tariff rate is computed by taking into account both basic customs duty and auxiliary duty.19 The effective nominal tariff rate is calculated after taking into account exemptions on account of both basic customs duty and auxiliary duty.20 The nominal tariff rate is computed as a simple average of the effective nominal tariff rates of the products situated within the particular industry.21 We calculate the nominal tariff rate for the manufacturing sub-groups and three use-based groups. The tariff rates have been derived from the Customs Tariff Working Schedule, Directorate of Publications, Customs and Central Excise, New Delhi.

3.2: Measuring Effective Rate of Protection

Tariff schedules are inadequate guides to nominal protection when quantitative restrictions and not tariffs, are the binding instrument of trade policy22. Further, the nominal protection rate disregards the fact that the degree of protection conferred on an activity will depend not only on the any interventions which affect the price of the final good produced, but also by any interventions which affect the price paid for inputs into the production process. This major shortcoming can be overcome by estimating the effective protection rate23. The concept of effective protection discussed in Meade (1951) has been extensively refined by Johnson (1960) and Corden (1966).

The effective rate of protection (ERP) is the per centage excess of domestic value-added, vis-à-vis world value-added, introduced because of tariff and other trade barriers.

This measures the distortion introduced due to tariff on the input prices as well as the final output prices, and therefore, measures protection to domestic factors of production. The incentive structure of the domestic production process is described by the return to primary factors of production and the measure of protection based on value added is able to capture it.

The forgoing aspect of effective rate of protection is predicated on a number of simplifying assumptions, not all of which concur with reality. Thus it is rare to find a production process where some intermediate inputs are non-traded, tariffs are not often the sole form of protection, and tariff imposition itself may have induced exchange rate effects, which influence the net protection conferred on a given activity. The treatment of non-traded intermediate inputs is important and introduces some complication into the calculation of effective rates. This issue is important because value added has to be determined by extracting the primary factors of production.26 It can be argued that we would expect the price of non-traded inputs to increase with protection because of competition for resources and aggregate expenditure effects. The extent to which their price increases then depends upon elasticities of substitution between non-tradable and tradable, both in supply and demand In the case of QRs, it will have a price raising effect. Further, it is difficult to compute the tariff equivalents of QRs. So long as it can be measured, the effective rate of protection would incorporate all interventions that distort domestic and international prices. Finally, protection may induce exchange rate changes. Thus id one group of industries are given protection, whilst some other group is not (say exporters), we might expect the trade balance to improve. Other things being equal, this should result in exchange rate appreciating, thereby eroding some of the benefits of protection. Some analyst attempt to adjust for induced exchange rate changes. Many of the measurement problems are “study specific.”27

The present study constructs the ERP measure based on Corden’s formula:

where ERP j is the effective rate of protection for the jth activity (product), Tj is the nominal tariff rate of that activity, Tj (i=1,2,.., n) are the nominal tariff rates of tradable intermediate inputs used in the jth activity and aij (i=1,2,…n) are the cost shares of inputs in total value of production of the jth activity. The cost shares are computed after valuing output and tradable inputs at world prices. The data on costs of production are obtained from the input-output tables28. There are two ways of obtaining the free-trade input coefficients. First is to assume that a developed country (like USA, which has low levels of nominal tariffs) input coefficients could approximate the world input-output coefficient. The second is to assume that free trade prices are equal to the protected prices deflated by appropriate tariff rates. This gives the free trade coefficients as

We compute the Corden measure of ERP for the sample industries numbering 72 in all, as well as the use-based classification- consumer goods, intermediate goods and capital goods sectors for the three phases of trade: minor (1980-81 to 1985-86), moderate (1986-87 to 1990-91), major (1991-91 to 1994-95) and the period 1980-81 to 1994-95.

The industry wise ERP’s are calculated by mapping the different tariff codes with the three-digit ASI industries. The detail of the mapping is discussed in Das (2001). The tariff rates for various product categories (items in the tariff working-schedule under BTN or HS codes) have been derived from the Customs Tariff Working Schedule.29 For each product category, the effective rate of duty was arrived at taking into account quantifiable exemptions and was restricted to basic and auxiliary duties. The ERP for a three-digit industry was based on the computed NRP valued at international prices. These ERP estimates are not adjusted for any exchange rate overvaluations, but nonetheless are representative of the sorts of levels and heights of effective protection found in developing countries.

3.3: Measuring Non-Tariff Barriers

Non-tariff barriers (NTBs) dominate the trade regimes of most developing countries.30 NTBs consist of all barriers to trade that are not tariffs. It is even more general than that, since the term is often used to include trade interventions such as export subsidies that serve to stimulate rather than retard trade and therefore, are not barriers to trade at all. It also includes well-known trade distorting policies such as import quotas and voluntary export restraints.31 The measures range from narrowly conceived ones affecting particular products, industries and countries to more general ones that are rooted in national, institutions and policies.32 Thus it may be difficult to devise accurate quantification of many of these NTB measures. Some of the barriers may be formal and are explicitly stated in official and governmental mandates.33 It is important to mention that there is no single useful way of measuring the “size” of an NTB. NTBs require several parameters to characterize them fully. In this connection it is important to know the various characteristics of NTBs, even though that it may be difficult to capture them empirically.34 In order to quantify the particular occurrence of an NTB, it is important to look at the specific details of the implementation of that NTB.35 The specific details encompass direct information, which needs to be converted into useful form that can be understood and compared to other forms of trade interventions. There are however serious disadvantages to this direct approach especially as one is looking for a broad measure of NTBs.36 Even though direct information about NTBs is likely to be very accurate, it does not necessarily provide for a good starting point for a general analysis.

Four different methods can be used for measuring NTBs. These are classified as: (1) frequency-type measures based upon inventory listings of observed NTBs that apply to a particular sector or categories of trade; (2) price-comparison measures calculated in terms of tariff equivalents or price relatives; (3) quantity-impact measures based upon econometric estimates of models of trade flows; and (4) measures of equivalent nominal rates of assistance.37 An issue that arises in common for all of these methods is how to aggregate the measurements once they have been obtained for disaggregated product categories. The own-country imports and own-country production levels are the weights used in the research but they have their quota of drawbacks.38 It is possible to construct a variety of measures that indicate the frequency of occurrence of NTBs. Such measures may be un weighted, or they may be weighted by imports or by production. The former is defined as frequency ratio and the latter as import coverage ratio.

We calculated for purpose of quantifying non-tariff trade barriers, both frequency ratio and import coverage ratio for the 72 three-digit industries and three use-based industry groups for the three phases of the trade reform as well as 1980-9539.

Thus, Frequency Ratio is defined as:

j stands for a particular industry and i represents a product line within that particular industry. Di is a dummy variable, Ni and ΣNi represents the ith and the total number of product lines in the within a particular industry. Each product line (4-digit HS codes) is given either a number 1 or 0 depending whether the product is affected by a NTB or not. We made the following simplifications, items were treated as affected by NTB if they fall under the category: restricted (R). R covers all of the restrictive lists (banned/restricted, limited permissible and canalized) and hence given a weight of 1. The items under OGL were treated as free (F) and consequently given a weight of 0. Though this has obvious limitations, yet one was constrained to making this simplification in order to build a consistent series for the entire period 1990-2010.40

Thus, Di = 1, if the product is listed under R [banned/restricted, limited permissible, canalized].41

= 0, if the product is listed under F [OGL list].

The import coverage ratio is defined as:

Where Di is as usual a dummy variable defined as:

Di = 1, if the product is listed under R [banned/restricted, limited permissible, canalized]

= 0, if the product is listed under F [OGL list].

j stands for a particular industry and i represent a product line within that particular industry. Mi is the value of imports of the i th product category (4digit HS code) which is subject to NTBs (R in our study) and Σ Mi, is the sum of the value of imports of all the product lines within the industry.

The measure has the virtue of simplicity, both in its computation and interpretation, but also has some limitations.42 NTBs can also be gauged in terms of its impact on the domestic price in comparison to some reference price. Price comparisons have provided the basis for much of the general empirical work that has tried to quantify them and not just identify where they occur.43

For computing these measures of NTB according to the three-digit industries, we need the following data: (1) information on the product lines within an industry subject to NTB and (2) import values for product lines. ASI does not provide information on industry according to product lines, thus necessitating a mapping of product lines (4-digit HS codes) to the respective three-digit industries.44 The yearly import-export policy documents, published by the Ministry of Commerce, Government of India were utilized to determine the number of product categories subject to NTB. The import values at four-digit HS codes were obtained from the yearly issues of the Monthly Statistics of Foreign Trade, published by the Directorate General of Commercial Intelligence and Statistics (DGCIS), Ministry of Commerce, Government of India.

The calculation of import coverage ratio over a period of time allows us to quantify the change in NTBs over time by industries. Though coverage ratios are useful indicators of NTBs, they do not actually show the impact in terms of the price advantage domestic producers get nor do they give us any idea of its likely impact on industrial performance. Due to lack of suitable time-series data on domestic and international prices by industry groups, we are unable to compute tariff-equivalent indicator of NTB45

3.4: Measuring Import Penetration Rates

In the trade regime of India, where both QRs and tariffs played a dominant role, it is important to assess the combined impact of changes in both constituents of trade policy. Lowering of tariffs combined with shifting of products from restricted list to OGL should lead to an increase in the imports. The opposite results from a hike in tariffs and reverse shift in quantitative restrictions. We calculate the import penetration rate for three-digit industry as the ratio of industry imports to domestic availability. Domestic availability is defined as production plus imports minus exports. Aggregating the exports and imports of the product lines situated within a particular industry, we arrive at industry exports and imports.

j stands for the industry. Y, M and X represent production, imports and exports. ASI does not provide values of export and import by industry groups for any level of disaggregation. We generate industry wise export and import data by establishing a mapping between trade data (imports and exports) available at product levels and ASI three-digit industries.46 Value of the gross output is used, as information on physical production by industry groups is not available. The yearly data on import and export data is available in the Monthly Statistics of Foreign Trade whereas the production data is proxied by the gross output from ASI.

4: Empirical Measures of Trade Liberalization

The following sections document and analyze the trends in the important indicators of trade liberalization for the three digit manufacturing groups as well as use-based industries covering the entire organized manufacturing of India for the phases of trade reforms as indicated by various trade policy stance of the Government during the period 1990-2010.As an indicator of trade policy measure based on solely on tariff, the nominal tariff and effective rate of protection have been computed. As a proxy for non-tariff based trade policy measure, we document both frequency as well as import coverage ratio for the above mentioned industry groups and time periods. Finally, to assess the joint effects of both tariffs as well as non-tariff protection, we computed the import penetration ratios. To understand the significance of these indicators of trade policy reforms and its impact on manufacturing sector, it is essential to view the progress of the manufacturing sector.

The listing of India in the ranks of emerging nations of the world has been considerably driven by service sector performance as engine of growth. India’s manufacturing sector on the other hand contributes about 16 per cent to the GDP, and India’s share in world manufacturing is only 1.8 per cent. This is in stark contrast to China; where manufacturing contributes 34 per cent to the GDP and is 13.7 per cent of world manufacturing (Manufacturing Plan, Government of India). The trade and industrial policy reforms since 1991-92 were aimed at making Indian manufacturing competitive and thereby boosting manufactured exports. Figure 4.1 documents the manufacturing growth observed from 1991 with focus on the decades of 1990-2000 and 2000-2010. Interestingly we find that against a growth of around 5 per cent per annum in the 1980s, the manufacturing sector is now growing at 8 per cent per annum. The pertinent question to pose here is that how much of this reflects the long term changes in trade policy – first ad hoc in the 1980s and then substantial in 1991-92 economic reforms.

Over the last ten years, India’s merchandise trade increased manifold from US$ 195.1 billion in 2004-05 to US$ 764.6 billion in 2013-14 (Economic Survey 2014-15). The growth in merchandise exports is around 20 per cent and imports around 28 per cent according to the latest economic survey. These numbers reflect the long term impact that have been brought about by changes in the trade policies of 1991-92 and successive trade policy documents that have continued to lower tariffs and reduce the multiple exemptions that encompassed India’s trading regimes. To this end, in Figure 4.2 we document the three measures of trade liberalization- nominal and effective protection rates, NTBs and import penetration rates for the all manufacturing for two points in time 1990-91 and 2009-10. We observe huge downward slides for both the tariff based protection levels (in both cases we find more than 100 per cent declines). In terms of NTBs as captured by frequency and import coverage ratios- we find that only 5 per cent of all manufacturing items are covered by non-tariff based restrictions and given India’s diversified manufacturing base, this shows major liberalization of non-tariff based trade regime. The import penetration though shows an increase from 10 per cent to 15 per cent at the level of all manufacturing, yet the gain here has not been commensurate with the overall lowering of barriers- both tariff and non-tariffs. To conclude, we observe substantial lowering of trade restrictions for manufacturing in India.

To comprehend the extent of these trade liberalization efforts it is necessary to look at the impact in a disaggregated set up. The efforts at trade reforms were sequential- as early as mid- 1980s, Government was making effort in shifting manufacturing products from complicated restricted lists- limited permissible, restricted and banned to open general licensing- where it was freely allowed to be imported with tariff (albeit high tariff rates). After creating this level playing field for domestic entrepreneurs, there was full scale removal of NTBs except for a small restricted list along with lowering of high tariff rates in 1991-92.47 We therefore, need to document the trade liberalization efforts for manufacturing sub-groups, sectors and use-based groups, etc., to gauge who has benefited from the removal of trade restrictions and this is what we have attempted to document in the following sections with each of our three measures of trade liberalization. Section 4.1 documents the trends and patterns of tariff based trade barriers. In section 4.2, we discuss and document the non-tariff based trade barriers and section 4.3, the joint impact of tariff as well as non-tariff restrictions are documented by import penetration rates.

4.1: Tariff Based Trade Liberalization - Trends and Patterns

In this section, we present our estimates of tariff based measures of trade liberalization – both nominal as well as effective rates of protection for total manufacturing, use-based groups and three digit manufacturing sub-groups. The estimates are provided for the following periods of trade reforms- 1990-91 to 1996-97, 1997-98 to 2002-03 and 2003-04 to 2009-10. These phases are connected to the trade policy documents of the Government of India, which showcase India’s trade policy regime with respect to export and import. We observe both variations across sectors as well as over time.

At the level of total manufacturing, we observe sharp declines in both nominal as well as effective rates of protection from around more than 100 per cent to a drop of around 20 per cent for the overall manufacturing sector. Figure 4.3 shows that the levels of trade protections declined sharply since 1991-92 trade reforms. If we look at the entire period 1990-2010, we find that the rate of decline varies between early 1990s and since 1995-96. The tariff reforms in the 1991-92 were directed more towards the capital and intermediate goods sector and these sectors saw sharp declines to low levels from very high tariff rates. The 1997-98 trade policy reforms brought more sectors into the fold of low tariff levels especially lowering of tariffs on consumer goods.

We next document the trends in NRP and ERP in the use-based sectors- capital goods, intermediate goods and consumer goods. As is well known by now, trade policy changes have been substantial beginning 1991-92 economic reforms and this is evident from Figure 4.4. In panel A, we document the NRP levels and in panel B, we provide estimates for ERP. In both panels we find evidence that support each other- both measures of trade liberalization indicate that lowering of protection was much more in the case of capital goods and intermediate goods in relation to consumer goods. Second, the fall in tariff rates were much sharper in the earlier period in comparison to the period after 1996-97. This indicates that after a substantial revamping of the rates of protection, there has been a gradual and steady decline to the prevailing present levels after the mid-1990s. It is also evident from both panels that the tariff levels for consumer goods still remain at a level higher than that of intermediate and capital goods, where the rates seem to steadily merge to very low levels of tariffs.

We also look at the distribution of industries across different levels of tariffs for select time points- 1990-91, 1995-96, 2000-01 and 2009-10 (see Figure 4.5). As already indicated major downward revision in tariff rates across industry sub-groups happened with the trade policy reforms of 1991-92. We find from figure below that in 1990-91 around 80 per cent of industry groups- three digit NIC, had tariff levels of more than 100 per cent. This also holds true in terms of ERP. This documents an extremely skewed distribution of tariff levels for Indian manufacturing in the period prior to policy reforms. Following trade reforms, we find in 1995-96, that the all industries were concentrated within the tariff bands of 20-50 per cent, signaling a major downward revision of tariff rates across most tariff lines. The period of 2000s present an even better picture of trade liberalization across industry groups. In 2000-01, we find the number of industries in the tariff band of 30-40 per cent substantial increase from around 23 per cent of all manufacturing to around 65 per cent of total manufacturing. Further, we take the 20-30 per cent band we find that almost 90 per cent of manufacturing groups have low tariff levels. The fall in tariff rates have been substantial by 2009-10 with majority of the industry groups around the 0-10 per cent tariff levels.

Panel B of Figure 4.5 documents the trends in terms of effective rates of protection. The difference between the two panels is mainly in terms of the spread of industries according to the rates of effective protection. The story however remains the same in terms of sharp declines in levels of protection. Given that the degree of protection conferred on an industry is a function of both output and input price changes brought about by lowering of tariff rates, measure of tariff reduction based on effective rates of protection sums up adequately India’s attempt at tariff liberalization. The final picture that emerges is that from around 82 per cent industries exhibiting ERP levels of more than 100 per cent in 1990-91 to around 80 per cent of industries having ERP levels of less than 20 per cent in 2009-10. We observe that within the category of less than 20 per cent protection, the proportion of industries differ for NRP and ERP and this has implications for trade reforms. This conveys and sums up India’s efforts at not only reducing the complexities of rules and regulations governing tariff rates but also the opening of the economy.

Appendix Tables A1 and A2 shows the NRP and ERP for all manufacturing sub-groups listed under heads of use-based classifications. As can be seen, we observe wide variations across use-based groups as also within sub-sectors of each group. We also observe that there is a pattern of successive decline in tariffs for majority of sectors since the first period (1990-91 to 1996-97). This is evident for both nominal as well as effective rates of protections. The extent of decline across intermediate and capital goods sub-groups is more than that of consumer goods. It has to be kept in mind that most of the consumer goods sector did not experience substantial tariff reforms as in the other two sectors – capital and intermediate for much of 1990s. The trade policies of 1997-98 and 2003-04 however show lowering of tariffs for many of the tariff lines belonging to consumer goods.

ERP estimates across manufacturing sub-groups show that despite the substantial across the board lowering of tariff rates the protection levels were rather high in the first period. It is only from the second period, that we find evidence of systematic decline for most industry groups. There is further consolidation of the decline in the 2000s. In the 2000s, interestingly, we find evidence of an increase in protection levels for some items of manufacturing belonging to consumer goods- food, beverages etc - two digit groups 20, 21 and 22. This is evident across nominal tariff rates as well as ERP levels. In contrast, manufacturing items belonging to intermediate and capital goods have protection levels as low as less than 15 per cent per annum.

Figure 4.6 compares the decades of 1990s with those of 2000s with respect to nominal rate of protection levels of manufacturing sectors. The figure shows that there was a sharp fall in tariff levels in the 1990s especially since the trade policy reforms of 1991-92 as compared to the 2000s. As of 2000-01, there were just four major tariff categories: 35 per cent, 25 per cent, 15 per cent and 5 per cent. The majority of the manufacturing subgroups are in the 3rd quadrant reflecting much steeper falls in 1990s as compared to 2000s. This is because tariff levels dropped from very high levels post 1991-92 reforms as a policy of phased reduction in maximum tariff rate was combined with a reduction in the average level as well as in dispersion of rates. Manufacturing groups like metal products, basic metals, rubber/ plastic products, exhibit steep declines in ERP levels in 1990s.

The figure points to some outliers-consumer products. The extreme restrictiveness of the pre-reform regime can be seen from the fact that in 1990-91, the import-weighted average rate of tariff was around 164 per cent, on consumer goods imports (World Bank 2000a, Annex Table 6.6). Further, pre-reform tariff and NTBs on consumer goods were left in place initially in 1991 and reduced only much later. Therefore, the manufacturing sub-groups like beverages and tobacco show sharper decline in 2000s as compared to 1990s. The case of manufacturing sub group-food products however shows an increase in tariff rates in 2000s reflecting an increase in ERP levels. This could partly be explained by the fact that in 2001, India published a list of 300 sensitive goods. Domestics production of these products were protected by use of high tariff rates or various non-tariff measures which are compatible under the article XX b (protection of human, animal or plant life or health) or article XXI (security or defense reasons).

In conclusion, we find that external sector reforms since 1991 amongst others showed significant reductions in tariff rates and their dispersion. This is captured by lowering of both nominal tariffs (NRP) as well as effective rates of protection (ERP) across all manufacturing sub-groups and use-based sectors. The 2000s allowed further reduction in levels of tariff based protection48 with existing levels of tariff around 10 per cent on an average. The full impact of India’s attempt at trade liberalization can only be inferred after we have examined the lowering of NTBs (quantitative restrictions) in manufacturing in the next section.

4.2 Non-tariff based Trade Liberalization - Trends and Patterns

Non-tariff barriers operating through the import licensing system have long been the principal means of regulating imports and protecting domestic industries.49 The complexity of the import regime makes it very difficult to quantify the impact and significance of the QR.50 We quantify the extent of NTBs by three-digit industries for the period 1990-91 to 2009-10 using the following measures- frequency ratio and import coverage ratio.51 The first attempt at removal of NTBs in Indian manufacturing started in the late 1970s with commissioning of a report by Abid Hussain (1984) to study the existing trade regimes in manufacturing and to shift away from physical controls. Against the backdrop of this development, the second attempt at removal of NTBs started in mid-1980s with the shifting of tariff lines belonging to capital and intermediate goods to the OGL and finally, in 1991-92 trade reforms, India did away with all kinds of quantitative barriers except for categories deemed essential on health, defense and environment grounds.

As with tariff based levels of trade protection, the estimates are provided for the following periods of trade reforms- 1990-91 to 1996-97, 1997-98 to 2002-03 and 2003-04 to 2009-10. These phases are connected to the trade policy documents of the Government of India, which showcase India’s trade policy regime with respect to export and import. We observe both variations across sectors as well as over time.

At the all manufacturing level, we find from Figure 4.7 that both Frequency Ratio (FR) and Import Coverage Ratio (MCR) show a sharp fall in 1991-92.The pre-reform share of 90 per cent has been significantly reduced to 36 per cent by 1996 and declines to less than 10 per cent by the beginning of 2000-01. Das (2003) provides trends in NTBs for the period of 1980s for select sectors of manufacturing and it is evident that nearly 100 per cent of tariff lines across the select manufacturing sub-groups were under import restrictions of one category or other- limited permissible, restricted and banned and post 1991-92 reforms, substantial decline in the number of items subject to import restrictions have occurred.

It is evident from the above figure showing the sharp rate of decline in levels of NTBs even beyond 1991-92 reforms. This was addressed in the trade policies of 1997-98 and 2002-03 which lifted the prevailing QRs for many tariff lines belonging to items of consumer good leading to even further lowering of non-tariff protection for the manufacturing sector.

We next look at the trends for the use-based sectors of manufacturing. As is evident from Figure 4.8 both FR and MCR show steeper declines for intermediate and capital goods in comparison to consumer goods. The 1992-92 reforms majorly addressed easing of non-tariff restrictions for intermediate and capital goods (refer to 1991-92 trade policy reforms). Whereas a beginning was made in mid 1980s in terms of piecemeal shifts of items to OGL, the 1991-92 policy advocated complete withdrawals of all NTBs except a few prior notified categories and consumer goods. As a result, it is evident from the figure that post 1991-92 there as a divergence between the lowering of QRs for capital/intermediate goods and consumer goods as for much of the 1990s, there was still substantial import restrictions (non-tariff barriers) for consumer goods. It was only after 2002-03 there all three use-based sectors have converged to low levels of FR and MCR.

The distribution of industries across different levels of NTBs (both FR and MCR) is highlighted in the Figure 4.9 below. In the upper panel, we cover the frequency ratio and in the bottom panel, import coverage ratio is documented. Observing four different time points-1990-91, 1995-96, 2000-01 and 2009-10, we find that 65 per cent of industries had FR>80 per cent in 1990-91 and by 2009-10 96 per cent of industries had FR<10 per cent (In terms of MCR - 75 per cent of industries had MCR>80 per cent in 1990-91, by 2009-10 83 per cent of industries had MCR<10 per cent). It is interesting to point that though sharp lowering of NTBs has been in place since the 1991-92 reforms, yet at the level of industry groups, we still find that still 50 per cent of manufacturing subgroups have trade protection based on non-tariff levels (based on MCR) of greater than 50 per cent. In 2000-01 however we observe 40 per cent of manufacturing in the 0-10 per cent import restriction levels (see bottom panel). We infer that most of manufacturing subgroups by the end of 2009-10 fall in the lowest slab (0-10 per cent) NTB, however for much of 1990s and early 2000s this groups was essentially from capital and intermediate groups as evident from Appendix Tables A3 and A4.

Appendix Tables A3 and A4 quantifies the non-tariff barriers (FR and MCR) by manufacturing sub-groups. As is evident from tariff based protection, there are wide variations across the subgroups even for non-tariff protection. Both FR and MCR indicates that non-tariff protection levels fell sharply for manufacturing subgroups within 30,31,33,34, 35, 36 and 37 as indicated in 1991-92 trade policy and continued to decline in 1990s and by 2009-10 reached the level of near zero. The lowering of QRs for sub-groups in textiles (23, 24 25 26), wood (27), paper (28), cement etc (32) came much later in the period 1997-2002. Further some consumer goods- food, beverages and tobacco (20, 21, and 22) still had around 50 per cent of items under restrictions and it is only after 2002-03 we find lowering of NTBs. Our examination of manufacturing subgroups reveals that the case of dismantling of QRs has happened in a phased manner for many manufacturing sub-groups excluding capital and intermediate groups since 1991-92

We now examine the period of 1990s versus 2000s in order to understand the manner of lowering of NTBs. It is clearly evident from Figure 4.10 that major manufacturing sub-groups like- machinery & equipment, transport equipments, metals experienced massive lowering of QRS in the 1991-92 reforms to almost negligible proportions. Further, it is interesting to observe the extent of decline across major manufacturing sub-sectors. The placing of the some of the capital goods sub-groups shows that lowering of barriers have already started before the 1991-92 reforms as evident from 1985-86 trade policy statement. It can also be seen that some of the labor intensive groups like textiles and food products have declined more in the 2000s as compared to 1990s, the reasons for which have been spelt out earlier.

We conclude that it is evident that the trading regime with respect to QRs began to be administered more liberally in the 1980s, but granting of licenses remained discretionary. The first phase of dismantling QRs occurred in the first two years of the 1991-92 reforms when import licensing was virtually abolished for imports of industrial raw materials, intermediates, components, and capital goods and this is reflected in our estimates of both FR and MCR for use-based sectors- capital and intermediate. Our estimates also indicate the vast tariff lines catering to industrial consumer goods remained subject to import controls.52 Continuing with a near infinite protection for consumer goods for much of 1990s, while liberalizing other imports has been widely criticized as illogical because it distorted resource allocation in favor of highly protected consumer goods industries and away from basic and capital goods industries which are otherwise thought to be 'strategically' important (Ahluwalia M 2000)

4.3 Combined Tariff & Non-tariff Trade Liberalization - Import Penetration Rates

The import-export policy announced in April 1985 incorporating the recommendations of the Abid Hussein Committee on trade policy reforms (1984) favored a greater role for tariffs in regulating imports. Simultaneously in 1980s there were changes taking place in the import-licensing regime necessitating the shifting of products from one category of licenses to another. The trade liberalization attempt initiated with the announcement of the trade policy changes in 1991-92 aimed at creating a globally competitive environment via reducing the degree of licensing and regulatory controls on foreign trade. A major focus of the new trade regime related to lowering the structure of import duties and quantitative restrictions on imports.53 The lowering of tariffs and abolition of import controls are intended to bring about competition via imports in the manufacturing sectors. We document the import penetration rates (MPR) for the manufacturing and its sub-groups54 for the period 1990-91 to 2009-10 in order to assess the joint impact of reductions in both tariff and NTBs on the manufacturing sector.

Figure 4.11 documents the MPR for total manufacturing as well as use-based sectors of manufacturing for the period 1990-91 to 2009-10. At the level of total manufacturing the change in MPR has been from 9.7 per cent in 1990-91 to around 18 per cent by the end of 2009-10, a near doubling within 20 years. Capital goods achieved the highest level of import penetration followed by intermediate and consumer goods in the period 1990-2010. Further, across all the three sectors, the increase has been consistent in the upward direction since the 2000s.

We next look in Figure 4.12 at the distribution of industries across different levels of MPR.55 We look at four time points which represents different phases of trade liberalization- 1990-91 is the era of piecemeal attempt at trade reforms, 1995-96 and 2000-01 is the consolidation of 1991-92 trade policy reforms, 2009-10 reflects the end point reflecting twenty years of trade reforms.56 The overall inter temporal pattern of change in import penetration ratios observed in the figure seems to hold across all sectors of manufacturing. We however conclude that 67 per cent of industries had MPR less than 10 per cent in 1990-91, by 2009-10 it has come down to 42 per cent thereby indicating that a large number of industries are now concentrated outside the lowest slab of MPR. However it remains to be examined which manufacturing subgroups are showing higher levels of import penetration.

We list the levels of import penetration ratios by manufacturing sub-groups. Appendix Table A5 lists the various manufacturing sub-groups for the three phases of trade liberalization addressed in this report- 1990-96, 1997-2002 and 2003-2010. As is the case with other measures of trade liberalization- tariff and non-tariff, we find that extent of import penetration is higher in capital and intermediate goods manufacturing sub-groups- metal products (33), non-metal products (34), machinery and equipments (35), electrical machinery (36) and transport equipments (37) all show a high ratio of imports to domestic production. This has shown considerable improvements since period 1990-96. However there still remains manufacturing sub-groups which even in period 2003-10 show low levels of import penetration-Food, beverages and tobacco (20-22), spinning of cotton, wool, manmade and jute textile (235, 242, 247, 254), consumer goods (blankets, shawls, carpets), labor intensive categories like (wood, cane bamboo products, leather footwear), The organic and inorganic chemicals have shown a rise in import penetration from 22 per cent to around 50 per cent in the third period. Most of these manufacturing groups have seen substantial reduction in tariff rates as well as removal of import restrictions.

Next we do a scatter plot (see Figure 4.13) to examine if there is a link between reduction of tariffs as well as NTBs and rise in import penetration rates. The two scatter diagrams show the relationship between fall in tariff level/ fall in non-tariff levels to changes in import penetration ratio. In the upper panel, as expected we see a positive relationship between falling nominal rate of protection and increase in import penetration ratio. When we compare falling nominal rate of protection across 2-digit NIC87 industries, we can see metal products(34) has observed highest fall in tariff level since 1990-91 which resulted maximum increase in import penetration. But textile sector in spite of experiencing fall in tariff level, import penetration did not improve in the last two decades. We have also tried to capture the level of NTBs across these 2 digit industries using the size of the bubbles, which signifies fall in import coverage ratio since 1990-91. For example: even though leather industries experienced similar level of fall in tariff level since 1990-91 compared to metal products, but fall in NTBs (as represented by the size of the bubble) was much smaller compared to metal products which may explains its relative poor performance in import coverage compared to latter. Similarly in the lower panel, we address the same issue with respect to fall in non-tariff levels (proxied by FR) and rise in import penetration ratio. We have also tried to capture the level of tariff barriers across these 2 digit industries using the size of the bubbles, which signifies fall in nominal rate of protection since 1990-91. The cases of metal products vis a vis transport industries reveal the relatively higher fall in NRP and hence the size of the bubble.

Given that tariffs were reduced and NTBs were eliminated under the reforms, we would expect to see a rise in import penetration across manufacturing sub-sectors of Indian manufacturing. For the empirical analysis, we have used information on both tariff and NTBs by manufacturing groups to assess the impact on import penetration rates (MPR). Our estimates show that for total manufacturing, there has been a substantial rise in levels of MPR from 1990-91 and capital goods manufacturing achieved the highest level of import penetration by 2009-10.

In conclusion, we state that by end of the first decade of the 2000s, most industries faced very little protection, in contrast to the high rates of protection accorded to the manufacturing sector till the 1991 reforms. One important aspect of trade policy reforms in India to keep in mind is the pace of the reforms differed significantly across capital goods, intermediate goods and consumer goods. The reduction in protection was much more drastic and faster for capital and intermediate goods. In contrast, the consumer goods sector remained protected for much of the 1990s. Our measures of trade liberalization presented in this section bear testimony to this. In particular, trade protection measured by nominal import tariff as well as effective rate of protection were brought down substantially in 1990s. Non-tariff protection got almost halved by 1992-93 and become less than 10 per cent by the beginning of 2000-01.Two, Capital goods saw faster reduction in ERP as well as NTB during 1990s compared to intermediate & consumer goods. Three, at the level of total manufacturing the change in import penetration rates show a near doubling within 20 years from around 9.7 per cent in 1990-91 to around 18 per cent by the end of 2009-10. We have also compared the period of 1990s versus 2000s in order to understand the manner of lowering of tariff as well as NTBs. We confirm that there was a sharp fall in tariff levels as well as quantitative restrictions in the 1990s as compared to the 2000s57. The periods of 2000s were more aimed at simplifying the trade procedures as well as boosting exports.

5: Exploring the Link between Trade Openness and Industrial Performance

An important issue for developing countries is the link between trade policy regime and industrialization. The role of unilateral trade liberalization in the process of industrial growth in developing countries however continues to be widely debated. Exposure to international competition forces domestic producers to raise their productivity performance to international levels and the expansion of market size beyond the national borders through exports allows scale economies to be realized. The proponents of import substitution based their policies partially on infant industry protection and rapid growth in productivity was expected when industrial skills along with modern technology were mastered. There have been many attempts to investigate the possible links between trade policy and productivity growth [See Pack (1988), Havrlyshyn (1990) and Tybout (1992)]. The first major NBER project conducted by Bhagwati and Krueger in the 1970s failed to find any firm support for the hypothesis that trade liberalization stimulates productivity growth. However, there are a number of studies that correlate aspects of policy regimes with measured changes in total factor productivity at the industry level. Helleiner (1994)58 presents empirical evidence for selected countries covering the period of 1980s and observes that the relationship between TFP growth and trade regime is by and large inconclusive. In the macro economically turbulent 1970s and 1980s, trade policy did not generally play a major role in the growth and development experiences of the selected countries. External-shocks, debt crises necessitated macroeconomic policy responses that dominated other determinants of industrial and overall economic performance. Industrial productivity growth was typically associated strongly with output growth; its relationship with the trade policy regime or the trade orientation of the individual industries was unclear. Thus the empirical verification of the impact of trade liberalization on industrial productivity growth is far from resolved. This study seeks to address this problem in the Indian context.

5.1 Modeling the Impact of Trade Liberalization on Productivity Growth

Static and dynamic effects of trade policy changes are conceptually distinct in that the latter involve a time dimension. However, all responses to policy take time, even those that can be analytically described with a static model. Trade Liberalization brings about competition within the industries, however response of firms often depends on entry/exit barriers, scale economies and form of protection- tariffrΔ versus quotarΔ. The standard argument is that foreign competition drives inefficient domestic producers to exploit scale-economies, eliminates waste, adopt best practice technologies or shut down.59 Further, given the short time-periods spanned by micro-data, it is rarely possible to distinguish transitory one-shot adjustments in productivity levels from lasting changes in the rate of productivity growth60. Recently endogenous growth- trade theorists have formulated a range of models, in which trade contributes to productivity growth via increasing the quantity and variety of intermediate inputs, diffusion of technology, amplifying learning by doing and increasing the market size61. One route that has attracted attention is whether trade protection induces technologically backward industries to catch-up.62 In this connection, technology diffusion constitutes an important channel for capturing the dynamic effect of trade liberalization on productivity growth. There can be several routes for diffusion: trade, foreign direct investment and learning by doing.63 We wish to analyze the impact of trade liberalization on the productivity growth of organized manufacturing (TFPG). Further, it is important that the model specification incorporates the industrial policy reforms and macroeconomic environment as these often supplement trade reform.64 Thus we specify TFPG as a function of a combination of factors representing trade policy changes, industrial policy reforms and macro environment.65 That is,

TFPG = f (Changes in Trade Policy, Changes in Industrial Policy and Macroeconomic Environment)

The variables representing trade policy orientation are; effective rate of protection (ERP), import coverage ratio (MCR) and export growth (EG). The advocates of a neutral trade regime expect greater improvements in TFP when an outward oriented trade policy is followed than when import substituting trade restrictions are in operation. Two major studies, Weiss (1992) and Iscan (1998) found evidence for a lagged impact of trade liberalization on TFP growth. We allow for lagged impact of variables measuring the trade policy changes.66 To reflect the outcomes of industrial policy reforms, we include two variables, namely; the price–cost margins (PCM)67, and capital intensity (K/L)68. Output growth (OG) reflects the effects of scale with an expected significant positive relationship with TFP growth. The macroeconomic uncertainty is proxied by the level of inflation uncertainty (INFLu)69. We thus arrive at a more concrete specification:

5.2 Data Base and Descriptive Statistics

The data set consists of a balanced panel of 43 three-digit industries (in NIC98) for 20 years (1990-91 to 2009-10). We also undertake separate analysis of panels of capital, intermediate and consumer goods industries. Table 5.1 gives the basic statistical characteristics of dependent and explanatory variables:

We use productivity growth as a measure of manufacturing performance. Several studies have attempted to analyze the productivity performance of organized manufacturing in India during the pre and post reforms period- 1980s and 1990s. Majority of the studies observe that reforms have not enhanced productivity performances.70 For the present study, we compute TFP growth for 43 manufacturing groups in the organized sector and also use-based sectors- capital, intermediate and consumer goods. The TFP estimates are computed using a growth accounting methodology based on KLEMS production as the underlying production framework.71 Our estimates show modest TFP growth of one per cent for the period 1990-91-2009-10 for aggregate manufacturing. From appendix table A8, it can be seen that only a small subset of manufacturing groups- mostly machinery and equipments, electronic items belonging to capital goods industries and wood products score high on TFP growth, whereas in majority of sectors, either we see a negligible improvement in TFP or no growth at all. Figure 5.1 below shows the yearly movement of the use-based and aggregate manufacturing. As is evident from table A8, sectors belonging to capital goods sector show higher TFP growth since 1991-92. This is may be attributed to far reaching changes in trade policy towards capital equipments and import of technology embodied in new and better machines and equipment. Intermediate goods and consumer goods productivity improvements lag behind capital goods, however it may be pointed out that only towards the end of 1990s especially 1997-2002 trade policy rules and regulations allowed lifting of import restrictions along with lowering of tariff rates for consumer goods.

Annexure A9 show the TFP performance of the entire manufacturing sub-groups and results do not reflect substantial improvement even for all manufacturing sub-groups. The TFP growth still remains modest at slightly over 1 per cent. We also compare our estimates for organized manufacturing with India KLEMS manufacturing sub-groups72 and find our estimates to follow closely that of India KLEMS all manufacturing, which is inclusive of informal manufacturing also. It is evident from our comparison that when it comes to all manufacturing, though informal sector absorbs more than 80 per cent of employment, on grounds of productivity it still remains weak and much of the aggregate manufacturing TFP performance is led by organized manufacturing.

Table 5.1: Summary Statistics of Dependent and Explanatory Variables - 1990-91 to 2009-10
  Number of Observations Mean Standard
Deviation
Minimum Maximum
Dependent variable: Total Factor Productivity(TFP): 1990-91=100
All Industries 860 114.9 52.5 39.3 613.1
Consumer goods 420 107.1 26.4 50.8 233.5
Intermediate goods 220 98.1 22.7 39.3 152.7
Capital goods 220 146.6 86.9 80.8 613.1
Independent variables: Trade policy measures for all industries
ERP (%) 860 49.3 45.9 0.3 342.2
MCR (%) 860 25.5 34.5 0.0 100.0
Exports (INR crore) 860 664422.3 1242560.0 0.0 13300000.0
Independent variable: Industry Policy reform73
PCM (%) 860 15.1 5.7 1.6 39.8
KL (ratio) 860 11.1 17.4 0.3 157.5
Independent variable: Macroeconomic uncertainty
INFLu (%) 860 5.18 4.95 0.00 63.16
Independent variables: Scale
Output (INR crore) 860 4012492.0 6187105.0 13023.3 55000000.0
Source: Author’s computations based on DGIS database, Custom Tariff Schedules, Input-Output Tables, Government of India, Das (2012), and Annual survey of Industries

We transform the each series across all the industries into their natural logarithmic form before being put into use for our model. Logarithmically transforming variables in a regression model is a very common way to handle situation where a non-linear relationship exists between the independent and dependent variables. Logarithmic transformations are also a convenient means of transforming a highly skewed variable into one that is more approximately normal as well as handle data base which come with different units. The idea behind in our current model structure is to achieve the flexibility of handling both level and growth variable together. The choice of level vs difference of level (in this case difference of natural logarithmic variable would be the growth of that variable) would be taken based on the underlying time series characteristics of our variables and diagnostic steps undertaken on the panel structure (details in subsequent section).

5.3 Methodology for Model Selection and Diagnostics

Based on the availability of data across 43 industries in 3 Digit NIC 1998 classification from 1990-91 to 2009-10, the current study uses a cross sectional-time series panel structure to capture impact of trade policy changes on productivity (TFP) growth. The exact specification of the panel model structure is based on the statistical characteristics of underline data.

The selection of panel model specification depends on the results of following diagnostic steps as highlighted in the Figure 5.2 below:

Cross-sectional Dependence: A growing body of the panel-data literature concludes that panel-data models are likely to exhibit substantial cross-sectional dependence in the errors, which may arise because of the presence of common shocks and unobserved components that ultimately become part of the error term, spatial dependence, and idiosyncratic pairwise dependence in the disturbances with no particular pattern of common components or spatial dependence (De Hoyos, R., and V. Sarafidis, 2006). Based on the nature of our dataset where we are trying to understand the impact of trade policy liberalization on TFP growth; the presence of cross-sectional dependence cannot be ruled out. This is more so when trade policy reforms were introduced after 1991 and followed a gradual process during 1990s impacting across all manufacturing sectors. Moreover, if the unobserved components that create interdependencies across cross sections are correlated with the included regressors, the traditional FE and RE estimators will be biased and inconsistent.

Testing cross-sectional dependence when T>N, where T is the time dimension of the data and N is number of cross-sectional units, one may use for these purposes the Lagrange multiplier (LM) test, developed by Breusch and Pagan (1980). On the other hand, when T < N, the LM test statistic enjoys no desirable statistical properties in that it exhibits substantial size distortions. We have used Pesaran’s (2004) cross-sectional dependence (CD) test designed to test for cross-sectional dependence in large-N, small-T panels. Pesaran’s CD test was applied to our standard74 RE and FE panel model with Ho: Cross-sectional independence.

Pesaran (2004) has proposed the following CD statistics:


Table 5. 2: Cross-sectional Dependence Tests
Test applied to: Pesaran’s CD statistics p-Value Average absolute value of the off-diagonal elements
Random Effect (RE) Model 5.478 0.000 0.409
Fixed Effect (FE) Model 5.167 0.000 0.411
Source: Author’s computations

As we can see, the CD test strongly rejects the null hypothesis of no cross-sectional dependence.

Panel Unit Root: The econometric theory for panel data was largely developed for survey data where T, the number of time-series observations, was small but N the number of groups or individuals was large. But use of macro panel structure like in our current model can have problem of unit roots on the time-series components. Time-series data tend to be non-stationary, determining the order of integration or cointegration of the variables becomes important. The order of integration is the number of times a time-series must be differenced to make it stationary. Many economic time-series appear to be integrated of order one, I(1), needing to be differenced once to make them stationary. Further, Cross-section dependence can pose serious problems for testing the null hypothesis that all units in a panel are nonstationary.

We have used Fisher-type (Choi 2001) tests for panel unit root test for all the concerned variables. Following Levin, A. et al. (2002), impact of cross sectional dependence can be mitigated under Fisher-type test by subtracting the cross-sectional averages from the series. We use Phillips-Perron unit-root test to perform unit-root tests on each panel; denote the p-value for the respective test on the ith panel as pi, then

The Ho: All Panels contains unit roots. Table 5.3 shows results of the Panel unit root test:

Table 5.3: Panel Unit Root Tests
  Inverse chi-squared Modified inv. chi-squared
Natural log: P Statistics p-Value Pm Statistics p-Value
TFP 118.8 0.011 2.5 0.006
ERP 146.3 0.000 4.6 0.000
MCR 190.5 0.000 7.9 0.000
PCM 319.7 0.000 17.8 0.000
KL 199.3 0.000 8.6 0.000
INFLu 205.2 0.000 9.0 0.000
Export 135.1 0.000 3.7 0.000
Output 146.5 0.000 4.6 0.000
Note: AR Parameter: Panel specific, Panel means: included, Time trend: Not included
Source: Author’s computations

The panel unit root test shows that controlling for cross-sectional dependence; the natural logarithmic level variables are panel stationary. This allows using levels of the natural logarithmic transformation of the variable in our panel structure.


Table 5.4: Serial Correlation Test Wooldridge Test for Autocorrelation in Panel Data
  F-Statistics Prob>F
Ho: no first-order autocorrelation 85.889 0.0000

Linear regression in first-difference Pooled OLS: Dependent variable: ΔlnTFP

Δln Coefficient Robust Standard Error t-statistic P>|t|
ERP -0.0131 0.0077 -1.700 0.0970
MCR 0.0017 0.0024 0.720 0.4750
KL -0.0537 0.0171 -3.140 0.0030
PCM 0.1163 0.0109 10.660 0.0000
INFLu -0.0449 0.0059 -7.550 0.0000
Export 0.0026 0.0078 0.330 0.7440
Output 0.0700 0.0139 5.030 0.0000
Note: Std. Err. Adjusted for 43 clusters
Source: Author’s computation

The null hypothesis of no serial correlation is strongly rejected. Also, the output from the first-differenced regression includes standard errors that account for clustering within the panels. If there is serial correlation in the idiosyncratic error term, clustering at the panel level will produce consistent estimates of the standard errors.

Heteroskedasticity: Both the error component models (fixed effects and random effects) assume that the regression disturbances are homoskedastic with the same variances across time and industries. This may be a restrictive assumption when the cross-sectional units, three-digit level manufacturing industries, in this case, are of varying size and as a result may have unequal disturbance variances. The error process may be homoskedastic within cross-sectional units, but its variance may differ across units: a condition known as group-wise heteroskedasticity. Assuming homoskedastic disturbances when heteroskedasticity is present will still result in consistent estimates of the regression coefficients, but these estimates will not be efficient. Also the standard errors of these estimates will be biased. Correction of the standard errors for the possible presence of heteroskedasticity is desirable.76

A modified Wald statistic for group-wise heteroskedasticity in the residuals of a fixed-effect regression model77 was calculated, following Greene (2000). The null hypothesis specifies that σi2= σ2 for i = 1 to N, where N is the number of cross-sectional units.

We can also undertake Likelihood-ratio (LR) test for panel-level (or group-wise) Heteroscedasticity using iterated generalized least square (GLS) method. Since iterated GLS with only Heteroscedasticity produces maximum-likelihood parameter estimates, we can easily do an LR test. We can achieve this by fitting two separate models with and without panel-level Heteroscedasticity and save the likelihoods. The result of LR test on iterated GLS model applied on our standard structure used across all the diagnostic tests. Table 5.5 presents the results of the Modified Wald Statistics and the LR tests

Table 5.5: Heteroscedasticity Test
Modified Wald test for group-wise Heteroscedasticity in fixed effect regression model
  Modified Wald-Statistics
(chi2)
Prob> chi2
H0: σi2= σ2 for i = 1 to N 5717.89 0.0000
Likelihood Ratio (LR) test after iterated GLS with heteroskedastic panels
  LR chi2 Prob> chi2
LR Test (Homoskedastic nested in heteroskedastic panels) 1001.43 0.0000
Source: Author’s computations

The two tests clearly confirm the presence of panel-level Heteroscedasticity in our panel structure. Thus from above diagnostic tests conducted on our panel structure indicate that traditional fixed or random effect panel model is not applicable to our data. The feasible generalized least square (FGLS) structure in the family of panel data model allows estimation in the presence of AR(1) autocorrelation within panels and cross-sectional correlation and Heteroscedasticity across panels. But FGLS approach must estimate additional variance and covariance parameters in the presence of Heteroscedasticity and contemporaneous correlation at panel level. There must be sufficient degrees of freedom for these estimates, or the covariance matrix will be singular. This means that the panel structure must have at least as many time periods as there are cross-sectional units in the dataset, T>=N.

The way around to this problem would be to use model structure of linear regression with panel-corrected standard errors (PCSE). It is an alternative to FGLS for fitting linear cross-sectional time-series models when the disturbances are not assumed to be independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.). It calculates panel-corrected standard error (PCSE) estimates for linear cross-sectional time series models where the parameters are estimated by either OLS or Prais–Winsten regression. When computing the standard errors and the variance–covariance estimates, it assumes that the disturbances are, by default, heteroskedastic and contemporaneously correlated across panels. The disturbances may also be assumed to be auto correlated within panel, and the autocorrelation parameter may be constant across panels or different for each panel. It produces OLS estimates of the parameters in the absence of serial autocorrelation, or Prais–Winsten estimates when we observe autocorrelation within panel.

5.4 Empirical Results

The current panel structure of 43 NIC98 3 digit industries across 20 years (1990-91 to 2009-10), characterized by panel Heteroscedasticity, panel autocorrelation, and contemporaneous correlation (HPAC) imposes restriction of using linear regression with panel-corrected standard errors (PCSE). One very import point to be noted in HPAC structure is that estimates cannot give a unique value of R-square. The concept of explained variance in HPAC structure does not exist because the data are not independent and identically distributed. The disturbance variance is not well defined and it varies from one observation to another, so there is no single number to quantify the same.

Based on the model specification, the standard model framework for our empirical test of impact of trade policy reform on productivity changes are:

Where i represents industry and t stands for year, ξ it is the error term which is not independent and identically distributed. We will also introduce, industry fixed effect and time dummies for phases of reform. We include a period dummy D defined in terms of reform in 1990s vs 2000s to control for any structural breaks in the overall period. Further, to check whether the trade liberalization impacts are period (phase) specific, we include interactive dummies for effective rate of protection. We would also test for Import Penetration (MPR) which is an outcome variable for ERP and MCR as part of explanatory variables. The idea of introduction of lagged level variable is based on theoretical underpinning of transmission of impact of relaxation of trade restriction on productivity. Expected signs of the coefficients of the explanatory variables are shown below:

Table 5.6: Expected Signs of the Coefficients of the Explanatory Variables in the TFP Equations
Impact on Total factor productivity
Explanatory Variable Expected sign of coefficient Conjecture
ERP - Lowering of protection will enhance productivity
MCR - Removal of NTB’s will enhance productivity
EG + Increase in exports will raise productivity
PCM - Fall in mark-up (increase in competition) will raise productivity
KL + Increased capital intensity will raise productivity
GO + Increased output growth will reflect higher productivity growth (Verdoorn's law)
INFLu - Lowering of inflation uncertainty will raise productivity
MPR + Increase in imports will enhance productivity

The variables representing trade policy reforms cover the following routes to productivity enhancement- competition and scale. First, the changes in both tariff- based protection and the import coverage ratios are our measures of increased exposure to foreign competition. We expect the coefficients of both Δ ERP and Δ MCR to be negative. The coefficient of Δ EG is expected to be positive, reflecting that higher exports reflect higher productivity growth. Output growth (OG) reflects the effects of scale with a significant positive relationship with TFP growth interpreted as the existence of dynamic increasing returns or the Verdoorn relationship [Nishimizu and Robinson (1986)]. Most empirical studies of the determinants of TFP growth find the output growth to be by far the single most important explanatory variable. The change in price-cost margin for an industry is defined as the ratio of (value added –total emoluments) to the value of output is used as a measure of the change in domestic competitive pressure, with a decrease reflecting a drop in monopolistic mark-ups. If greater internal competitive pressure brought about by reforms in industrial policy acts a spur to productivity growth, the sign on the Δ PCM coefficient will be negative. The change in the capital-labor ratio (also capital-output ratio) is used as a measure of capital intensity with the expectation that increased capital use relative to labor will raise productivity as a result of superior technology embodied in the capital inputs. The variable representing the macro-environment i.e. inflation uncertainty (INFLu) is expected to have a negative sign with a decrease in uncertainty reflecting an improved productivity growth.

Table 5.7: Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth: Empirical Results
Regression Results - Dependent variable: lnTFP (All Manufacturing)
  Model-I Model-II Model-III Model-IV
lnERPt-1 -0.0272*** -0.0289*** -0.0309***  
(0.0104) (0.00721) (0.00753)  
lnERPt-2 -0.0152 -0.0166** -0.0198***  
(0.0104) (0.00703) (0.00752)  
lnMCRt-1 -0.00697*** -0.00779*** -0.00363  
(0.00246) (0.00217) (0.00226)  
lnMCRt-2 -0.00854*** -0.00983*** -0.00718***  
(0.00245) (0.00216) (0.00218)  
lnPCMt-1 -0.0466*** -0.0427*** -0.0549*** -0.0522***
(0.0120) (0.0112) (0.0124) (0.0123)
lnPCMt-2 -0.000142 0.00344 -0.0143 -0.0129
(0.0117) (0.0113) (0.0127) (0.0126)
lnKLt-1 0.0526*** 0.0464*** 0.0271* 0.0229
(0.0133) (0.0119) (0.0155) (0.0150)
lnKLt-2 -0.000547 0.00339 -0.00556 -0.0109
(0.0134) (0.0123) (0.0156) (0.0146)
lnINFLu -0.0376*** -0.0374*** -0.0337*** -0.0341***
(0.00476) (0.00427) (0.00426) (0.00423)
lnINFLt-1u -0.00811 -0.00757* -0.00687 -0.00775*
(0.00509) (0.00427) (0.00425) (0.00424)
Δ ln GO 0.0402*** 0.0458*** 0.0480*** 0.0453***
(0.0121) (0.0101) (0.0117) (0.0115)
ΔlnGOt-1 0.0230* 0.0269*** 0.0272** 0.0236**
(0.0125) (0.0102) (0.0118) (0.0116)
ΔlnEG   -0.000902 -0.00134 -0.00165
  (0.00751) (0.00747) (0.00738)
ΔlnEGt-1   0.00125 0.00163 0.000840
  (0.00772) (0.00762) (0.00768)
D(1990s)   0.0214**    
  (0.0102)    
lnNRPt-1       -0.0403***
      (0.00864)
lnNRPt-2       -0.0122
      (0.00853)
lnFRt-1       -0.00516
      (0.00358)
lnFRt-2       -0.0100***
      (0.00372)
Constant 4.975*** 4.961*** 5.124*** 5.164***
(0.0578) (0.0559) (0.0880) (0.0872)
Observations 772 764 764 764
Industry Fixed effect No No Yes Yes
Number of industries 43 43 43 43
Note: Panel corrected standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Source: Author’s estimations based on model (5.1) and variables listed in Table 5.6

We have undertaken estimation of 4 versions of the standard HPAC model specified in the previous section. All the 4 models are estimated on natural logarithmic levels of the variables for all NIC98 industries in the panel. Model-I and Model-II differ in terms of the time dummy D for 1990-91 and 1999-00 period. In Model-III, we have introduced industry fixed effect at NIC98 3 digit level. In Model-IV, alternate measure of trade policy measures were introduced, we have used Nominal Tariff rates (NTR) in place of Effective rate of protection (ERP) and Frequency ratio (FR) instead of Import Coverage ratio (MCR).

Looking at the regression result for all industries, the effect of decrease in ERP on TFP is mainly felt with one year lag and impact vary from 0.27 per cent to 0.30 per cent increase in TFP with 10 per cent fall in ERP. The reduction of NTBs captured by MCR has relatively smaller impact on increase in TFP. A 10 per cent fall in MCR increases TFP between 0.07 per cent and 0.09 per cent with 2 years lag. The biggest impact of rise in TFP has actually come from improvement in domestic industrial policy. We have tried to capture domestic level of competition using Price Cost Margin (PCM). A 10 per cent fall in PCM increases TFP between 0.4 per cent and 0.6 per cent with 1 year lag. We can also observe that increase in output growth has the second highest impact on TFP change. The impact of changes in trade policy measures and domestic industrial policy is statistically significant in 1990s, evident from the time dummy D.


Table 5.8: Regression Results - Dependent Variable: lnTFP (Used-based Manufacturing)
  Consumer goods Intermediate goods Capital goods
lnERPt-1 -0.00937 -0.0282* -0.0627***
(0.0110) (0.0161) (0.0188)
lnERPt-2 -0.00317 0.0121 -0.0740***
(0.0114) (0.0153) (0.0183)
lnMCRt-1 -0.0141*** -0.00567* 0.00100
(0.00525) (0.00321) (0.00411)
lnMCRt-2 -0.00772 -0.00404 -0.00552
(0.00521) (0.00318) (0.00424)
lnPCMt-1 -0.0529*** -0.0520** -0.0797***
(0.0164) (0.0210) (0.0254)
lnPCMt-2 -0.0102 -0.0272 0.00843
(0.0160) (0.0199) (0.0271)
lnKLt-1 -0.00244 0.0414 0.0952***
(0.0249) (0.0358) (0.0260)
lnKLt-2 -0.0548** -0.0563 0.0402
(0.0251) (0.0389) (0.0275)
lnINFLu -0.0424*** -0.0312*** -0.0111
(0.00634) (0.00762) (0.00936)
lnINFLt-1u -0.0105* -0.00523 -0.00352
(0.00637) (0.00879) (0.00974)
ΔlnGO 0.0192 0.104*** 0.0818***
(0.0157) (0.0326) (0.0298)
ΔlnGOt-1 0.0162 0.0672** 0.0186
(0.0143) (0.0326) (0.0286)
ΔlnEG -0.0329** -0.000296 -0.0168
(0.0133) (0.00829) (0.0221)
ΔlnEGt-1 -0.0173 -0.00180 -0.0102
(0.0133) (0.00849) (0.0220)
Constant 5.157*** 4.128*** 5.202***
(0.115) (0.0892) (0.152)
Observations 370 196 198
Industry Fixed effect Yes Yes Yes
Number of industries 21 11 11
Note: Panel corrected standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Source: Author’s computation

We have estimated Model-III separately for 3 use-based industry groups for period 1990-91 to 2009-10. From the results it is evident that impact of fall in ERP is not significant in consumer goods sector and highest in capital goods sector. A 10 per cent fall in ERP increases TFP by almost 0.6 per cent and for intermediate goods the impact is around 0.3 per cent with 1 year lag. The impact of ERP in capital good sector is more with 2 years lag. On the other hand fall in non-tariff restriction is significant in consumer goods sector with 1 year lag but has no impact on capital goods sector. One of the very significant results is impact of increase in capital intensity in capital goods sector, 10 per cent increase in capital intensity in capital goods sector increase TFP by almost 1 per cent.

In conclusion, the results suggest that the trade policy reforms of the 1990s and further changes in trading rules and regulations in 2000s did contribute to improvements in productivity growth via the removal of both tariff and non-tariff based barriers. This holds for the all industries as well as capital goods industries, one of the three-use-based sectors analyzed in the study. We find that lowering of trade barriers is consistent with the competitive effect of trade liberalization. Our results are also in line with those from other studies on South Asia [India-Ahluwalia (1994), Krishna and Mitra (1998), Sri Lanka–Athukorala and Rajapatirana (2000)] and majority of the studies surveyed in the literature The econometric exercise confirms that trade policy reforms have significant positive impact on productivity yardstick of manufacturing performance.

6: Conclusion

The study examined India’s efforts at trade liberalization for the 20 year period beginning 1990-91 at the level of industrial sector, especially in organized manufacturing. This was done via examining the trends and patterns of lowering tariff as well as non-tariff barriers (QRs) at the total manufacturing as well as use-based sectors of manufacturing- intermediate, capital and consumer goods. To do this end, we computed and estimated- nominal as well as effective rate of protection, proxies for NTBs - frequency ratio as well as import coverage ratio. Finally, an assessment of the impact of simultaneous lowering of tariffs and non-tariff restrictions was done by examining the import penetration rates.

Further, using a quantitative framework, an assessment was made of the impact of these measures of trade liberalization on manufacturing performance for the period 1990-2010. In particular, an econometric model based on panel data to explore the impact of trade liberalization on performance indicators (total factor productivity) for the manufacturing sector in India covering the several phases of trade reforms beyond 1990-91. To assess the impact on manufacturing performance, we used variables that represent trade liberalization along with industrial policy reforms and macroeconomic business environment.

The study observed that removal of restrictions in trade-in terms of lowering of tariff barriers and dismantling of import licensing regime has been substantial since 1990-91 but gain in terms of import penetration has not been of the similar order. In particular, One, trade protection measured by Nominal import tariff as well as Effective rate of protection were brought down substantially in 1990s. Non-tariff protection got almost halved by 1992-93 and become less than 10 per cent by the beginning of 2000-01. Two, Capital goods saw faster reduction in ERP as well as NTB during 1990s compared to intermediate & consumer goods. Three, at the level of total manufacturing the change in import penetration rates show a near doubling within 20 years from around 9.7 per cent in 1990-91 to around 18 per cent by the end of 2009-10. We have also compared the period of 1990s versus 2000s in order to understand the manner of lowering of tariff as well as NTBs. We confirm that there was a sharp fall in tariff levels as well as quantitative restrictions in the 1990s as compared to the 2000s. The periods of 2000s were more aimed at simplifying the trade procedures as well as boosting exports.

The examination of the impact of trade openness as captured by various measures of trade policy reforms indicates that of decrease in tariff barrier (captured by effective rate of protection) on industrial productivity is mainly felt with one year lag and the reduction of NTBs captured by import coverage ratio has relatively smaller impact on increase in TFP. The biggest impact of rise in TFP has actually comes from improvement in domestic industrial policy. Therefore, greater internal competitive pressure brought about by reforms in industrial policy acts a spur to productivity growth. We also find a positive impact of increase in capital intensity in capital goods sector and this is mainly driven by substantial lowering of tariff rates on capital goods imports as well relaxing of import controls on machines and equipments since 1991-92. Our quantitative result reinforces not only the role of trade policy reforms but also the literature on roles of industrial as well as trade reforms as complementarities in enhancing manufacturing performance.

We conclude that from a piecemeal trade liberalization effort in the 1980s, we have come a long way in reforming our trading regimes during the period 1990s- 2010 with respect to tariff and non-tariff restrictions. In terms of the MFN tariffs, India is not out of line with the other Asian countries- China: 8.7 (2009); Thailand: 8.0 (2011); and Malaysia: 5.8 (2010). Our tariffs on capital goods have also been considerably lowered in successive trade policy documents since 1991-92. We have also seen the full-scale dismantling of the remaining import curbs in the Export-Import (EXIM) Policy for 2001-02 announced by the Government of India on March 31, 2001. What remains worrisome is that despite all these efforts at trade liberalization, the rate of change in import penetration ratios is not in line with the other measures of trade liberalization. This needs to be examined in greater depth and will form the core of further research.

It is a well documented fact that Indian manufacturing still contributes an insignificant share of world manufacturing and services sector leading the engine of growth. It needs an examination as to why Indian manufacturing is still far from the levels achieved by either Asian economies like Thailand, Malaysia or Taiwan or even countries like Brazil and Mexico. The Government of India (The Manufacturing Plan, Planning Commission, GoI) attributes poor manufacturing performance to poor implementation and outlines two causes - inadequate consensus amongst stakeholders for policy changes, and very poor coordination amongst agencies in execution. Further it suggests that longer time frame national manufacturing policy. We assert that with the substantial changes in trade and industrial policies, it is essential that we look for factors which still constrain manufacturing growth and productivity and suggest appropriate policy changes in those areas which still constrain manufacturing performance.

Finally, as we have already seen substantial reduction in levels of trade protection across manufacturing groups and the trade policy changes have also been followed by reforms in industrial policy. Therefore, we now need to address issues which can further magnify the benefits of trade and industrial policy reforms such as easing of supply constraints and appropriate policy changes to remove bottlenecks transport, power shortages, erratic supply of energy (water and electricity) as well as labor regulations etc. Appropriate policy actions on these fronts along with further easing of trading environment will make India’s manufactured goods internationally competitive.


Annexure

Table A 1: Nominal Rate of Protection (per cent) in Indian Industries: Use-Based Classification
Code NIC 87 Three-Digit Classification Description 1990-91 to 1996-97 1997-98 to 2002-03 2003-04 to 2009-10
Intermediate Goods industries
230 Cotton ginning, spinning and bailing 75.46 34.38 14.97
231 Cotton spinning other than in mills 75.46 34.38 14.97
235 Cotton spinning, weaving and processing in mills 75.46 34.38 14.97
240 Preparing of raw wool, silk and textile fibers for spinning 96.06 33.15 14.61
241 Wool spinning, weaving and finishing other than in mills 77.49 33.72 14.87
242 Wool spinning, weaving and finishing in mills 77.49 33.72 14.87
244 Spinning, weaving & finishing of silk other than in mills 87.71 31.57 14.20
245 spinning, weaving and finishing of silk in mills 87.71 31.57 14.20
247 spinning, weaving and processing of man-made textiles 122.97 34.16 14.75
248 spinning, weaving & processing of artificial/synthetic textiles 122.97 34.16 14.75
250 Jute and Mesta pressing and bailing 104.26 38.53 15.53
251 Preparatory operations of jute and Mesta fibers 104.26 38.53 15.53
252 Preparatory operations of coir fibers 104.26 38.53 15.53
253 Preparatory operations of other vegetable fibers 104.26 38.53 15.53
254 Spinning, weaving and finishing of jute and Mesta textiles 104.26 38.53 15.53
255 Spinning, weaving and finishing of coir textiles 104.26 38.53 15.53
256 Spinning, weaving and finishing of vegetable fiber textiles 104.26 38.53 15.53
270 Sawing and planking of wood 85.83 33.09 15.41
271 Manufacture of veneer sheets 85.83 33.09 15.41
272 Manufacture of structural wooden goods 85.83 33.09 15.41
280 Manufacture of pulp, paper and paper board 94.49 27.72 14.03
281 Manufacture of container and boxes of paper 94.49 27.72 14.03
282 Manufacture of paper and paper board NEC 94.49 27.72 14.03
290 Tanning, curing, finishing of leather 79.31 32.15 14.73
300 Industrial organic and inorganic chemical 82.63 35.48 14.15
301 Fertilizers and pesticides 63.59 29.02 11.84
302+306 Synthetic rubber Man-made Fibers 82.46 35.78 14.37
303 Paints, varnishes and related products, 99.29 36.32 15.17
308 Explosives and Fireworks 79.97 33.98 15.80
309 Chemical Products n.e.c 79.97 33.98 15.80
310 Tyre and tubes 88.89 40.34 15.41
312 Rubber product n.e.c 88.89 40.34 15.41
313 Plastic products n.e.c 91.39 37.47 15.53
314 Refined petroleum product 68.91 23.26 11.22
316 Refined petroleum products n.e.c 68.91 23.26 11.22
318 Coke-oven products 61.55 33.94 15.19
319 Other coal and coal tar product n.e.c 61.55 33.94 15.19
324 Manufacture of cement, lime and plasters 105.57 38.33 15.14
325 Manufacture of mica products 103.43 36.83 15.72
326 Manufacture of structural stone goods and stone ware 103.43 36.83 15.72
327 Manufacture of asbestos cement and other cement products 105.57 38.33 15.14
329 Manufacture of misc. non metallic mineral products n.e.c 103.43 36.83 15.72
330 Iron and steel primary/semi finished forms 76.87 35.28 14.33
331 Semi finished iron and steel products 76.87 35.28 14.33
332 Ferro Alloys 67.04 31.78 12.77
333 Copper manufacturing 69.40 32.55 11.57
335 Aluminum manufacturing 69.40 32.55 11.57
336 Zinc manufacturing 69.40 32.55 11.57
338+339 Metal products and Non Ferrous metals 69.40 32.55 11.57
340 Fabricated structural metal products 87.43 36.43 15.36
341 Fabricated metal products, n.e.c 87.43 36.43 15.36
343+349 Hand-tools, weights etc 72.31 35.75 15.49
Capital Goods industries
350 Agri machinery and equipments and parts thereof 50.66 29.29 14.04
351 Construction and mining industries 51.24 27.28 13.73
352 Prime movers, boilers, steam generating plants nuclear reactors 51.24 27.28 13.73
353 Industrial machinery for food and textile industry 51.42 28.72 13.76
354 Industrial machinery other than food and textile 51.24 27.28 13.73
356 General purpose Machinery 58.94 29.26 13.86
357 Machine tools parts and accessories 54.41 27.00 13.71
358 Office, computing and accounting machinery and parts 73.39 30.80 7.49
359 Special purpose machinery and equipment /component/accessories 58.94 29.26 13.86
360 Electrical industrial machinery 56.99 28.46 13.74
361 Insulated wires and cables 82.57 40.06 13.45
362 Primary cells and primary batteries 93.71 40.72 15.17
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 76.05 28.13 8.64
368 Electronic valves and tubes 76.05 28.13 8.64
369 X ray Machines and Electrical equipment’s n.e.c 76.05 28.13 8.64
370 Ship and boat building 57.67 34.60 14.28
371 Locomotives and parts 53.46 28.77 14.79
372 Railway/tramway wagons and coaches 53.46 28.77 14.79
377 Aircraft, spacecraft and parts 83.53 40.65 15.53
379 Transport and equipment’s and parts 83.53 40.65 15.53
Consumer Goods industries
200 Slaughtering, preparation and preservation of meat 101.60 28.86 32.26
201 Manufacture of dairy products 101.60 28.86 32.26
202 Canning and preservation of fruits and vegetables 101.60 28.86 32.26
203 Processing, canning and preservation of fish, crustacean 101.60 28.86 32.26
204 Grain milling 101.60 28.86 32.26
205 Manufacture of bakery products 101.60 28.86 32.26
206 Manufacture and refining of sugar (vacuum pan sugar factories) 83.14 48.24 61.46
207 Production of indigenous sugar, ‘Boora’, ‘Khandsari’, ‘Gur’ etc. 83.14 48.24 61.46
208 Manufacture of common salt 101.60 28.86 32.26
209 Manufacture of cocoa products and sugar confectionery 101.60 28.86 32.26
210 Manufacture of hydrogenated oil and Vanaspati 107.71 33.33 90.17
211 Manufacture of Vegetable oils 110.43 54.08 72.59
212 Manufacture of Animal oils 110.43 54.08 72.59
213 Processing and blending of tea including instant tea 115.57 48.60 74.14
214 Coffee curing, roasting and blending 115.57 48.60 74.14
215 Manufacture of edible nuts 101.60 28.86 32.26
216 Manufacture of ice 101.60 28.86 32.26
217 Manufacture of prepared animal and bird fee 101.60 28.86 32.26
218 Manufacture of Starch 101.60 28.86 32.26
219 Manufacture of food products n.e.c 101.60 28.86 32.26
220 Distilling rectifying and blending of spirits 204.86 94.93 50.81
221 Manufacture of Wine 204.86 94.93 50.81
222 Manufacture of Malt Liquors and Malt 204.86 94.93 50.81
223 Manufacture of Country Liquors 204.86 94.93 50.81
224 Manufacture of Soft drinks and Syrups 204.86 94.93 50.81
225 Tobacco Stemming, redrying and other preparations 115.57 37.23 30.17
226 Manufacture of bidi 115.57 37.23 30.17
227 Manufacture of Cigars, cigarette, cheroots and c tobacco 115.57 37.23 30.17
228 Manufacture of Snuff, Zarda etc 115.57 37.23 30.17
229 Manufacture of Pan masala etc 115.57 37.23 30.17
232 Weaving and finishing of cotton khadi 75.46 34.38 14.97
233 Weaving and finishing of cotton textiles on handlooms 75.46 34.38 14.97
234 Weaving and finishing of cotton textiles on power looms 75.46 34.38 14.97
236 Bleaching, dyeing and pruning of cotton textiles 75.46 34.38 14.97
243 Bleaching and dyeing of woolen textiles 77.49 33.72 14.87
246 Bleaching and dyeing of silk textiles 87.71 31.57 14.20
257 Bleaching, dyeing and printing of Jute and Mesta fibers 111.49 38.68 15.53
258 Bleaching, dyeing and printing of coir fibers 111.49 38.68 15.53
259 Bleaching, dyeing and printing of vegetable fibers nec 111.49 38.68 15.53
260 Manufacture of knitted or crocheted textile products 93.83 40.41 15.53
262 Threads, Cordage, Ropes n Twines 90.93 38.11 15.33
263 Blankets, shawls, carpets, and other similar textile products 77.41 33.73 14.87
265 Textile garments and clothing accessories 93.83 40.41 15.53
267 Made up textiles except apparel 93.83 40.41 15.53
268 Water proof textile fabrics 90.93 38.11 15.33
269 Textiles/ textile products n.e.c. 90.93 38.11 15.33
273 Manufacture of wooden goods 85.83 33.09 15.41
274 Manufacture of wooden industrial goods 85.83 33.09 15.41
275 Manufacture of cork and cork products 85.83 33.09 15.41
276 Manufacture of wooden furniture and fixtures 115.57 38.33 15.53
277 Manufacture of bamboo and cane furniture and fixtures 115.57 38.33 15.53
279 Manufacture of wood, cane, bamboo, reed & grass n.e.c 115.57 38.33 15.53
283 Manufacture of special purpose newspaper-printed or not n.e.c 94.49 27.72 14.03
284 Printing and publishing of newspaper 69.17 22.38 11.86
285 Printing and publishing of periodicals, books, etc 69.17 22.38 11.86
286 Printing of bank notes, currency etc 69.17 22.38 11.86
287 Engraving, etching and block making 69.17 22.38 11.86
288 Book binding on account of others 69.17 22.38 11.86
289 Printing and allied activities NEC 69.17 22.38 11.86
291 Footwear of leather 91.77 40.69 15.53
292 Wearing apparel of leather + leather sub 79.31 32.16 14.73
293 Leather products and substitutes 79.31 32.16 14.73
299 Leather and fur product n.e.c. 79.31 32.16 14.73
304 Drugs and medicines 81.34 36.05 14.93
305 Perfumes, cosmetics and Lotions 94.01 42.35 17.69
311 Rubber and Plastic Footwear 90.12 38.90 15.47
321 Manufacture of glass and glass products 101.89 35.35 14.70
322 Manufacture of earthen and plaster products 101.89 35.35 14.70
323 Manufacture of non structural ceramic ware 101.89 35.35 14.70
342 Furniture’s and fixtures of metals 85.26 36.92 15.87
346 Metal Kitchen ware 85.26 36.92 15.87
355 Manufacture of refrigerators, AC's 79.03 37.79 15.09
363+364 Electric lamps, fans and Domestic Appliances 79.04 37.79 15.09
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 76.05 28.13 8.64
373+374 Heavy motor vehicles; cars and parts 74.54 42.24 28.86
375 Motor cycles, scooters and parts 77.53 47.88 39.99
376 Bicycles, cycle rickshaws and parts 65.77 40.67 15.53
Source: Author’s computation based on DGCIS database, Customs Tariff Schedule and Input-Output Transactions table, Government of India.

Table A 2: Effective Rate of Protection (per cent) in Indian Industries: Use-Based Classification
Code NIC 87 Three-Digit Classification Description 1990-91 to 1996-97 1997-98 to 2002-03 2003-04 to 2009-10
Intermediate Goods industries
230 Cotton ginning, spinning and bailing 73.49 34.41 15.06
231 Cotton spinning other than in mills 73.49 34.41 15.06
235 Cotton spinning, weaving and processing in mills 73.49 34.41 15.06
240 Preparing of raw wool, silk and textile fibers for spinning 108.40 32.86 14.73
241 Wool spinning, weaving and finishing other than in mills 64.21 33.25 14.90
242 Wool spinning, weaving and finishing in mills 64.21 33.25 14.90
244 Spinning, weaving and finishing of silk other than in mills 87.76 31.31 14.23
245 Spinning, weaving and finishing of silk in mills 87.76 31.31 14.23
247 Spinning, weaving and processing of manmade textiles 173.22 34.04 15.06
248 Spinning, weaving and processing of artificial/synthetic textiles 173.22 34.04 15.06
250 Jute and Mesta pressing and bailing 108.48 39.17 15.61
251 Preparatory operations of Jute and Mesta fibers 108.48 39.17 15.61
252 Preparatory operations of coir fibers 108.48 39.17 15.61
253 preparatory operations of other vegetable fibers 108.48 39.17 15.61
254 Spinning, weaving and finishing of Jute and Mesta textiles 108.48 39.17 15.61
255 Spinning, weaving and finishing of coir textiles 108.48 39.17 15.61
256 Spinning, weaving and finishing of vegetable fiber textiles 108.48 39.17 15.61
270 Sawing and planing of wood 86.47 33.07 15.53
271 Manufacture of veneer sheets 86.47 33.07 15.53
272 Manufacture of structural wooden goods 86.47 33.07 15.53
280 Manufacture of pulp, paper and paper board 98.61 26.30 13.91
281 Manufacture of container and boxes of paper 98.61 26.30 13.91
282 Manufacture of paper and paper board NEC 98.61 26.30 13.91
290 Tanning, curing, finishing of leather 82.54 39.47 14.72
300 Industrial organic and inorganic chemical 83.81 36.14 13.40
301 Fertilizers and pesticides 57.23 31.34 13.40
302+306 Synthetic rubber Man-made Fibers 82.51 36.40 14.38
303 Paints, varnishes and related products, 136.51 37.37 15.15
308 Explosives and Fireworks 79.38 33.93 15.54
309 Chemical Products NEC 79.38 33.93 15.54
310 Tyre and tubes 92.37 43.61 15.96
312 Rubber product n.e.c 92.37 43.61 15.96
313 Plastic products n.e.c 98.64 39.05 16.42
314 Refined petroleum product 68.72 23.04 11.18
316 Refined petroleum products n.e.c 68.72 23.04 11.18
318 Coke-oven products 60.81 34.03 15.36
319 Other coal and coal tar product n.e.c 60.81 34.03 15.36
324 Manufacture of cement, lime and plasters 109.37 38.66 15.31
325 Manufacture of mica products 115.10 37.81 16.42
326 Manufacture of structural stone goods and stone ware 115.10 37.81 16.42
327 Manufacture of asbestos cement and other cement products 109.37 38.66 15.31
329 Manufacture of misc non Metallica mineral products n.e.c 115.10 37.81 16.42
330 Iron and steel primary/semi finished forms 107.74 46.06 15.49
331 Semi finished iron and steel products 107.74 46.06 15.49
332 Ferro Alloys 64.52 31.19 12.69
333 Copper manufacturing 69.14 32.48 10.99
335 Aluminum manufacturing 69.14 32.48 10.99
336 Zinc manufacturing 69.14 32.48 10.99
338+339 Metal products and Non Ferrous metals 69.14 32.48 10.99
340 Fabricated structural metal products 172.20 45.64 17.02
341 Fabricated metal products, nec 172.20 45.64 17.02
343+349 Hand-tools, weights etc 71.58 37.39 17.44
Capital Goods industries
350 Agri machinery and equipments and parts thereof 42.05 26.20 14.17
351 Construction and mining industries 41.85 24.05 14.21
352 Prime movers, boilers, steam generating plants nuclear reactors 41.85 24.05 14.21
353 Industrial machinery for food and textile industry 41.70 27.19 14.30
354 Industrial machinery other than food and textile 41.85 24.05 14.21
356 General purpose Machinery 50.90 26.82 14.41
357 Machine tools parts and accessories 45.16 23.25 13.61
358 Office, computing and accounting machinery and parts 72.75 29.00 3.62
359 Special purpose machinery and equipment /component/accessories 50.90 26.82 14.41
360 Electrical industrial machinery 48.91 25.02 14.22
361 Insulated wires and cables 93.42 49.49 14.17
362 Primary cells and primary batteries 107.26 48.18 17.21
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 78.60 23.51 3.51
368 Electronic valves and tubes 78.60 23.51 3.51
369 X ray Machines and Electrical equipments nec 78.60 23.51 3.51
370 Ship and boat building 49.63 34.66 14.99
371 Locomotives and parts 45.49 25.87 15.74
372 Railway/tramway wagons and coaches 45.49 25.87 15.74
377 Aircraft, spacecraft and parts 89.96 43.68 10.70
379 Transport and equipments and parts 89.96 43.68 10.70
Consumer Goods industries
200 Slaughtering, preparation and preservation of meat 103.87 27.96 32.06
201 Manufacture of dairy products 103.87 27.96 32.06
202 Canning and preservation of fruits and vegetables 103.87 27.96 32.06
203 Processing, canning and preservation of fish, crustacean 103.87 27.96 32.06
204 Grain milling 103.87 27.96 32.06
205 Manufacture of bakery products 103.87 27.96 32.06
206 Manufacture and refining of sugar (vacuum pan sugar factories) 83.69 49.04 65.12
207 Production of indigenous sugar, ‘Boora’, ‘Khandsari’, ‘Gur’ etc. 83.69 49.04 65.12
208 Manufacture of common salt 103.87 27.96 32.06
209 Manufacture of cocoa products and sugar confectionery 103.87 27.96 32.06
210 Manufacture of hydrogenated oil and vanaspati 109.36 30.65 110.79
211 manufacture of Vegetable oils 111.19 55.83 77.56
212 Manufacture of Animal oils 111.19 55.83 77.56
213 Processing and blending of tea including instant tea 117.17 48.93 80.73
214 Coffee curing, roasting and blending 117.17 48.93 80.73
215 Manufacture of edible nuts 103.87 27.96 32.06
216 Manufacture of ice 103.87 27.96 32.06
217 Manufacture of prepared animal and bird fee 103.87 27.96 32.06
218 Manufacture of Starch 103.87 27.96 32.06
219 Manufacture of food products n.e.c 103.87 27.96 32.06
220 Distilling rectifying and blending of spirits 287.42 139.29 65.68
221 Manufacture of Wine 287.42 139.29 65.68
222 manufacture of Malt Liquors and Malt 287.42 139.29 65.68
223 Manufacture of Country Liquors 287.42 139.29 65.68
224 Manufacture of Soft drinks and Syrups 287.42 139.29 65.68
225 Tobacco Stemming, redrying and other preparations 122.31 38.24 31.40
226 manufacture of bidi 122.31 38.24 31.40
227 Manufacture of Cigars, cigarette, cheroots and c tobacco 122.31 38.24 31.40
228 Manufacture of Snuff, Zarda etc 122.31 38.24 31.40
229 Manufacture of Pan masala etc 122.31 38.24 31.40
232 Weaving and finishing of cotton khadi 75.70 34.53 15.06
233 Weaving and finishing of cotton textiles on handlooms 75.70 34.53 15.06
234 Weaving and finishing of cotton textiles on power looms 73.49 34.41 15.06
236 Bleaching, dyeing and pruning of cotton textiles 73.49 34.41 15.06
243 Bleaching and dyeing of woolen textiles 64.21 33.25 14.90
246 Bleaching and dyeing of silk textiles 87.76 31.31 14.23
257 Bleaching, dyeing and printing of Jute and Mesta fibers 137.24 40.08 16.15
258 Bleaching, dyeing and printing of coir fibers 137.24 40.08 16.15
259 Bleaching, dyeing and printing of vegetable fibers n.e.c 137.24 40.08 16.15
260 Manufacture of knitted or crocheted textile products 101.04 45.05 16.16
262 Threads, Cordage, Ropes n Twines 96.57 40.35 15.75
263 Blankets, shawls, carpets, and other similar textile products 64.21 33.25 14.90
265 Textile garments and clothing accessories 101.05 45.06 16.16
267 Made up textiles except apparel 101.05 45.06 16.16
268 Water proof textile fabrics 96.57 40.34 15.75
269 Textiles/ textile products n.e.c. 96.57 40.34 15.75
273 Manufacture of wooden goods 86.47 33.07 15.53
274 Manufacture of wooden industrial goods 86.47 33.07 15.53
275 Manufacture of cork and cork products 86.47 33.07 15.53
276 Manufacture of wooden furniture’s and fixtures 125.97 39.11 15.70
277 Manufacture of bamboo and cane furniture and fixtures 125.97 38.30 15.53
279 Manufacture of wood, cane, bamboo, reed and grass NEC 125.97 39.11 15.70
283 Manufacture of special purpose newspaper-printed or not NEC 98.61 26.30 13.91
284 Printing and publishing of newspaper 59.15 19.23 10.45
285 Printing and publishing of periodicals, books, etc 59.15 19.23 10.45
286 Printing of bank notes, currency etc 59.15 19.23 10.45
287 Engraving, etching and block making 59.15 19.23 10.45
288 Book binding on account of others 59.15 19.23 10.45
289 Printing and allied activites NEC 59.15 19.23 10.45
291 Footwear of leather 93.02 35.91 15.85
292 Wearing apparel of leather + leather sub 82.54 39.47 14.72
293 Leather products and substitutes 82.54 39.47 14.72
299 Leather and fur product n.e.c. 82.54 39.47 14.72
304 Drugs and medicines 79.17 36.93 14.43
305 Perfumes, cosmetics and Lotions 105.48 48.02 19.72
311 Rubber and Plastic Footwear 95.51 41.33 16.19
321 Manufacture of glass and glass products 109.12 35.73 14.82
322 Manufacture of earthen and plaster products 109.12 35.73 14.82
323 Manufacture of non structural ceramic ware 109.12 35.73 14.82
342 Furniture’s and fixtures of metals 94.44 40.59 18.17
346 Metal Kitchen ware 94.45 40.59 18.17
355 Manufacture of refrigerators, AC's 80.08 39.99 16.69
363+364 Electric lamps, fans and Domestic Appliances 80.07 40.00 16.69
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 78.60 23.51 3.51
373+374 Heavy motor vehicles; cars and parts 74.16 46.77 47.38
375 Motor cycles, scooters and parts 76.38 53.82 59.84
376 Bicycles, cycle rickshaws and parts 62.84 43.86 16.24
Source: Author’s computation based on DGCIS database, Customs Tariff Schedule and Input-Output Transactions table, Government of India.

Table A 3: Frequency Ratio (per cent) in Indian Industries: Use-Based Classification
Code NIC 87 Three-Digit Classification Description 1990-91 to 1996-97 1997-98 to 2002-03 2003-04 to 2009-10
Intermediate Goods industries
230 Cotton ginning, spinning and bailing 45.45 31.57 0.00
231 Cotton spinning other than in mills 45.45 31.57 0.00
235 Cotton spinning, weaving and processing in mills 45.45 31.57 0.00
240 Preparing of raw wool, silk and textile fibers for spinning 52.16 26.98 3.03
241 Wool spinning, weaving and finishing other than in mills 18.18 6.06 3.03
242 Wool spinning, weaving and finishing in mills 18.18 6.06 3.03
244 Spinning, weaving and finishing of silk other than in mills 72.86 61.11 0.00
245 Spinning, weaving and finishing of silk in mills 72.86 61.11 0.00
247 Spinning, weaving and processing of manmade textiles 43.72 11.66 0.00
248 Sinning, weaving and processing of artificial/synthetic textiles 43.72 11.66 0.00
250 Jute and Mesta pressing and bailing 66.52 42.71 0.00
251 Preparatory operations of jute and Mesta fibers 66.52 42.71 0.00
252 Preparatory operations of coir fibers 66.52 42.71 0.00
253 Preparatory operations of other vegetable fibers 66.52 42.71 0.00
254 Spinning, weaving and finishing of jute and Mesta textiles 66.52 42.71 0.00
255 Spinning, weaving and finishing of coir textiles 66.52 42.71 0.00
256 Spinning, weaving and finishing of vegetable fiber textiles 66.52 42.71 0.00
270 Sawing and planing of wood 49.69 6.83 0.00
271 Manufacture of veneer sheets 49.69 6.83 0.00
280 Manufacture of pulp, paper and paper board 54.91 11.01 0.00
281 Manufacture of container and boxes of paper 54.91 11.01 0.00
282 Manufacture of paper and paper board n.e.c 54.91 11.01 0.00
290 Tanning, curing, finishing of leather 33.04 11.79 8.93
300 Industrial organic and inorganic chemical 5.36 4.48 2.90
301 Fertilizers and pesticides 83.33 12.22 2.13
302+306 Synthetic rubber Man-made Fibers 10.34 2.16 0.37
303 Paints, varnishes and related products, 71.43 20.71 0.00
308 Explosives and Fireworks 48.10 20.37 15.91
309 Chemical Products n.e.c 48.10 20.37 15.91
310 Tyre and tubes 58.77 18.75 5.99
312 Rubber product n.e.c 58.77 18.75 5.99
313 Plastic products n.e.c 61.22 21.56 6.89
314 Refined petroleum product 61.61 21.03 7.20
316 Refined petroleum products n.e.c 61.61 23.12 7.20
318 Coke-oven products 28.57 0.00 0.00
324 Manufacture of cement, lime and plasters 100.00 37.22 0.00
325 Manufacture of mica products 73.82 19.63 0.00
326 Manufacture of structural stone goods and stone ware 73.82 19.63 0.00
327 Manufacture of asbestos cement and other cement products 100.00 37.22 0.00
329 Manufacture of misc non metallic mineral products NEC 73.82 19.63 0.00
330 Iron and steel primary/semi finished forms 33.13 6.38 4.47
331 Semi finished iron and steel products 33.13 6.38 4.47
332 Ferro Alloys 33.04 7.07 12.24
333 Copper manufacturing 24.52 17.61 10.01
335 Aluminum manufacturing 24.52 17.61 10.01
336 Zinc manufacturing 24.52 17.61 10.01
338+339 Metal products and Non Ferrous metals 24.52 17.61 10.01
340 Fabricated structural metal products 28.57 0.00 0.00
341 Fabricated metal products, n.e.c 28.57 0.00 0.00
343+349 Hand-tools, weights etc 79.70 30.88 0.00
Capital Goods industries
350 Agri machinery and equipments and parts thereof 38.10 28.28 0.00
351 Construction and mining industries 14.29 0.01 0.00
352 Prime movers, boilers, steam generating plants nuclear reactors 14.29 0.01 0.00
353 Industrial machinery for food and textile industry 34.69 1.44 0.00
354 Industrial machinery other than food and textile 14.29 0.01 0.00
356 General purpose Machinery 59.74 16.74 12.47
357 Machine tools parts and accessories 0.00 0.00 0.00
358 Office, computing and accounting machinery and parts 66.33 12.51 0.00
359 Special purpose machinery and equipment /component/accessories 59.74 16.74 12.47
360 Electrical industrial machinery 35.71 10.25 10.00
361 Insulated wires and cables 42.86 0.00 0.00
362 Primary cells and primary batteries 100.00 25.00 0.00
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 49.11 15.79 2.98
368 Electronic valves and tubes 49.11 15.79 2.98
369 X ray Machines and Electrical equipments nec 49.11 15.79 2.98
370 Ship and boat building 91.43 39.67 4.29
371 Locomotives and parts 35.71 0.00 0.00
372 Railway/tramway wagons and coaches 35.71 0.00 0.00
Consumer Goods industries
200 Slaughtering, preparation and preservation of meat 91.32 49.17 9.46
201 Manufacture of dairy products 91.32 49.17 9.46
202 Canning and preservation of fruits and vegetables 91.32 49.17 9.46
203 Processing, canning and preservation of fish, crustacean 91.32 49.17 9.46
204 Grain milling 91.32 49.17 9.46
205 Manufacture of bakery products 91.32 49.17 9.46
206 Manufacture and refining of sugar (vacuum pan sugar factories) 28.96 0.36 0.00
207 Production of indigenous sugar, ‘Boora’, ‘khandsari’, ‘Gur’ etc. 28.96 0.36 0.00
208 manufacture of common salt 91.32 49.17 9.46
209 Manufacture of cocoa products and sugar confectionery 91.32 49.17 9.46
210 Manufacture of hydrogenated oil and vanaspati 80.65 65.28 36.25
211 Manufacture of Vegetable oils 86.31 30.40 2.39
212 Manufacture of Animal oils 86.31 30.23 2.08
213 Processing and blending of tea including instant tea 98.51 53.58 0.00
214 Coffee curing, roasting and blending 98.51 53.58 0.00
215 Manufacture of edible nuts 96.30 52.50 10.10
216 Manufacture of ice 93.53 49.34 8.91
217 Manufacture of prepared animal and bird fee 93.53 49.34 8.91
218 Manufacture of Starch 93.53 49.34 8.91
219 Manufacture of food products n.e.c 93.53 49.34 8.91
220 Distilling rectifying and blending of spirits 92.06 62.04 0.00
221 Manufacture of Wine 92.06 62.04 0.00
222 Manufacture of Malt Liquors and Malt 92.06 62.04 0.00
223 Manufacture of Country Liquors 92.06 62.04 0.00
224 Manufacture of Soft drinks and Syrups 92.06 62.04 0.00
225 Tobacco Stemming, redrying and other preparations 100.00 69.44 0.00
226 Manufacture of bidi 100.00 69.44 0.00
227 Manufacture of Cigars, cigarette, cheroots and c tobacco 100.00 69.44 0.00
228 Manufacture of Snuff, Zarda etc 100.00 69.44 0.00
229 Manufacture of Pan masala etc 100.00 69.44 0.00
232 Weaving and finishing of cotton khadi 38.96 31.57 0.00
233 Weaving and finishing of cotton textiles on handlooms 45.45 31.57 0.00
234 Weaving and finishing of cotton textiles on power looms 45.45 31.57 0.00
236 Bleaching, dyeing and pruning of cotton textiles 45.45 31.57 0.00
243 Bleaching and dyeing of woolen textiles 18.18 6.06 3.03
246 Bleaching and dyeing of silk textiles 72.86 61.11 0.00
260 Manufacture of knitted or crocheted textile products 87.54 53.05 0.78
262 Threads, Cordage, Ropes n Twines 76.83 44.31 2.23
263 Blankets, shawls, carpets, and other similar textile products 48.05 13.64 0.00
265 Textile garments and clothing accessories 87.54 53.05 0.78
267 Made up textiles except apparel 87.54 53.05 0.78
268 Water proof textile fabrics 76.83 44.31 2.23
269 Textiles/ textile products n.e.c. 76.83 44.31 2.23
273 Manufacture of wooden goods 49.69 6.83 0.00
274 Manufacture of wooden industrial goods 49.69 6.83 0.00
275 Manufacture of cork and cork products 49.69 6.83 0.00
276 Manufacture of wooden furniture’s and fixtures 86.29 34.01 0.00
277 Manufacture of bamboo and cane furniture and fixtures 86.29 34.01 0.00
279 Manufacture of wood, cane, bamboo, reed and grass NEC 86.29 34.01 0.00
283 Manufacture of special purpose newspaper-printed or not NEC 54.91 11.01 0.00
284 Printing and publishing of newspaper 60.32 25.43 5.77
285 Printing and publishing of periodicals, books, etc 60.32 25.43 5.77
286 Printing of bank notes, currency etc 60.32 25.43 5.77
287 Engraving, etching and block making 60.32 25.43 5.77
288 Book binding on account of others 60.32 25.43 5.77
289 Printing and allied activities n.e.c 60.32 25.43 5.77
291 Footwear of leather 82.14 49.44 0.00
292 Wearing apparel of leather + leather sub 32.14 11.79 8.93
293 Leather products and substitutes 32.14 11.79 8.93
299 Leather and fur product n.e.c. 32.14 11.79 8.93
304 Drugs and medicines 11.69 15.90 3.06
305 Perfumes, cosmetics and Lotions 72.14 12.13 0.00
311 Rubber and Plastic Footwear 60.52 26.32 5.54
321 Manufacture of glass and glass products 76.19 38.89 0.00
322 Manufacture of earthen and plaster products 76.19 38.89 0.00
323 Manufacture of non structural ceramic ware 76.19 38.89 0.00
342 Furniture’s and fixtures of metals 69.64 27.13 0.00
346 Metal Kitchen ware 69.64 27.13 0.00
355 Manufacture of refrigerators, AC's 89.80 42.48 0.00
363+364 Electric lamps, fans and Domestic Appliances 100.00 44.80 0.00
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 49.11 15.79 2.98
373+374 Heavy motor vehicles; cars and parts 75.32 45.02 9.09
375 Motor cycles, scooters and parts 33.33 26.85 0.00
376 Bicycles, cycle rickshaws and parts 50.00 41.67 0.00
Source: Author’s computation based on DGCIS database, Customs Tariff Schedule, Government of India.

Table A 4: Import Coverage Ratio (per cent) in Indian Industries: Use-Based Classification
Code NIC 87 Three-Digit Classification Description 1990-91 to 1996-97 1997-98 to 2002-03 2003-04 to 2009-10
Intermediate Goods industries
230 Cotton ginning, spinning and bailing 92.83 55.58 0.00
231 Cotton spinning other than in mills 92.83 55.58 0.00
235 Cotton spinning, weaving and processing in mills 92.83 55.58 0.00
240 Preparing of raw wool, silk and textile fibers for spinning 47.75 17.78 0.00
241 Wool spinning, weaving and finishing other than in mills 0.98 0.91 0.00
242 Wool spinning, weaving and finishing in mills 0.98 0.91 0.00
244 Spinning, weaving and finishing of silk other than in mills 83.75 67.71 0.00
245 Spinning, weaving and finishing of silk in mills 83.75 67.71 0.00
247 Spinning, weaving and processing of Man-made textiles 45.38 10.60 0.00
248 Spinning, weaving and processing of artificial/synthetic textiles 45.38 10.60 0.00
250 Jute and Mesta pressing and bailing 88.15 70.94 0.00
251 Preparatory operations of Jute and Mesta fibers 88.15 70.94 0.00
252 Preparatory operations of coir fibers 88.15 70.94 0.00
253 Preparatory operations of other vegetable fibers 88.15 70.94 0.00
254 Spinning, weaving and finishing of Jute and Mesta textiles 88.15 70.94 0.00
255 Spinning, weaving and finishing of coir textiles 88.15 70.94 0.00
256 Spinning, weaving and finishing of vegetable fiber textiles 88.15 70.94 0.00
270 Sawing and planing of wood 36.51 0.99 0.00
271 Manufacture of veneer sheets 36.51 0.99 0.00
280 Manufacture of pulp, paper and paper board 63.64 36.65 28.87
281 Manufacture of container and boxes of paper 63.64 36.65 28.87
282 Manufacture of paper and paper board NEC 63.64 36.65 28.87
290 Tanning, curing, finishing of leather 3.12 1.17 0.44
300 Industrial organic and inorganic chemical 0.29 0.64 0.37
301 Fertilizers and pesticides 88.51 11.74 1.29
302+306 Synthetic rubber Man-made Fibers 4.17 0.39 0.07
303 Paints, varnishes and related products, 84.87 15.26 0.00
308 Explosives and Fireworks 26.26 3.18 1.58
309 Chemical Products n.e.c 26.26 3.18 1.58
310 Tyre and tubes 26.39 4.03 0.61
312 Rubber product n.e.c 26.39 4.03 0.61
313 Plastic products n.e.c 54.87 18.45 3.82
314 Refined petroleum product 97.24 74.15 41.00
316 Refined petroleum products n.e.c 97.24 74.15 41.00
318 Coke-oven products 28.57 0.00 0.00
324 Manufacture of cement, lime and plasters 100.00 22.77 0.00
325 Manufacture of mica products 97.71 93.07 0.00
326 Manufacture of structural stone goods and stone ware 97.71 93.07 0.00
327 Manufacture of asbestos cement and other cement products 100.00 22.77 0.00
329 Manufacture of misc non metallic mineral products NEC 97.71 93.07 0.00
330 Iron and steel primary/semi finished forms 28.81 3.67 6.63
331 Semi finished iron and steel products 28.81 3.67 6.63
332 Ferro Alloys 28.59 8.35 10.77
333 Copper manufacturing 50.26 85.74 14.37
335 Aluminum manufacturing 50.26 85.74 14.37
336 Zinc manufacturing 50.26 85.74 14.37
338+339 Metal products and Non Ferrous metals 50.26 85.74 14.37
340 Fabricated structural metal products 28.57 0.00 0.00
341 Fabricated metal products, n.e.c 28.57 0.00 0.00
343+349 Hand-tools, weights etc 56.33 7.39 0.00
Capital Goods Industries
350 Agri machinery and equipments and parts thereof 39.75 18.38 0.00
351 Construction and mining industries 16.00 0.00 0.00
352 Prime movers, boilers, steam generating plants nuclear reactors 16.00 0.00 0.00
353 Industrial machinery for food and textile industry 28.49 0.10 0.00
354 Industrial machinery other than food and textile 16.00 0.00 0.00
356 General purpose Machinery 54.69 2.11 0.07
357 Machine tools parts and accessories 0.00 0.00 0.00
358 Office, computing and accounting machinery and parts 30.33 0.27 0.00
359 Special purpose machinery and equipment /component/accessories 54.69 2.11 0.07
360 Electrical industrial machinery 21.09 0.84 0.04
361 Insulated wires and cables 42.86 0.00 0.00
362 Primary cells and primary batteries 100.00 19.18 0.00
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 19.79 6.26 4.89
368 Electronic valves and tubes 19.79 6.26 4.89
369 X ray Machines and Electrical equipments nec 19.79 6.26 4.89
370 Ship and boat building 88.82 12.95 2.16
371 Locomotives and parts 42.77 0.00 0.00
372 Railway/tramway wagons and coaches 42.77 0.00 0.00
377 Aircraft, spacecraft and parts 99.82 34.88 0.00
379 Transport and equipments and parts 99.82 34.88 0.00
Consumer Goods Industries
200 Slaughtering, preparation and preservation of meat 92.12 54.92 6.79
201 Manufacture of dairy products 92.12 54.92 6.79
202 Canning and preservation of fruits and vegetables 92.12 54.92 6.79
203 Processing, canning and preservation of fish, crustacean 92.12 54.92 6.79
204 Grain milling 92.12 54.92 6.79
205 Manufacture of bakery products 92.12 54.92 6.79
206 Manufacture and refining of sugar (vacuum pan sugar factories) 29.63 0.70 0.00
207 Production of indigenous sugar, ‘Boora’, ‘Khandsari’, ‘Gur’ etc. 29.63 0.70 0.00
208 manufacture of common salt 92.12 54.92 6.79
209 Manufacture of cocoa products and sugar confectionery 92.12 54.92 6.79
210 Manufacture of hydrogenated oil and vanaspati 82.13 58.42 47.20
211 manufacture of Vegetable oils 92.34 31.35 0.96
212 Manufacture of Animal oils 92.34 31.35 0.95
213 Processing and blending of tea including instant tea 82.83 74.48 0.00
214 Coffee curing, roasting and blending 82.83 74.48 0.00
215 Manufacture of edible nuts 92.12 54.81 6.79
216 Manufacture of ice 93.83 55.60 6.10
217 Manufacture of prepared animal and bird fee 93.83 55.60 6.10
218 Manufacture of Starch 93.83 55.60 6.10
219 Manufacture of food products NEC 93.83 55.60 6.10
220 Distilling rectifying and blending of spirits 98.94 77.15 0.00
221 Manufacture of Wine 98.94 77.15 0.00
222 Manufacture of Malt Liquors and Malt 98.94 77.15 0.00
223 Manufacture of Country Liquors 98.94 77.15 0.00
224 Manufacture of Soft drinks and Syrups 98.94 77.15 0.00
225 Tobacco Stemming, redrying and other preparations 100.00 72.03 0.00
226 Manufacture of bidi 100.00 72.03 0.00
227 Manufacture of Cigars, cigarette, cheroots and c tobacco 100.00 72.03 0.00
228 Manufacture of Snuff, Zarda etc 100.00 72.03 0.00
229 Manufacture of Pan masala etc 100.00 72.03 0.00
232 Weaving and finishing of cotton khadi 78.77 55.58 0.00
233 Weaving and finishing of cotton textiles on handlooms 92.83 55.58 0.00
234 Weaving and finishing of cotton textiles on power looms 92.83 55.58 0.00
236 Bleaching, dyeing and pruning of cotton textiles 92.83 55.58 0.00
243 Bleaching and dyeing of woolen textiles 0.98 0.91 0.00
246 Bleaching and dyeing of silk textiles 83.75 67.71 0.00
260 Manufacture of knitted or crocheted textile products 92.95 60.77 0.07
262 Threads, Cordage, Ropes n Twines 73.13 38.34 5.84
263 Blankets, shawls, carpets, and other similar textile products 32.17 8.68 0.00
265 Textile garments and clothing accessories 92.95 60.77 0.07
267 Made up textiles except apparel 92.95 60.77 0.07
268 Water proof textile fabrics 73.13 38.34 5.84
269 Textiles/ textile products n.e.c. 73.13 38.34 5.84
273 Manufacture of wooden goods 36.51 0.99 0.00
274 Manufacture of wooden industrial goods 36.51 0.99 0.00
275 Manufacture of cork and cork products 36.51 0.99 0.00
276 Manufacture of wooden furniture’s and fixtures 85.52 35.57 0.00
277 Manufacture of bamboo and cane furniture and fixtures 85.52 35.57 0.00
279 Manufacture of wood, cane, bamboo, reed and grass NEC 85.52 35.57 0.00
283 Manufacture of special purpose newspaper-printed or not NEC 63.64 36.65 28.87
284 Printing and publishing of newspaper 52.29 18.07 30.02
285 Printing and publishing of periodicals, books, etc 52.29 18.07 30.02
286 Printing of bank notes, currency etc 52.29 18.07 30.02
287 Engraving , etching and block making 52.29 18.07 30.02
288 Book binding on account of others 52.29 18.07 30.02
289 Printing and allied activities NEC 52.29 18.07 30.02
291 Footwear of leather 29.23 10.18 0.00
292 Wearing apparel of leather + leather sub 3.12 1.17 0.44
293 Leather products and substitutes 3.12 1.17 0.44
299 Leather and fur product n.e. 3.12 1.17 0.44
304 Drugs and medicines 10.16 21.05 5.58
305 Perfumes, cosmetics and Lotions 63.58 6.77 0.00
311 Rubber and Plastic Footwear 39.93 19.72 1.87
321 Manufacture of glass and glass products 30.60 2.13 0.00
322 Manufacture of earthen and plaster products 30.60 2.13 0.00
323 Manufacture of non structural ceramic ware 30.60 2.13 0.00
342 Furniture’s and fixtures of metals 38.08 6.69 0.00
346 Metal Kitchen ware 38.08 6.69 0.00
355 Manufacture of refrigerators, AC's 55.75 23.24 0.00
363+364 Electric lamps, fans and Domestic Appliances 100.00 29.48 0.00
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 19.79 6.26 4.89
373+374 Heavy motor vehicles; cars and parts 21.15 6.38 0.00
375 Motor cycles, scooters and parts 0.32 0.82 0.00
376 Bicycles, cycle rickshaws and parts 0.00 0.12 0.00
Source: Author’s computation based on DGCIS database, and Customs Tariff Schedule, Government of India.

Table A 5: Import Penetration Ratios in Indian Industries: Use-Based Classification
Code NIC Three-Digit Classification Description 1990-91 to 1996-97 1997-98 to 2002-03 2003-04 to 2009-10
Intermediate Goods Industries
235 Cotton spinning ,weaving and processing in mills 0.002 0.003 0.011
242 Wool spinning, weaving and finishing in mills 0.075 0.024 0.021
247 spinning, weaving and processing of manmade textiles 0.028 0.025 0.042
248 spinning, weaving and processing of artificial/synthetic textiles 0.447 0.349 2.160
254 spinning, weaving and finishing of Jute and Mesta textiles 0.004 0.014 0.037
270 Sawing and planing of wood 0.086 0.058 0.073
271 Manufacture of veneer sheets 0.013 0.012 0.016
280 Manufacture of pulp, paper and paper board 0.130 0.147 0.191
281 Manufacture of container and boxes of paper 0.467 0.372 0.461
282 Manufacture of paper and paper board NEC 0.944 0.848 0.952
290 Tanning, curing, finishing of leather 0.158 0.102 0.122
300 Industrial organic and inorganic chemical 0.352 0.487 0.776
301 Fertilizers and pesticides 0.118 0.151 0.329
302+306 Synthetic rubber Man-made Fibers 0.204 0.172 0.385
303 Paints, varnishes and related products, 0.010 0.017 0.045
308 Explosives and Fireworks 0.749 1.213 1.589
309 Chemical Products NEC 0.237 0.343 0.496
310 Tyre and tubes 0.062 0.111 0.195
313 Plastic products n.e.c 0.049 0.056 0.101
314 Refined petroleum product 0.272 0.168 0.135
318 Coke-oven products 0.143 0.501 0.430
324 manufacture of cement, lime and plasters 0.000 0.000 0.003
327 Manufacture of asbestos cement and other cement products 0.002 0.006 0.047
330 Iron and steel primary/semi finished forms 0.125 0.111 0.166
331 Semi finished iron and steel products 0.362 0.325 0.473
332 Ferro Alloys 0.743 0.692 1.016
333 Copper manufacturing 0.778 0.991 1.079
335 Aluminum manufacturing 0.421 0.683 0.729
336 Zinc manufacturing 0.865 0.985 1.072
338+339 Metal products and Non Ferrous metals 0.971 1.008 1.099
340 Fabricated structural metal products 0.026 0.676 0.748
341 Fabricated metal products, nec 0.019 0.567 0.648
343+349 Hand-tools, weights etc 0.038 0.081 0.114
Capital Goods Industries
350 Agri machinery and equipments and parts thereof 0.004 0.021 0.026
351 construction and mining industries 0.589 1.157 1.202
352 Prime movers, boilers, steam generating plants nuclear reactors 0.319 0.785 0.921
353 Industrial machinery for food and textile industry 0.315 0.758 0.790
354 Industrial machinery other than food and textile 0.434 1.008 1.099
356 General purpose Machinery 0.485 1.075 1.242
357 Machine tools parts and accessories 0.039 0.211 0.288
358 Office, computing and accounting machinery and parts 1.213 1.066 1.038
359 Special purpose machinery and equipment /component/accessories 0.850 1.290 1.442
360 Electrical industrial machinery 0.056 0.113 0.178
361 Insulated wires and cables 0.023 0.046 0.096
362 Primary cells and primary batteries 0.026 0.065 0.141
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 0.182 0.311 0.457
368 Electronic valves and tubes 0.735 0.669 0.778
369 X ray Machines and Electrical equipments nec 1.231 1.028 0.947
370 Ship and boat building 0.273 0.444 1.061
371 Locomotives and parts 0.094 0.242 0.514
372 Railway/tramway wagons and coaches 0.039 0.057 0.157
379 Transport and equipments and parts 0.009 0.008 0.014
Consumer Goods Industries
201 Manufacture of dairy products 0.062 0.037 0.060
204 Grain milling 0.028 0.019 0.015
206 Manufacture and refining of sugar (vacuum pan sugar factories) 0.015 0.014 0.020
210 Manufacture of hydrogenated oil and vanaspati 0.004 0.007 0.016
211 Manufacture of Vegetable oils 0.044 0.125 0.122
213 Processing and blending of tea including instant tea 0.001 0.004 0.012
220 Distilling rectifying and blending of spirits 0.007 0.010 0.070
221 Manufacture of Wine 0.055 0.080 0.400
222 manufacture of Malt Liquors and Malt 0.010 0.017 0.116
223 Manufacture of Country Liquors 0.032 0.056 0.312
224 Manufacture of Soft drinks and Syrups 0.015 0.012 0.081
225 Tobacco Stemming, redrying and other preparations 0.003 0.004 0.017
226 manufacture of bidi 0.001 0.002 0.008
227 Manufacture of Cigars, cigarette, cheerots and c tobacco 0.002 0.002 0.007
228 Manufacture of Snuff, Zarda etc 0.007 0.006 0.027
229 Manufacture of Pan masala etc 0.006 0.005 0.026
263 Blankets, shawls, carpets, and other similar textile products 0.105 0.029 0.021
276 Manufacture of wooden furniture’s and fixtures 0.006 0.019 0.108
279 Manufacture of wood, cane, bamboo, reed and grass NEC 0.024 0.030 0.126
283 Manufacture of special purpose newspaper-printed or not NEC 0.939 0.964 1.057
284 Printing and publishing of newspaper 0.067 0.109 0.222
285 Printing and publishing of periodicals, books, etc 0.139 0.254 0.492
286 Printing of bank notes, currency etc 0.783 1.007 1.127
287 Engraving , etching and block making 1.359 1.588 2.017
288 Book binding on account of others 1.110 1.189 1.355
289 Printing and allied activities NEC 0.114 0.140 0.158
291 Footwear of leather 0.022 0.009 0.021
304 Drugs and medicines 0.100 0.131 0.319
305 Perfumes, cosmetics and Lotions 0.035 0.077 0.121
321 Manufacture of glass and glass products 0.039 0.037 0.099
323 Manufacture of non structural ceramic ware 0.116 0.111 0.213
342 Furniture’s and fixtures of metals 0.801 0.163 0.140
346 Metal Kitchen ware 0.292 0.487 0.695
355 Manufacture of refrigerators, AC's 0.133 0.217 0.439
363+364 Electric lamps, fans and Domestic Appliances 0.118 0.247 0.455
365+366 Radio and TV apparatus 0.182 0.311 0.457
373+374 Heavy motor vehicles; cars and parts 0.041 0.052 0.080
375 Motor cycles, scooters and parts 0.013 0.011 0.022
376 Bicycles, cycle rickshaws and parts 0.029 0.022 0.049
Source: Author’s computation based on DGCIS database, and Customs Tariff Schedule, Government of India.

Table A 6: Nominal Rate of Protection, Frequency Ratio and Import Penetration Ratios
NIC-1998 Nominal Rates of Protection (%) Frequency Ratio (%) Import Penetration Ratios
P1 P2 P3 P1 P2 P3 P1 P2 P3
20 97.908 32.736 38.100 78.848 39.408 7.568 0.035 0.023 0.032
21 106.771 38.299 54.493 92.071 48.293 8.646 0.016 0.045 0.050
22 160.215 66.080 40.490 96.030 65.740 0.000 0.014 0.019 0.106
23 75.460 34.380 14.970 44.523 31.570 0.000 0.002 0.003 0.011
24 93.067 33.038 14.591 45.858 27.979 1.347 0.183 0.133 0.741
25 106.429 38.575 15.530 66.520 42.710 0.000 0.004 0.014 0.037
26 90.241 38.470 15.350 77.309 43.674 1.290 0.105 0.029 0.021
27 95.743 34.837 15.450 63.415 17.023 0.000 0.032 0.030 0.081
28 79.298 24.516 12.728 58.156 19.662 3.462 0.605 0.662 0.803
29 81.802 33.864 14.890 42.320 19.320 7.144 0.090 0.056 0.072
30 82.908 35.370 14.969 43.811 13.543 5.035 0.226 0.324 0.508
31 77.526 33.931 14.330 55.867 18.504 5.544 0.132 0.209 0.215
32 103.388 36.650 15.193 81.254 31.250 0.000 0.039 0.039 0.091
33 71.197 33.220 12.530 28.197 12.896 8.746 0.609 0.685 0.805
34 83.538 36.490 15.590 55.224 17.028 0.000 0.235 0.395 0.469
35 58.051 29.396 13.300 39.127 11.822 2.494 0.438 0.759 0.849
36 77.064 32.444 11.501 59.376 17.901 2.740 0.319 0.349 0.439
37 68.686 38.029 19.913 53.583 25.535 2.230 0.071 0.119 0.271
Source: Author’s computation based on Appendix Tables A1, A3 and A5
Note: For description of industry codes, see Table A7. P1 is the time period from 1990-91 to 1996-97, P2 refers to the period from 1997-98 to 2002-03 and P3 covers the period 2003-04 to 2009-10.

Table A 7: Description of Industry Codes: NIC-1998 Two Digit Industries
NIC- 98 Industry Descriptions
15 Manufactures of Food Products and Beverages
16 Manufactures of Tobacco Products
17 Manufactures of Textiles
18 Manufactures of Wearing Apparel; Dressing And Dyeing of Fur
19 Tanning And Dressing of Leather; Manufacture of Luggage, Handbags, Saddlery, Harness And Footwear
20 Manufactures of Wood and of Products of Wood and Cork, Except Furniture; Manufacture of Articles of Straw and Plaiting Materials
21 Manufactures of Paper and Paper Products
22 Publishing, Printing and Reproduction of Recorded Media
23 Manufactures of Coke, Refined Petroleum Products and Nuclear Fuel
24 Manufactures of Chemicals and Chemical Products
25 Manufactures of Rubber and Plastics Products
26 Manufactures of Other Non-Metallic Mineral Products
27 Manufacture of Basic Metals
28 Manufacture of Fabricated Metal Products, Except Machinery And Equipment
29 Manufacture of Machinery And Equipment n.e.c
30 Manufacture of Office, Accounting and Computing Machinery
31 Manufacture of electrical machinery and apparatus n.e.c.
32 Manufacture of Radio, Television and Communication Equipment and Apparatus
33 Manufacture of Medical, Precision and Optical Instruments, Watches and Clocks
34 Manufacture of Motor Vehicles, Trailers and Semi-Trailers
35 Manufacture of Other Transport Equipment
36 Manufacture of furniture; manufacturing n.e.c.
37 Recycling
Source: Annual Survey of Industries, Central Statistical Organisation, Government of India

Table A 8: TFP Estimates for 43 Organized Manufacturing Sub-sectors - 1990-91 to 2009-10
NIC 2004 Industry Description Classification GVA Share TFPG
151 Production, processing and preserving of meat, fish, fruits, veg., oils and fats Consumer 1.46 1.14
152 Manufacture of dairy product Consumer 1.32 -0.22
153 Manufacture of grain mills products, starches and starch products and prepared animal feeds Consumer 1.44 0.22
154 Manufacture of other food products Consumer 5.01 -0.69
155 Manufacture of beverages Consumer 1.26 -0.41
160 Manufacture of tobacco products Consumer 2.37 -1.39
171 Spinning, weaving and finishing of textiles Consumer 8.02 2.06
173 Manufacture of knitted and crocheted fabrics and articles Consumer 0.77 -2.59
181 Manufacturing of wearing apparel, except for fur apparel Consumer 2.02 0.65
182 Dressing and dyeing of fur, manufacture of articles of fur Consumer 0.01 2.98
191 Tanning and dressing of leather, manufacture of luggage hand bags, saddlery & harness Consumer 0.24 -0.16
192 Manufacture of footwear Consumer 0.53 0.29
201 Saw milling and planing of wood Intermediate 0.03 -3.29
202 Manufacture of products of wood, cork, straw and plaiting materials Intermediate 0.19 -1.96
210 Manufacture of paper and paper product Consumer 2.56 1.75
221 Publishing Consumer 0.92 -3.06
222 Printing and service activities related to printing Consumer 0.60 -2.22
231 Manufacture of coke oven products Intermediate 0.18 -2.45
232 Manufactured refined petroleum products Intermediate 4.70 -1.02
241 Manufacture of basic chemicals Intermediate 10.86 0.45
242 Manufacture of other chemical products Intermediate 8.80 -0.34
251 Manufacture of rubber products Consumer 1.64 1.88
252 Manufacture of plastic products Consumer 1.66 1.74
261 Manufacture of glass and glass products Consumer 0.54 1.98
269 Manufacture of non-metallic mineral products n.e.c Intermediate 4.99 0.52
271 Manufacture of basic iron and steel Intermediate 7.12 0.89
272 Manufacture of basic precious and non-ferrous metals Intermediate 2.42 1.02
281 Manufacture of structural metal products, tanks, reservoirs and steam generators Intermediate 0.89 1.65
289 Manufacture of other fabricated metal products, metal working service activities Intermediate 1.77 1.11
291 Manufacture of general purpose machinery Capital 2.90 1.85
292 Manufacture of special purpose machinery Capital 2.68 0.34
293 Manufacture of domestic appliances, n.e.c Consumer 0.59 2.49
300 Manufacture of office, accounting and computer machinery Capital 0.52 9.54
311 Manufacture of electric motors, generators and transformers Capital 1.10 0.82
312 Manufacture of electricity distribution and control apparatus Capital 0.68 2.08
313 Manufacture of insulated wire and cable Capital 0.73 0.91
314 Manufacture of accumulators, primary cells and primary batteries Capital 0.40 2.11
321 Manufacture of electronic valves and tubes and other electronic components Capital 0.88 4.27
323 Manufacture of TV and radio receivers, sound or video recording or reproducing apparatus, and associated goods Capital 0.88 5.63
341 Manufacture of motor vehicles Consumer 1.94 1.36
352 Manufacture of railway and tramway locomotives and rollick stock Capital 0.19 4.05
359 Manufacture of transport equipment n.e.c. Capital 1.79 1.81
361 Manufacture of furniture Consumer 0.26 4.46
  Aggregate Manufacturing (43 sectors)   89.87 0.98
Note:
1. Aggregate Manufacturing comprises the 43 subgroups included in the sample.
2. Average indicates simple average of 43 sub-groups
3. GVA shares are for 200-01
Source: Annual Survey of Industries and P C Das (2012)

Table A 9: TFP Estimates for Organized Manufacturing Sub-sectors - 1990-91 to 2009-10
NIC 2004 Industry Description GVA Share TFPG
151 Production, processing and preserving of meat, fish, fruits, veg., oils and fats 1.46 1.14
152 Manufacture of dairy product 1.32 -0.22
153 Manufacture of grain mills products, starches and starch products and prepared animal feeds 1.44 0.22
154 Manufacture of other food products 5.01 -0.69
155 Manufacture of beverages 1.26 -0.41
160 Manufacture of tobacco products 2.37 -1.39
171 Spinning, weaving and finishing of textiles 8.02 2.06
172 Manufacture of other textiles 0.77 2.84
173 Manufacture of knitted and crocheted fabrics and articles 0.77 -2.59
181 Manufacturing of wearing apparel, except for fur apparel 2.02 0.65
182 Dressing and dyeing of fur, manufacture of articles of fur 0.01 2.98
191 Tanning and dressing of leather, manufacture of luggage hand bags, saddlery & harness 0.24 -0.16
192 Manufacture of footwear 0.53 0.29
201 Saw milling and planing of wood 0.03 -3.29
202 Manufacture of products of wood, cork, straw and plaiting materials 0.19 -1.96
210 Manufacture of paper and paper product 2.56 1.75
221 Publishing 0.92 -3.06
222 Printing and service activities related to printing 0.60 -2.22
231 Manufacture of coke oven products 0.18 -2.45
232 Manufactured refined petroleum products 4.70 -1.02
241 Manufacture of basic chemicals 10.86 0.45
242 Manufacture of other chemical products 8.80 -0.34
251 Manufacture of rubber products 1.64 1.88
252 Manufacture of plastic products 1.66 1.74
261 Manufacture of glass and glass products 0.54 1.98
269 Manufacture of non-metallic mineral products n.e.c 4.99 0.52
271 Manufacture of basic iron and steel 7.12 0.89
272 Manufacture of basic precious and non-ferrous metals 2.42 1.02
281 Manufacture of structural metal products, tanks, reservoirs and steam generators 0.89 1.65
289 Manufacture of other fabricated metal products, metal working service activities 1.77 1.11
291 Manufacture of general purpose machinery 2.90 1.85
292 Manufacture of special purpose machinery 2.68 0.34
293 Manufacture of domestic appliances, n.e.c 0.59 2.49
300 Manufacture of office, accounting and computer machinery 0.52 9.54
311 Manufacture of electric motors, generators and transformers 1.10 0.82
312 Manufacture of electricity distribution and control apparatus 0.68 2.08
313 Manufacture of insulated wire and cable 0.73 0.91
314 Manufacture of accumulators, primary cells and primary batteries 0.40 2.11
321 Manufacture of electronic valves and tubes and other electronic components 0.88 4.27
323 Manufacture of TV and radio receivers, sound or video recording or reproducing apparatus, and associated goods 0.88 5.63
331 Manufacture of medical appliances and instruments and appliances for measuring, checking, testing, navigating and other purposes except optical instruments 0.58 1.44
332 Manufacture of optical instruments and photographic equipment 0.10 -0.07
333 Manufacture of watches and clocks 0.22 4.24
341 Manufacture of motor vehicles 1.94 1.36
342 Manufacture of bodies for motor vehicles, trailer and semi-trailers 0.06 1.64
351 Building and repair of ships and boats 0.15 2.99
352 Manufacture of railway and tramway locomotives and rollick stock 0.19 4.05
353 Manufacture of air craft and space craft 0.04 0.33
359 Manufacture of transport equipment n.e.c. 1.79 1.81
361 Manufacture of furniture 0.26 4.46
369 Manufacturing n.e.c 0.97 0.22
  All Manufacturing 92.74 1.09
Note:
1. Aggregate Manufacturing comprises the 43 subgroups included in the sample.
2. Average indicates simple average of 43 sub-groups
3. GVA shares are for 200-01
Source: Annual Survey of Industries and P C Das (2012)

Table A 10: TFP Estimates by Industry Groups: NIC-1998 Two Digit Organized Manufacturing Industries and India KLEMS Broad Manufacturing Groups
Industries Total Manufacturing (KLEMS Study) Organized Manufacturing (RBI Study)
1990-91 to 1999-00 2000-01 to 2009-10 1990-91 to 2009-10 1990-91 to 1999-00 2000-01 to 2009-10 1990-91 to 2009-10
Food Products, Beverages and Tobacco -0.48 -0.07 -0.26 -0.35 -0.12 -0.23
Textiles & Leather Products 0.19 1.43 0.84 1.23 0.54 0.87
Wood and Products of wood -8.60 -1.66 -4.95 -6.77 1.10 -2.63
Pulp, Paper, Paper products, printing and publishing -0.87 0.31 -0.25 -2.18 -0.27 -1.18
Coke, Refined Petroleum products and Nuclear fuel -2.25 -0.60 -1.38 -0.88 -2.51 -1.74
Chemicals and Chemical Products -1.38 1.89 0.34 -1.34 1.31 0.06
Rubber and Plastic Products -0.21 1.42 0.65 1.67 1.93 1.81
Other Non-Metallic Mineral Products 0.00 -0.26 -0.14 0.46 1.96 1.25
Basic Metals and Fabricated Metal Products 0.53 -1.01 -0.28 2.13 0.30 1.17
Machinery, n.e.c. -0.15 1.06 0.48 1.29 1.80 1.56
Electrical and Optical Equipments -0.23 2.20 1.05 3.95 2.33 3.10
Transport Equipment 0.44 0.76 0.61 3.39 0.80 2.03
Manufacturing, n.e.c 1.35 -0.77 0.24 4.51 0.39 2.34
Note:
1. KLEMS manufacturing covered both organized and unorganized manufacturing and NIC 1998 covers organized manufacturing
2. NIC 1998 organized manufacturing industry groups have been mapped to broad KLEMS manufacturing industry groups.
3. Growth rates are average of annual growth rates. For organized manufacturing we use average of three digit industries to get estimates for above specifying industries
Source: Total manufacturing growth rates are estimated using KLEMS data base (www.rbi.org). Organized manufacturing growth rates are taken from Pilu Chandra Das. (2012), Total factor Productivity in Indian Organized Manufacturing Sector- The Story of the Noughties, Unpublished M.Phil. Dissertation, Delhi School of Economics

References

Ahluwalia, Montek S. 2000. ';India's Economic Reforms: An Appraisal,'; in India in the Era of Economic Reforms. Jeffrey Sachs and Nirupam Bajpa, eds. New Delhi: Oxford University Press, pp. 26-80.

Aksoy, A. (1991), ‘The Indian Trade Regime’, Policy Research Working Paper # 989, The World Bank, Washington DC.

Aksoy. A. and F.M. Ettori (1992), ‘Protection and Industrial Structure in India’ Policy Research Working Paper # 990, The World Bank, Washington DC.

Alexander, P.C. (1977), Report on the Committee on Import-Export Policies and Procedures, Ministry of Commerce, Government of India.

Balassa, B. (1965), ‘Tariff Protection in Industrial Countries: An Evaluation’, Journal of Political Economy, 73,573-94.

Balassa, B. (1982), ‘Development Strategies and Economic Performance’ in Development Strategies in Semi-industrialization Economies, Oxford University Press, London.

Balassa, B. (1985), ‘Exports, Policy Choices and Economic Growth in Developing Countries after the1973 Oil Shock,’ Journal of Development Economics, 18(2), May/June, 23-35.

Baltagi, B.H.(1988), ‘An Alternative Heteroscedastic Error Components Model, Problem 88.2.2,’Econometric Theory, 4, 349-350.

Baltagi, Badi H & Griffin, James M, 1988. ';A General Index of Technical Change,'; Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 96(1), pages 20-41, February.

Banga R and A Das (2010), “Role of trade policies in growth of Indian manufacturing sector; Centre for WTO studies, UNCTAD, New Delhi

Bhagwati J and T N Srinivasan (1978), Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: India, NBER, New York.

Breusch, T S & Pagan, A R, (1980). ';The Lagrange Multiplier Test and Its Applications to Model Specification in Econometrics,'; Review of Economic Studies, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 47(1), pages 239-53, January.

Cavallo, D.(1991), ‘Argentina: Trade Reform,1976-82’ in Shepard, G.and C.G. Langoni (eds) Trade Reform: Lessons from Eighteen Countries, ICS Press for International Center for Economic Growth, San Francisco.

Choudhury (2010), Trade Reforms and Performance in Indian Manufacturing: An analysis of the impact of the trade reforms on aspects of economic performance of the organized manufacturing sector, Lambert Academic Publishing, 2010.

Choudhury (2012), Essays on the Changing Inter-Industry Wage Structure in India, Unpublished PhD Thesis, Department of Economics, Dundee University, UK, March 2012.

Corbo, V. and J. Demelo (1987), ‘Lessons from the Southern Cone Policy Reforms,’ The World Bank Research Observer, Vol.2, No.2, 111-142.

Cordon, W.M. (1966), ‘The Structure of a Tariff System and the Effective Protection Rate’ Journal of Political Economy, 74, 221-231.

Das, D. K. (2001), Some Aspects of Productivity Growth and trade in Indian Industry, unpublished Ph.D dissertation, Delhi school of Economics, Delhi

Das, D. K. (2003), “Quantifying Trade Barriers: Has Protection Declined Substantially in Indian Manufacturing’, ICRIER Working Paper 105, Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations (ICRIER), New Delhi

Das D.K (2006). ‘Improving Industrial Productivity: Does Trade Liberalisation Matter? Evidence from Indian Capital and Intermediate Goods Sectors’, in S. Tendulkar, A. Mitra, K. Narayanan, and D.K. Das (ed.), India: Industrialization in a Reforming Economy: Essays for K.L. Krishna, Academic Foundation, New Delhi, 2006, 321–48.

Das D K et al (2014), ‘Labour Regulations in India: Exploring The Contract Labour Act (1970) and implication for Formal Manufacturing Employment’ ICRIER working paper, forthcoming

Dollar, D. (1992), ‘Outward-Oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 40, 523-544.

Deardorff, A. (1987), ‘Why do Governments Prefer Non-tariff Barrier?’, Carnegie- Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 26, 191-216.

Deardorff, A. and R. Stern (1999), Measurement of Non-tariff Barriers, University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.

Dutz, A.M.(1996), ‘Oligopolistic Firms’s Adjustment to Quota Liberalisation: Theory and Evidence’, in Roberts, M. and J.R.Tybout (ed.) Industrial Evolutions in Developing Countries: Micro Patterns of Turnover, Productivity and Market Structure, Oxford University Press for the World Bank.

Edwards, S. (1992), ‘Trade Orientation, Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries,’Journal of Development Economics, 39, 31-37.

Gang, I. and M.Pandey (1998), ‘What was Protected? Measuring India’s Tariff Barriers 1968-1997,’Indian Economic Review, Vol. xxxiii, No.2, 119-152.

Goldar (2014), “Productivity in Indian Manufacturing in the Post Reform Period’. In Kathuria V et al (ed.), Productivity in Indian Manufacturing- Measurements, Methods and Analysis, Routledge, India.

Goldar B N and A Kumari (2003), ‘Import Liberalization and Productivity Growth in Indian Manufacturing Industries in the 1990s’, The Developing Economies, 41(4), 2003, 436–60.

Goldar, B.N., A.V.L.Narayana and S.N.Hashem (1992), ‘Structure of Nominal Tariff Rates in India’, Studies in Industrial Development, Office of the Economic Advisor, Ministry of Industry, Government of India.

Goldar, B.N. and V.S. Renganathan (1990), ‘Economic Reforms and R&D Expenditure in Industrial Firms in India,’ Indian Economic Review, Vol.46, No.2, 60-75.

Goldar, B.N. and S.N.Hashem (1992), ‘India’s Tariff Structure: Effective Rates of Protection of Indian Industries,’ Studies in Industrial Development, Office of the Economic Advisor, Ministry of Industry, Government of India.

Goldar, B.N. and S.N.Hashem (1994), ‘Study of India’s Tariff Structure: Effect of Tariff Protection on Domestic Industries,’ Studies in Industrial Development, Office of the Economic Advisor, Ministry of Industry, Government of India.

Greenway, D. (1988), ‘Evaluating the Structure of Production in Less Developed Countries in D.Greenway (ed.) Economic Development and International Trade, Macmillan, London.

Greenway, D. and C. Milner (1993), Trade and Industrial Policy in Developing Countries- A Manual for Policy Analysis, Macmillan, London.

Griffiths, W. E and J.R. Anderson (1982), ‘Using a Time Series of Cross-Section Data to Estimate a Production Function with Positive and Negative Marginal Risks’, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 77,529-536.

Grossman, G. and E. Helpman (1991), ‘Trade Knowledge Spillovers and Growth,’ European Economic Review, 35, 517-526.

Gruebel, H. (1971), ‘Effective Tariff Protection: A Non-Specialist Guide to the Theory, Policy Implications and Controversies’, in Gruebel, H. and H. Johnson, Effective Tariff Protection, GATT, Geneva.

Hachette, D.(1991), ‘Chile: Trade Liberalization Since 1974’ in Shepard, G. and C.G. Langoni (eds) Trade Reform: Lessons from Eighteen Countries, ICS Press for International Center for Economic Growth, San Francisco.

Hashem, S.N. (2001), Protection in Indian Manufacturing: An Empirical Study, Macmillan India Ltd, Delhi.

Havyrlyshyn, O. (1990), ‘Trade Policy and Productivity Gains in Developing Countries: A Survey of Literature,’ The World Bank Research Observer, 5(1), 1-24.

Helleiner.G.K.(ed.)(1994), Trade Policy and Industrialization in Turbulent Times, Routledge, London and New York.

Hoda A and D Rai (2014),’ Trade and Investment Barriers affecting International Production networks in India’. ICRIER working paper 281, New Delhi

Hussain, Abid (1984), Report of the Committee on Trade Policies, Ministry of Commerce, Government of India.

Johnson, H.G. (1960), ‘The Costs of Protection and Scientific Tariff,’ Journal of Political Economy, 68,327-345.

Kathuria V et al (ed.) (2014),” Productivity in Indian Manufacturing- Measurements, Methods and Analysis, Routledge, India. Measurement

Kotwal, A., B Ramaswami and W.Wadhwa (2011) ';Economic Liberalization and Indian Economic Growth: What's the Evidence?,'; Journal of Economic Literature, American Economic Association, vol. 49(4), pages 1152-99, December.

Kowalski and Dihel (2009). ';India's Trade Integration, Realising the Potential,'; OECD Trade Policy Papers 88, OECD Publishing.

Krishna, P. and D. Mitra (1998), ‘Trade Liberalization, Market Discipline and Productivity Growth: New Evidence from India’, Journal of Development Economics, 56, 447-62.

Krueger, A. O. (1981), ‘Interactions between Inflation and Trade Objectives in Stabilization Programs ‘in Cline, W. and S. Weintraub (ed), Economic Stabilization in Developing Countries, Brookings Institution, Washington D

Krueger, A.O. (1984), ‘Trade Policies in Developing Countries’ in Jones, R.W and P.B.Kennen (ed.) Handbook of International Economics, Vol-1, Elsevier Science Publishers.

Mazodier, P. and A.Trognon (1978), ‘Heteroskedasticty and Stratification in Error Components Models,’ Annales de I Insee, 30-31, 451-482.

Meade, J. (1951), The Theory of Commercial Policy, Vol-1: The Balance of Payments, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Mehta, R. (1997), ‘Trade Policy Reforms, 1991-92 to 1995-96: Their Impact on External Trade’, Economic and Political Weekly, April 12, 779-784.

Mehta, R. and S.K Mohanty (1999), WTO and Industrial Tariffs: An Empirical Analysis for India, Research and Information System for the Non-Aligned and Other Developing Countries, Delhi.

Mishra, P. and U. Kumar (2008), Trade liberalisation and wage inequality: evidence from India, Review of Development Economics, Volume 12, Issue 2, May 2008, Pages 291 – 311.

Mitra, D. and B.P. Ural (2008) ‘Indian Manufacturing: A Slow Sector in a Rapidly Growing Economy’, Journal of International Trade and Economic Development, 17(4), 525–59.

Nambiar, R.G. (1983), ‘Protection to Domestic Industry: Fact and Theory,’ Economic and Political Weekly, 1-8 January, 27-32.

Narasimham, M. (1984) Report of the Committee to Examine the Principles of a Possible Shift from Physical to Financial Controls, Government of India.

Nishimizu, M. and S. Robinson (1986), ‘Productivity and Growth in Manufacturing’ in Chenery,H., S. Robinson and M.Syrquin (ed.) Industrialization and Growth: A Comparative Study, Oxford University Press, New York.

Nishimizu,M. and J.M. Page Jr (1991), ‘Trade Policy, Market Orientation and Productivity Change in Industry’, in DeMelo, J and A. Sapir (ed.) Trade Theory and Economic Reforms, Basil-Blackwell.

Pack, H. (1988), ‘Industrialization and Trade’ in Chenery, H. and T.N. Srinivasan (ed), Handbook of Development Economics, Amsterdam, North Holland.

Panagariya, A. (2004), India in the 1980s and 1990s: A Triumph of Reforms, IMF Working Paper No. WP/04/03, March

Panchmukhi,V.R. (1978), Trade Policies of India: A Quantitative Assessment Concepts Publishing house, New Delhi.

Pandey,M. (1999) Trade Liberalization: Non-tariff Barriers in India, Report Submitted to the Ministry of Finance, Government of India.

Pursell, G. (1988), ‘Trade Policies and Protection in India’, The World Bank, Washington DC, August.

Randolf, W.C. (1988), ‘A Transformation for Heterescedastic Error Component Regression Models’, Economic Letters, 27, 349-354.

Rao, N. (1985), Exchange Rate and Commercial Policy in a Controlled Trade Regime: A Case Study of India, Ph.D Dissertation, Oxford University.

Rodrik, D. and A. Subramanian (2005), From “Hindu Growth” to Productivity Surge: The Mystery of the Indian Growth Transition, IMF Staff Papers, Volume 52, Number 2, IMF.

Roberts, M. and J.R.Tybout (1991), ‘Size Rationalization and Trade Exposure in Developing Countries, in Baldwin (ed.) Empirical Studies of Commercial Policy, University of Chicago Press for NBER.

Rodrik, D. (1995), ‘Trade and Industrial Policy Reform’ in Behrman,J and T.N.Srinivasan (ed.) Handbook of Development Economics, Volume-3, Elesvier Science B.V.

Romer, P. (1994), ‘New Goods, Old Theory and The Welfare Costs of Trade Restrictions,’ Journal of Development Economics, 43, 5-38.

Sen, K. (2009), Trade Policy, Inequality and Performance in Indian Manufacturing, Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 2009

Sharma, G. (2006b), Competing or collaborating siblings? Industrial and trade policies in India, Department of Economics Working Paper 06–10, University of Missouri, Columbia.

Sivadasan, J. (2006), ‘Productivity Consequences of Product Market Liberalisation: Micro-evidence from Indian Manufacturing Sector Reforms’, Working paper no. 1062, Stephen M. Ross School of Business, University of Michigan,

Sivadasan, J. (2009), ‘Barriers to Competition and Productivity: Evidence from India’, The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy (electronic journal), 9(1), Article no. 42, 1–62.

Srinivasan, T.N. (1993) Agriculture and Trade in China and India- Policies and Performance since 1950, ICEG- California

Topalova, P (2004), ‘Trade Liberalisation and Firm Productivity: the Case of India’, IMF Working Paper no. WP/04/28, Washington DC, IMF, 2004.

Topalova, P. and A. Khandelwal (2011), ‘Trade Liberalisation and Firm Productivity: the Case of India’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(3), 2011, 995–1009.

Trivedi, P, A Prakash and D Sinate (2000), “Productivity in Major Manufacturing Industries in India: 1973-74 to 1997-98”, Development Research Group Study, No 20, Department of Economic Analysis and Policy, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai.

Trivedi, Pushpa, et al (2011). ';Productivity, Efficiency, and Competitiveness of the Indian Manufacturing Sector.'; DRG Study No. 37, Reserve Bank of India.

Tybout, J.R. (1992), ‘Linking Trade and Productivity: New Research Directions,’ The World Bank Economic Review, 6(2), 189-211.

Tybout, J.R. (2000), ‘Manufacturing Firms in Developing Countries: How Well Do They Do, and Why?’, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXVIII, 11-44.

Tybout, J.R. and M.D. Westbrook (1995), ‘Trade Liberalization and the Dimension of Efficiency Changes in Mexican Manufacturing Industries,’ Journal of Development Economics, 39, 53-78.

Wansbeek, T.J. (1989), ‘An Alternative Heteroscedastic Error Components Model, Solution 88 1.1’, Econometric Theory, 5,326.

World Bank (1989) India-An Industrializing Economy in Transition, A World Bank Country Study, The World Bank, Washington DC.

Young, A. (1991), ‘Learning by Doing and the Dynamic Effects of International Trade,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 369-405.


List of Abbreviation:

• ERP: Effective Rate of Protection

• FR: Frequency Ratio

• MCR: Import Coverage Ratio

• MPR: Import penetration ratio

• NRP: Nominal Rate of Protection

• NTB: Non-tariff Barrier

• OGL: Open General Licensing

• QR: Quantitative Restriction

• TFP: Total Factor Productivity


1Prof. Deb Kusum Das (dkd_ramjas@yahoo.com) is Professor in the Department of Economics, Ramjas College, University of Delhi. The views expressed in this Study are those of the author.

2 Many empirical studies of the impact of trade policy orientation on economic performance have been undertaken. Balassa (1985), Edwards (1992) and Dollar (1992) for example, have attempted to study the policy-performance aspect, using cross-country regressions relating economic performance and some measure of trade policy stance. These studies using different indicators as proxy for the overall trade policy stance have generally come to similar conclusions.

3 Improvement in productivity in manufacturing has been one of the main goals for the economic policy reforms launched in India in the early 1990s. See Kathuria et al (2014). Further, Goldar (2014) reviews the studies which have tried to capture the impact of trade policy reforms on industrial productivity.

4 Das (2003) provides a review of studies that have documented as well as analyzed the impact of import protection in Indian industries. The prominent of these studies are Goldar and Hashim (1992), Gang and Pandey (1998), Pandey (1999) and Hashim (2001).

5 Das (2003) is perhaps the first and only study to quantify outcomes of trade policy reforms in the form of nominal and effective tariff, import coverage ratio and frequency ratio and import penetration rates by 3 digit NIC industrial classification and these measures have been extensively used in studies of Mishra and Kumar (2008), Sen (2009), Rodrik and Subramanian (2005), Choudhury (2010), Kotwal et al (2011) and Choudhury (2012).

6 Das (2005) has used trade policy indicators for assessing the trade policy reforms on industrial productivity and finds a lagged impact of removing NTB on productivity performance. Study by Trivedi et al, 2000, from RBI, using non-dummy proxies for trade liberalization.

7 See studies by Gunjan Sharma (2008), Banga and Das (2010) discuss roles of trade as well as industrial policies in shaping manufacturing performance.

8 It would be important to point out that the early generation studies [Panchamuki (1978) and Nambiar (1983)] did make an effort to measure ERP via price–based data. Studies by the World Bank (1989), Aksoy (1991) and Aksoy and Ettori (1992) provide estimates of ERP based on price comparison for a single year, resulting in the inability to undertake time-series evaluations.

9 Other measures take into account both the exchange rate distortions and the direct price distortion. These measures are also known as sophisticated Corden’s and Balassa method and the measure of real effective exchange rate of protection.

10 The major problems with quantification arise from, (1) the descriptions in different licensing lists varying in coverage from very specific to very general, (2) the classification of items in the import policy was not organized according to the HS codes used to report imports and exports and (3) customs does not record imports by licensing categories, so the magnitude of imports under different licensing category cannot be observed.

11 Goldar and Hashim (1994) examined the effects of tariffs on industrial growth, factor remuneration and exports. They conclude the following. First, industries enjoying higher protection do not exhibit significantly better growth performance. Second, protection has a significant favorable effect on wage rate, however higher rates of protection may not lead to higher wages, since competition among domestic firms may keep the realized protection low. Finally the study confirms that there has been a bias against exports while following import substitution policies. In another related study, Goldar and Renganathan (1990) estimate the contribution of tariff hike to the growth of domestic capital goods industry.

12 Sharma, G (2008) examines whether there is a relationship between industrial deregulation and trade reform and concludes amongst other things that domestic competitive environment can be used to prepare firms in the economy for trade reforms.

13 See Table 2.1 in Greenway and Milner (1993) for the list of instruments under tariff and non-tariff measures.

14 The ad-valorem import tax has the advantage of being index linked, whilst the specific import tax has the desirable feature of reducing opportunities for under invoicing and other illegal practices aimed at minimizing the tax liability. Further, sometimes particular tariff can be used as a quasi non-tariff barrier, for example when it applies on a seasonal basis or when it is linked to a quota.

15 From a documentary standpoint the diversity of NTB is a major problem. One cannot easily ‘add together’ the restrictive impact of deliberately complicated customs valuation procedures with that of price surveillance, or an import quota. Greenway and Milner (1993) argue that it is in part for this reason that summary statistics are hard to come by. The situation is further complicated by the fact that many NTBs are quite deliberately opaque.

16 Greenway and Milner (1993) discusses the following practical problems, (1) existence of secondary tariff, (2) exceptions and exemptions to the scheduled tariffs, (3) tariff redundancy and (4) aggregation problems.

17 The Harmonized System (HS) code came into operation from 1986-87. Our study extending from 1990-91 to 2009-10 necessitated establishing a mapping of HS tariff codes to NIC three digit industries.

18 Available upon request from the author

19 The following types of customs duties are levied by the Government of India on goods imported into India: (1) basic customs duty, (2) auxiliary duty of customs, (3) additional (countervailing) duty of the customs. The standard rates of basic customs duty are generally ad valorem. Only in a small proportion of cases, specific rates or combination of ad valorem and specific rates are applicable.

20 The actual rate called the effective rate is determined by various exemption notifications announced by the Government from time to time. The presence of a large number of exemption notifications makes the structure of effective basic customs duty quite different from that of the standard basic customs duty rates. As in the case of basic duty, there were exemption notifications in respect of auxiliary duties also. Refer Goldar and Hashim (1992) for a detailed account of the types of exemption notifications prevalent in the tariff structure. For the present study we consider only those exemptions which apply to all items under a tariff heading at the 6-digit HS codes.

21 After 1993-94, the auxiliary duty was merged with the basic duty, hence the average nominal tariff was inclusive of the effective basic customs duty only.

22 Given the significance of NTBs, the first issue to be addressed in connection with measuring the height of protection is to obtain direct price comparison. For the problems associated with obtaining price comparisons refer to Krueger (1984).

23 Krueger (1984) points out that in developing countries, number of reasons exists for believing that ERPs might not straightforwardly indicate protection to value added. First, factor prices often fail to reflect opportunity costs, due to the presence of subsidies to inputs of capital, labor market imperfections and minimum wage legislation. In the presence of inappropriate factor costs, the net direction of resource pulls will be influenced by both the height of protection and the degree of divergence from a well functioning market. Second, it was a frequent observation that few firms produce any single product resulting in exploitation of monopoly power in sheltered home market. Thus the extent of protection to value added as reflected in the ERP measure would overstate (to the extent of monopoly profits) and misstate (to the extent factors were implicitly subsidized) the additional domestic resources employed per unit of value added in the protected industries.

24 The following assumptions are used: (1) there are fixed physical input coefficients in the production of j, (2) the domestic price is equal to the border price plus tariffs, i.e. there are no tariff redundancies or non- tariff barriers. The assumptions of fixed technical coefficients implies that price distortions do not affect technology used and that there is no substitution between traded and non-traded inputs because of price distortions [see Grubel (1971)].The assumption of the domestic price being equal to border price plus tariffs usually does not hold for countries like India, which have extensive non-tariff barriers [see Goldar and Hashim (1992)].

25 In empirical work, both negative numerators and denominators have been observed. Each gives rise to an estimated negative rate of effective protection, but the interpretation must be quite different. See Krueger (1984) for an economic interpretation of the negative numerator and denominator.

26 Balassa (1965) argued that non-traded inputs could be treated as if they were traded inputs in infinitely elastic supply. In such circumstances their price would be insensitive to protection and Tj would equal zero. In contrast, Corden (1966) argued that value added in non-traded inputs should be aggregated with all other value added. In effect then, non-traded inputs enjoy the same level of protection as primary factors. We consider the simple Corden methodology where non-traded inputs are treated as part of the primary factors of production and value-added is calculated by extracting the cost of traded inputs directly used in production.

27 Greenway and Milner (1993) illustrate many of these measurement problems with a case study. These could be listed as (1) choice of tariffs, (2) tariff averaging, (3) input-output coefficients, (4) choice of non-traded inputs, (5) import content of non-tradable, (6) non-tariff barriers, (6) treatment of exportable output and (8) exchange rate effects.

28 It was not possible to use the cost data for the three-digit industries, as detailed data were not available for all the years of the study. A mapping was established between the I-O sectors and ASI sectors, so as to enable the I-O coefficients to substitute for the input costs of the industries. Use has been made of multi sectoral sector I-O tables (1989-90, 1993-94, 1997-98, 2002-03 and 2007-08) for the period 1990-91 to 2009-10respectively. This implicitly involves the assumptions that input-output coefficients remained the same during the period under study. Details of mapping between I-O sectors and ASI three-digit industries are available upon request from the author.

29 The customs tariff working schedule was not available for some years of the study and hence the same information was collected from private sources such as Centax Publications and Cencus Publications.

30 Deardorff (1987) offers some possible explanations as to why governments in developing countries prefer non-tariff barriers to tariffs. They are: (1) institutional constraints built into GATT/WTO rules and into national constitutions that limit the use of tariffs, (2) the roles of firms and workers in influencing the policies, (3) considerations of reaction or retaliations against the policies of trading partners and (4) uncertainty about the ways in which different policies may perform. Deardorff favors the last of these explanations insofar as governments perceive that tariffs will not work effectively in reducing imports in uncertain world and only an explicit quantitative restriction can be relied upon.

31 Deardorff and Stern (1999) state that NTBs also include a potentially unlimited plethora of policies, perhaps as yet not invented, that alter however indirectly the prices and quantities of trade. Therefore, no typology of NTBs can possibly be complete.

32 See Deardorff and Stern (1999), chapter 2

33 There are also informal barriers arising from: (1) administrative procedures and unpublished Government regulations and policies, (2) market structure and (3) political, social and cultural institutions. The impediments associated with informal barriers may be the result of a conscious effort by Government to favor domestic over foreign interests, or these may be the byproducts of practices and policies that are rooted in domestic institutions. See Deardorff and Stern (1999)

34 (1) reduction in the quantity of imports, (2) the increase in price of imports, (3) the change in the elasticity of demand for imports, (4) the variability of NTBs, (5) the uncertainty of imports, (6) welfare costs and (7) resource costs of NTBs. See Deardorff and Stern (1999)

35 Quota usually permits an announced quantity of imports of a certain type, so that an analysis of quota should start with direct information pertaining to that quantity. A variable levy is defined in terms of a specified price of an imported good and that price provides the most direct information about what the levy entails.

36 (1)The direct approach only captures those NTBs that have been identified. If an industry makes use of a particular form of NTB, that an investigator does not take into account, then trade appears much free than it is actually. (2) Even for the NTBs that are included, it is extremely difficult to process the diverse direct information that is available on each NTB in a way that will be comparable across NTBs and thus allow them to be added-up to obtain a total measure of trade interference. (3) If more than one NTB is present in given industry, it is conceivable that the presence of one reduces the effects of another, so that analysis of each of them separately may lead to an overstatement of their total effects. More generally, inevaluating overall levels of protection by NTBs, general equilibrium effects are bound to matter (such as the effects of barriers on one sector on trade in another and the effects of all together on exchange rates).

37 Deardorff and Stern (1999) discuss these measures along with specific NTB methods.

38 The drawback with import weights is that most NTBs reduce imports to zero and do not show up in the aggregate, whereas in the case of own country production levels, protective NTBs stimulate domestic production above levels that would otherwise obtain. It may be therefore, worthwhile subject to availability of data to use world production levels or world trade as weights.

39 To calculate measures of NTB for the three-digit industries, we need to map the product wise information on import licensing status data to the three-digit industries, as the ASI does not provide any such information for the industries. For details and the procedure of mapping refer appendix Tables IV.2, 3 and 4 of Das (2001)

40 We have a single weighting scheme within NTBs, i.e. we provide a weight of 1 if the product is banned/restricted or limited permissible or canalized. Further, since majority of these categories was abolished after 1991-92, we were constrained to treat them all as one composite category called R in orderto have a comparable series for the 1980s, when information is available separately on each licensing status. For the period post 1991-92, the only available information in this category is the banned status.

41 The data from 1993-94 onwards, was available at a much higher level of disaggregation and a 4-digit HS code was treated as R if all 6 & 8 HS digit codes were restricted and similarly as F if all sub codes were free. However in some cases, a 4-digit HS code was listed as R, if majority of the sub codes were R (same for F). In some cases a 4-digit code was also listed as RF (RCF) if an equal number of sub codes were split between R and F (R, F and C) and given a weight of.50 (.66). Since the detailed information for 1993-94 pertains to the trade policy document 1992-97, the years in the third phase only were classified according to this rule.

42 First, NTBs are recorded as present or absent. Thus it does not matter if product x has “n” number of NTBs whilst product y has only one; both enter the ratio with equal weights. Second, it is implicitly assumed that all measures are equally restrictive. A quota on product a is treated in the same way as one on product b, even if the former applies to 10 per cent of the market and the latter applies to 90 per cent of the market. Thus although variations in the ratio through time can give some idea as to trends in the use of NTBs, they have to be treated cautiously. Third,both Fj and Cj does not provide any information on the possible deterrent effects that NTBs may have upon the pricing or quantity decisions of foreign exporters. Fourth, Fj and Cj ratios refer primarily to border measures and thus ignore the entire range of internal governmental measures and the restrictive actions of imperfectly competitive firms. Finally, these measures provide no information on the economic impact that NTBs have on prices, production, consumption and trade. Worse, they may be misleading in this regard, if a large number of relatively small or non-binding NTBs divert attention from a smaller number in other industries or countries that have more serious effects.

43 See Greenway and Milner (1993) for the tariff-equivalence analysis. Deardorff and Stern (1999) provide description for other techniques such as quantity-impact measures and special purpose methods for calculating NTBs.

44 The details of the mapping of product lines with ASI industry codes have been compiled by the author and are available upon request.

45 Pandey (1999), computes the tariff-equivalence of the non-tariff barrier at the product level for the period of 1990s.A major limitation of the exercise is that, the products cover only the agriculture sector and no effort has been made to compute the same for industrial products, which are under QRs.

46 The mapping between ITC (HS) four-digit codes, and ASI three-digit industries is available upon request from the author.

47 Arvind Subramanian (2009) distinguishes the period of 1980s from the 1990s by referring it as pro business orientation and in the 1990s pro market reforms.

48 Hoda and Rai (2014) contend that the easing out of high level of applied duties with respect to tariffs only started in 2000s.The surcharge on basic customs duty was given up in 2001-02, and the peak basic customs duty was reduced every year from 2002-03 onwards until it was 10 per cent in 2007-08, with very few exceptions.

49 The import control mechanism in India was first introduced as a result of the foreign exchange crises of the second five year plan (1956-61). From 1960-77 these controls were increasingly tightened and more complex. See World Bank (1989) and Aksoy (1991) for a detailed description of the import-licensing regime

50 Attempts have been made to estimate the share of imports subject to different licensing categories. Pursell (1988) has made rough estimates of imports under OGL for the 1980s, Aksoy (1991) presents share of imports in different licensing categories for 1986-87. Hashim (2001) extends the Aksoy framework for the 1990s.

51 It is possible to construct a variety of measures that indicate the frequency of occurrence of NTBs. Such measures may un weighted, or they may be weighted by imports or by production. Further they may be classified according to various categories of NTBs. For details, see OECD (1995).

52 Refer to the category of consumer goods in annexure tables A3 and A4.

53 The Trade Policy (1991-92) listed the following categories: (a) the prohibited items (tallow, fats, oils, lard, poultry, animal rennet and un-manufactured ivory) and (b) the restricted list. The restricted list further categorized items into (1) consumer goods, (2) security related items; (3) environment related items, (4) electronics and (5) Drugs and chemicals. Successive policy statements have further pruned the list.A phased reduction in the peak rate of customs duty was also undertaken in successive budget announcements. The customs duty on power projects and related machinery was brought down to 25 per cent and the duty on fertilizer projects was reduced to zero by the end of 1994-95.

54 The import penetration ratios were available for only a subset of all three-digit industries (NIC 1998) as an exact mapping could not be established for many of the three-digit industries

55 Das (2003) undertook a study of import penetration ratios for 72 three-digit industries in India. The analysis revealed an upward trend in the average level of import penetration in Indian industries in the post-reform period. According to his estimates, the average value of the import penetration ratio for these 72 industries increased from about 11% in the period 1986-90 to about 16% in the period 1996-2000. An increase in the import penetration ratio was found for all the three use-based industry groups into which the 72 industries were divided: intermediate goods (from 13% in 1986-90 to 18% in 1996-2000), capital goods (from 12% to 19%) and consumer goods (from 4% to 10%)

56 Goldar and Renganathan (2008) computed import penetration ratios for 66 manufacturing industries (the sectors of the input-output tables belonging to manufacturing) for the years 1983-84, 1989-90, 1993-94, 1998-99 and 2003-04. The following are observed- between1989-90 and 1998-99 there was an increase in import penetration in most industries. In many cases, the increase in the import penetration ratio was significant, reaching a 20% or higher level. In some cases, the import penetration ratio in 1998-99 even exceeded 40%. It may be concluded therefore, that in the first eight years of the post-reform period, 1991- 92 to 1998-99, there was increasing import penetration of the domestic markets of Indian industries caused by the liberalization of imports It is interesting to note that the upward trend in import penetration ratio did not persist after 1998-99. Between 1998-99 and 2003-04, there was an increase in the import penetration ratio in some industries, but in a larger number of industries, there was a fall in the import penetration ratio. The average import penetration ratio in Indian industries increased from about 9% in 1989-90 to about 16% in 1998-99, but declined to about 14% in 2003-04.

57 Refer to annexure table A6 for a summary of trade barriers at NIC 1998 two digit manufacturing sub- groups

58 Helleiner (1994) presents empirical evidence for selected countries in Latin America [Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico and Peru], Asia [Bangladesh, India, Korea, Malaysia, Sri-Lanka, Thailand and Turkey] and Africa [Kenya and Tanzania]

59 Tybout (2000) points out on the basis of empirical evidence that when trade liberalization improves productive efficiency, it is probably due to intra-plant improvements that are unrelated to internal or external scale economies. Micro panel studies by Roberts and Tybout (1991), Tybout and Westbrook (1995) and Dutz (1996) consistently find that increases in import penetration as well as reductions in protection are associated with reductions in plant size. Further, external scale economies also do not account for large protection related efficiency effects.

60 According to neo-classical trade theory, trade liberalization leads to level effects through improved allocation of resources, however the theory is not unequivocal about growth effects of trade liberalization.

61 See Grossman and Helpman (1991), Romer (1994) and Young (1991).

62 Catch-up models describe a one-time transition from dated to new technology. To link trade policy changes and productivity growth theorists have used a general equilibrium framework with continual knowledge production and diffusion. Tybout (2000) however concludes that the analytical literature is ambigious about the effect of trade policy changes on manufacturing.

63 Tybout (2000) argues that outward oriented policies are more likely to facilitate long-run growth and presents evidence on each channel to ascertain whether these processes are empirically important.

64 The consensus emerging from the failure of the southern cone of Latin America in the late 1970s points out that a stable macroeconomic environment is a prerequisite to the success of trade liberalization. See Corbo and de Melo (1987), Cavallo (1991) and Hachette (1991). Further, Rodrik (1995) points out that trade and price reforms often have been in reality mere appendages to stabilization programs ( as in Bolivia in 1985, Mexico at end 1987 and Brazil and Peru in 1990s and Argentina in 1991)

65 In India, industrial policy reforms were introduced in conjunction with trade liberalization. The 1980s saw wide ranging changes such as; broad banding, de-licensing of 23 broad categories of industries, relaxation on MRTP Act, expansion of capacity etc. The 1991-92 economic reforms saw the elimination of MRTP Act, downsizing of the public-sector reservations, abolition of industrial licensing, doing away of phased manufacturing programs and reforms in regulations concerning foreign technology and investment. Therefore, to assess the impact of trade reforms it is appropriate to conceive a framework which is a combination of industrial and trade policy changes along with the macro environment

66 In the econometric estimation, the lag length (s) is chosen as 2. See section 6.5 for a discussion on the choice of the lag length.

67 Price cost margin (PCM) as proxy variable for industrial policy liberalization/outcome of industrial policy reforms. The argument being that greater internal competitive pressure brought about by reforms in industrial policy act as a spur to productivity enhancement. We treat PCM here to reflect greater competition in the industry as against a measure of efficiency.

68 Changes in the capital intensity or capital labour ratio as a measure of capital intensity on the right hand side of the regression is with the expectation that increased capital use relative to labour will raise productivity as a result of superior technology embodied in the capital inputs.

69 Inflation uncertainity is a proxy for the macroeconomic environment and is defined as three year standard deviation of whole sale price indices.

70 Pilu Chandra Das (2012) reviews the literature of productivity performance in Indian manufacturing especially since reforms.

71 Pilu Chandra Das (2012) estimates TFP growth for the entire organized manufacturing sector based at three digit NIC 1998 classification using a Jorgenson et al (1987) KLEMS framework for the period 2000-2008. This is the first study which uses a KLEMS framework for organized manufacturing incorporating five inputs- traditional inputs (labor and capital) as well as intermediate inputs (material, energy and services) in calculating total factor productivity growth via growth accounting methodology for organized manufacturing. For the present study we constructed TFP for 43 manufacturing sub-groups from 1990-91 to 2009-10.

72 Our estimates of organized manufacturing TFP as derived using DAS, P C (2012) are in line with other estimates of TFP notably, the India KLEMS estimates for total manufacturing. See annexure table A10 for a detailed comparison of two set of TFP estimates

73 Infrastructure development which has improved tremendously compared to before 1991 could also have been an important indicator of outcomes of Industrial policy reforms. But the conventional indicators of infrastructure development like roads, railways, ports, airports and power have overall impact on the economy and are not specific to an industry. As such even though we observe change in infrastructure development over the time period under consideration but the same cannot be aligned to a specific industry in a panel structure. As part of the control variables we have taken Gross Output at industry level which varies across time as an independent variable and which can take into account the changing economics of scale as well as implicitly absorb the impact of infrastructure development over time. We have also introduced industry and time fixed effect which should be able to control for unobserved heterogeneity across industries.




Top