Bhupal Singh*
The empirical estimates suggest that short end of the financial market, particularly the
call money rate, exhibits a significant and contemporaneous (instantaneous) pass-through of
75 - 80 basis points in response to a percentage point change in the monetary policy rates under
deficit liquidity conditions and phases of relatively tight monetary policy. The state of liquidity
in financial markets is found to play an important role in conditioning the pass-through of
policy rate changes to short end of financial market. A significant asymmetry is observed in
the transmission of policy rate changes between the surplus and deficit liquidity conditions,
particularly at the short end of financial market, suggesting that maintaining suitable liquidity
environment is critical to yielding improved pass-through. There is also considerable asymmetry
evident in the transmission of monetary policy to financial markets depending on the tight or
easy cycles of monetary policy, which suggests the criticality of attaining a threshold level for
the policy rate under each cycle to have desired pass-through. Medium to long term rates such
as bank deposit and lending rates also exhibit asymmetrical response to policy rate changes
under varied market conditions. The results from the VAR model reiterate that it is the strong
presence of transmission lags that leads to higher degree of pass-through to financial markets,
thus, underscoring the importance of a forward-looking approach.
JEL classification : E52, G1
Keywords : Monetary policy, financial markets; transmission channels
Introduction
Notwithstanding a rich theoretical foundation and large body of
empirical literature on monetary policy transmission, policy makers
continue to face considerable uncertainty about the impact of policy
changes given the lack of direct interface of monetary policy actions
with real economic activity, existence of complexities in financial markets and presence of transmission lags. The presence of long
transmission lags also make it challenging to disentangle the impact of
monetary policy shocks from other exogenous shocks that may occur
in the interregnum. This lack of certainty in actual magnitude and the
timing of impact of policy changes on financial and real variables
build in considerable caution in policy decisions. Bernanke and Gertler
(1995), while raising the concern about the lack of understanding about
the transmission mechanism observed that “the same research that has
established that changes in monetary policy are eventually followed by
changes in output is largely silent about what happens in the interim.
To a great extent, empirical analysis of the effects of monetary policy
has treated the monetary transmission mechanism itself as a ‘black
box’.” Although this may not be true for many advanced economies
where there are less imperfections in asset, labour and goods markets,
many developing economies have not yet achieved the same degree
of flexibility in such markets, and continue to face challenges in the
assessment of monetary policy transmission. Given the considerable
rigidities in goods and labour market in most developing economies and
resultant complexities in the transmission mechanism, the motivation of
this paper is to refrain from investigating the direct causation between
the monetary policy shocks and macroeconomic aggregates, rather
focus on clearer understanding of propagation of changes in monetary
policy to various segments of financial markets.
Monetary policy affects output and prices through its influence
on key financial variables such as interest rates, exchange rates, asset
prices, credit and monetary aggregates, which is described as monetary
transmission mechanism. The complete transmission mechanism of
monetary policy to real variables could be understood as a two stage
process. In the first stage of transmission, policy actions of central
bank both current and expected, transmit through the money market
to bond, credit and asset markets, which directly influence the savings,
investment and consumption decisions of individuals and firms.
This operates through the term structure of interest rates in financial
markets; changes in short term rates affect the expectation of the
future interest rates and thus, affect the long end of yield curve, which
raises the marginal cost of funding long term assets. The second stage of monetary transmission involves propagation of monetary policy
shocks from financial markets to goods and labour markets, which
are ultimately reflected in aggregate output and prices1. Thus, clarity
about the first stage of monetary transmission is vital to understanding
the transmission to aggregate output and prices. This is vital in the
direction of understanding the market behaviour and bringing about
more clarity of the transmission channels. Needless to say that given the
great deal of uncertainties surrounding the impact of monetary policy
actions on real variables typically in economies where financial market
imperfections are prevalent, we consciously resist the temptation of
examining the second stage of transmission. The key question that we
attempt to examine in this paper is the existence of asymmetries in
the transmission of monetary policy rate changes to financial market
prices. More precisely, adopting an agnostic approach, we examine
how the same magnitude of policy rate change causes varied impact
on financial asset prices during different phases of policy cycle, varied
liquidity conditions and across the spectrum of maturity. Section II sets out a brief theoretical context to understanding the propagation of
monetary shocks to financial markets. We postulate a model explaining
asymmetries in response of financial markets to monetary policy shocks
in section III. Empirical results on assessment of degree of asymmetries
in the response of financial markets to policy shocks are presented in
section IV and conclusion in section V.
Section II
Theory
Monetary policy actions are transmitted to the rest of the economy
through changes in: (i) financial prices, mainly interest rates, exchange
rates, bond yields, asset prices; and (ii) financial quantities primarily
money supply, credit aggregates, supply of government bonds, foreign
currency denominated assets. Policy changes work through financial
markets, which act as interface between monetary policy and real
economy and are considered to be the purveyors of monetary policy shocks to real economy. Since monetary policy works through financial
markets (by changing interest rates or quantity of money or liquidity),
transmission is also contingent on the stage of development of domestic
financial markets as also on the inter-linkages between financial
markets, the degree of financial integration and inter-sectoral linkages
between financial sector and real economy. Second, transmission to
financial markets may also be affected by the degree of administrative
interventions in determination of financial asset prices. Third, horizontal
domestic integration and vertical integration with global market may
also significantly affect the speed and efficiency of transmission.
Fourth, exchange rate regimes may also have significant influence in
determining the pass-through of external shocks on domestic assets and
goods prices and may complicate the process of transmission. Further,
in real world, trade-off between short run liquidity management and
medium term price stability concerns may turn the policy communication
challenging and in such situations managing expectations to guide the
long run interest rates may turn complicated.
The effectiveness of monetary policy signals depends upon the speed
with which policy rates are transmitted to financial markets. The speed
and size of pass-through to financial asset prices depends on a number
of factors such as volatility in money markets, the extent to which the
policy changes are anticipated and maturity structure of banks’ balance
sheets. In some market segments, presence of structural rigidities in
terms of imperfect competition, low integration with other market
segments, regulatory norms and high cost of operations may impart
inflexibility to market interest rates to respond contemporaneously to
policy rate changes. Furthermore, differences in agents’ expectations
about short and long end of market may be a source of existence of lag
in the transmission of policy rates. Understanding the behaviour and
complexity of financial markets, thus, assumes critical importance in
understanding the standard monetary policy transmission channels.
Section III
Model and Data
The following model is postulated to estimate the aggregate impact
of monetary policy shocks on various segments of financial markets.
For empirical assessment of policy transmission, we use the
following variables to estimating the series of models4: (i) Reserve
Bank’s repo rate (rRPO), (ii) weighted average call money rates (rCall),
(iii) weighted average CBLO rates (rCBLO), (iv) weighted average
market repo rates (rMRPO), (v) weighted average rates on commercial
papers (rCP), (vi) weighted average rates on certificates of deposit
(rCD), (vii) yield on 91-day treasury bills (rTB91), (viii) average
interest rate on 1-month Mumbai Interbank Offer Rate (rMBR1m)5,
(ix) average interest rate on 1-year overnight index swaps (rOIS1y),
(x) average secondary market yield on government of India 10-year
bonds (r10y), (xi) average yield on AAA-rated 5-year corporate
bonds (rCorp), (xii) average interest rates on 1-3 year deposit rates of
commercial banks (rD3y), (xiii) average interest rates on lending rates
of commercial banks (rLend)6, (xiv) wholesale price index seasonally
adjusted (Lwpi), (xv) banks’ outstanding liquidity balances under the
liquidity adjustment facility (LAF), (xvi) rupee-dollar exchange rate
(EXR), (xvii) Bombay Stock Exchange Sensex (BSE). The data are
sourced from Reserve Bank of India, Clearing Corporation of India
Limited, International Finance Statistics, IMF, Thomson Reuters Eikon,
Thomson Reuters Datastream and the Bloomberg. The sample period
for the study is 2001:M3 to 2012:M6, however, a few variables have
data beginning later than 2001:M3. The rationale for choosing monthly
frequency of data for the analysis is guided by the fact that not all data
used in the estimates are available at less than monthly frequency. The
specific methodological issues involved in the empirical exercise are
contained in Annex A.
Section IV
Empirical Results
Before embarking on empirical analysis of the transmission
mechanism, it would be pertinent to understand the degree of integration of prices of various financial assets. A simple correlation analysis of
the spectrum of interest rates in India presented in Table 1 exhibits a
reasonably high degree of market integration. Broadly, the short end of
the financial markets has higher degree of correlation with policy rates
as well as with liquidity conditions in financial markets. Nevertheless,
the long end of the market such as bank lending rates and interest rates
on corporate bonds is also found to be correlated with the policy rate.
Thus, Table 1 provides the starting point for further exploring the impact
of policy rate changes on financial markets.
Table 1: Correlation Matrix (Sample: 2001:M3 to 2012:M6) |
|
rCorp |
rLend |
dLwpi |
EXR |
LAF |
rMBR1m |
rOIS1y |
r10y |
rCall |
rCBLO |
rCD |
rCP |
rMRPO |
rRPO |
rTB91 |
rD3y |
rCorp |
1.00 |
0.36 |
0.48 |
-0.03 |
-0.42 |
0.75 |
0.62 |
0.36 |
0.57 |
0.49 |
0.81 |
0.75 |
0.52 |
0.72 |
0.68 |
0.86 |
rLend |
0.36 |
1.00 |
-0.29 |
-0.33 |
0.42 |
0.04 |
-0.03 |
-0.25 |
0.00 |
-0.15 |
0.13 |
0.11 |
-0.10 |
0.38 |
-0.02 |
0.25 |
dLwpi |
0.48 |
-0.29 |
1.00 |
0.04 |
-0.59 |
0.51 |
0.55 |
0.55 |
0.46 |
0.52 |
0.49 |
0.46 |
0.52 |
0.41 |
0.54 |
0.34 |
EXR |
-0.03 |
-0.33 |
0.04 |
1.00 |
-0.17 |
0.04 |
-0.23 |
-0.12 |
0.05 |
0.10 |
-0.05 |
0.00 |
0.09 |
-0.15 |
-0.07 |
0.10 |
LAF |
-0.42 |
0.42 |
-0.59 |
-0.17 |
1.00 |
-0.79 |
-0.69 |
-0.54 |
-0.69 |
-0.77 |
-0.72 |
-0.70 |
-0.77 |
-0.66 |
-0.81 |
-0.46 |
rMBR1m |
0.75 |
0.04 |
0.51 |
0.04 |
-0.79 |
1.00 |
0.80 |
0.45 |
0.87 |
0.84 |
0.94 |
0.90 |
0.86 |
0.89 |
0.94 |
0.73 |
rOIS1y |
0.62 |
-0.03 |
0.55 |
-0.23 |
-0.69 |
0.80 |
1.00 |
0.79 |
0.74 |
0.76 |
0.80 |
0.63 |
0.76 |
0.87 |
0.90 |
0.50 |
r10y |
0.36 |
-0.25 |
0.55 |
-0.12 |
-0.54 |
0.45 |
0.79 |
1.00 |
0.45 |
0.52 |
0.48 |
0.30 |
0.50 |
0.55 |
0.62 |
0.28 |
rCall |
0.57 |
0.00 |
0.46 |
0.05 |
-0.69 |
0.87 |
0.74 |
0.45 |
1.00 |
0.92 |
0.78 |
0.77 |
0.95 |
0.79 |
0.85 |
0.50 |
rCBLO |
0.49 |
-0.15 |
0.52 |
0.10 |
-0.77 |
0.84 |
0.76 |
0.52 |
0.92 |
1.00 |
0.73 |
0.72 |
1.00 |
0.79 |
0.89 |
0.46 |
rCD |
0.81 |
0.13 |
0.49 |
-0.05 |
-0.72 |
0.94 |
0.80 |
0.48 |
0.78 |
0.73 |
1.00 |
0.87 |
0.76 |
0.86 |
0.90 |
0.81 |
rCP |
0.75 |
0.11 |
0.46 |
0.00 |
-0.70 |
0.90 |
0.63 |
0.30 |
0.77 |
0.72 |
0.87 |
1.00 |
0.76 |
0.76 |
0.81 |
0.75 |
rMRPO |
0.52 |
-0.10 |
0.52 |
0.09 |
-0.77 |
0.86 |
0.76 |
0.50 |
0.95 |
1.00 |
0.76 |
0.76 |
1.00 |
0.81 |
0.90 |
0.49 |
rRPO |
0.72 |
0.23 |
0.41 |
-0.15 |
-0.66 |
0.89 |
0.87 |
0.55 |
0.79 |
0.79 |
0.86 |
0.76 |
0.81 |
1.00 |
0.94 |
0.64 |
rTB91 |
0.68 |
-0.02 |
0.54 |
-0.07 |
-0.81 |
0.94 |
0.90 |
0.62 |
0.85 |
0.89 |
0.90 |
0.81 |
0.90 |
0.94 |
1.00 |
0.63 |
rD3y |
0.86 |
0.25 |
0.34 |
0.10 |
-0.46 |
0.73 |
0.50 |
0.28 |
0.50 |
0.46 |
0.81 |
0.75 |
0.49 |
0.64 |
0.63 |
1.00 |
rCorp = yield on AAA-rated corporate bonds, rLend= average lending rates of commercial banks, dLwpi = inflation rate, EXR= rupee- USD exchange rate, LAF = outstanding liquidity under the liquidity adjustment facility, rMBR1m = 1-month MIBOR rate, rOIS1y =1-year OIS yield, r10y= yield on 10-year govt. bond, rCall = weighted average call money rates, rCBLO = weighted average collateralized borrowing and lending rates, rCD = weighted average rate on certificates of deposits, rCP = weighted average rate on commercial papers, rMRPO = average interest rate on market repo transactions, rRPO = repo rate of the Reserve Bank, rTB91 = yield on 91-day treasury bills, rD3y = average interest rate on bank deposits of 1-3 year maturity.
Note: Some of the data series start later than 2001:M3. |
We estimate the pass-through of policy interest rates to financial
asset prices in the framework of a distributed lag model as monetary
policy may impact different segments of financial markets with varying
lags7. Furthermore, from a policy perspective, it is important to assess
the impact of policy changes in a forward looking manner. In other
words, a realistic assessment of the impact of policy changes has to take
into account (a) lags involved in the transmission, and (b) differences
in the contemporaneous and the lagged impact of policy changes on
market interest rates.8
(i) Monetary transmission to the short and long end of financial
markets : A baseline case
Due to the presence of unit roots in the variables, differenced terms
were used for estimation (See Annex Table 1). Only the significant lags
were retained in the model. We use dummy variables in the models to
control for the effects of extreme events in financial markets generated
by unanticipated exogenous shocks and which cannot be explained by
other variables.9 All the models are tested for residual diagnostic tests by using Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM Test.10 All the specified
models are found to be free from serial autocorrelation problem. We
begin with estimating models for assessing the impact of policy rate
changes (repo rate) on financial markets without differentiating either
between liquidity deficit and surplus conditions or tight and easy
monetary policy phases (see Chart 1 and 2 and Annex Table 2 and 3).11
Thus, the analysis below does not attempt to capture the impact of
policy rate changes under different market conditions.
First, as expected, the transmission of policy rates is instantaneous
and large for money market as compared with the longer end of financial
market.12 Transmission to financial markets improves significantly
as the lagged impact of policy rate changes takes effect. Second, call
money market seems to be highly sensitive to the policy rate changes
and displays substantial pass-through with lag effects in response to
policy rate shocks. Third, policy rate changes are likely to impact the
working capital cost of the corporates significantly as a policy rate shock
tends to cause considerable increase (decrease) in the interest rates
on commercial papers. As the funding cost of banks in the overnight
market increases significantly, banks may pass it on by raising short
term lending rates for corporates. Fourth, expectations seem to play an
important role in explaining the market behaviour in response to policy
rate shocks, as an initial shock could be construed by the market as
continuation of policy rate cycle of the central bank. This is reflected in
relatively strong response of 1-month MIBOR and 1-year OIS markets
to policy rate shocks. The assessment of the transmission process
towards the short end of financial markets suggests that between 40 to
75 basis points pass-through of a percentage point change in policy rates
is realised in the same month, indicating a high degree of instantaneous
pass-through (Chart 1). This can be attributed to a reasonable degree
of integration of money markets observed in India (see Bhoi and Dhal, 1998). The existence of the lag effects of policy rate changes is
considerable across market segments.
 |
Central banks often find it challenging to guide long-term interest
rates, which basically directly impact the saving and investment
decisions of economic agents and hence impact the macroeconomic
aggregates such as output and prices. Therefore, for transmission to be
effective, the short term interest rates should be significantly transmitted
to long term interest rates. In theory, short end (money markets) and
long end (capital markets) of financial markets are connected through
expectations.13 Thus, transmission of changes in policy rates to
long end of financial markets assumes critical importance. Empirical
estimates suggest that bank deposit and lending rates exhibit longer lags
in transmission (Chart 2 and Annex Table 3). The transmission of policy
rates to deposit rates increases overtime. The presence of long lags may
emanate from the fact that banks seem to be cautious about adjusting
deposit rates in response to the central bank’s policy rate signals due to
a variety of reasons such as expectation formations regarding the likely
path of future interest rates and the fear of losing their deposit base to
small savings and other competing investment avenues. Regarding the
long lags in lending rates, it could be possible that banks are unable to
adjust their lending rates swiftly in response to policy signals until they are able to adjust on the cost side by repricing the fixed-rate deposits
in the next cycle. It is also possible that longer lags in deposit rates
feed into lending rates adjustments. Besides these, adjustment cost of
frequent revisions in lending rates and borrowers’ aversion to recurrent
fluctuations in cash flows may also be constraints on banks in adjusting
lending rates frequently in response to changes in policy rates. Thus, due to
the aforementioned structural rigidities in the deposit and credit markets,
contemporaneous pass-through of policy rates to these segments seems
to be low. Nevertheless, the lagged transmission of policy rate changes
to deposit and lending rates seems to be reasonably significant, which
has important implications for savings and investment activities.
 |
Pass-through of policy rate changes to long term government bonds
yield (r10y) though relatively low, is reasonably instantaneous. The
corporate bonds yields (rCorp) show relatively faster contemporaneous
transmission of policy rates changes as compared with bank lending rates
due to differences in the structure of these two markets. This could also be
attributed to the fact that capital markets price in market developments
at a faster rate as compared with credit markets.
(ii) Does the monetary policy transmission improve during deficit
liquidity conditions?
Central banks typically operate at the short end of financial
markets by modulating liquidity (mainly overnight liquidity). It is
argued that monetary transmission is substantially more effective in
a deficit liquidity situation than in a surplus liquidity situation (RBI, 2011). We empirically test the hypothesis whether transmission is
significantly different during the deficit liquidity from that of the surplus
liquidity conditions. As liquidity position is either in surplus or deficit
mode, represented in positive and negative values, normalising such
series to log poses challenge. In order to empirically test the model
rt = α + (γ1 * Ø) rpt + et postulated for the liquidity deficit situation,
we capture liquidity deficit impact through a dummy variable (DLDef)
which assumes a value 1 for liquidity deficit conditions and 0 otherwise.14
The empirical estimates from a standard distributed lag model for call
money market based on the sample period 2001:M3 to 2012:M6 are presented in Table 2.
The estimates suggest that liquidity deficit has an important role
in causing changes in money market rates. Thus γ1 assumes a value of
1.84 and Ø a value of 0.82, indicating that liquidity has important role
in propagating monetary policy transmission. It is evident from Table
2 that after controlling for liquidity deficit, the contemporaneous term
turns insignificant and hence dropped from the model. This also seems
to suggest that when there is absence of liquidity stress, overnight
market rate responds gradually to policy rate changes. The limitation
of this model is that deficit or surplus values of varying magnitudes
which have significantly differential impact on market interest rates,
are assumed to be the same.15 In order to overcome this limitation,
we split the sample into periods of surplus and deficit liquidity. Based
on some broad empirical observation of sample, we treat LAF deficit
as conditions of liquidity stress. The empirical estimates suggest
significant asymmetric behaviour of call rates, commercial paper yield
and short term treasury bill yield to changes in policy rates during the
deficit liquidity conditions vis-a-vis surplus liquidity conditions (Chart 3 and 4)16. The instantaneous pass-through of policy rate changes to
call money rate during deficit liquidity conditions is nearly 75 basis
points in response to a percentage point change in policy rate. More
importantly, the lag impact is relatively much strong during the deficit
than the surplus conditions, suggesting that one should take into account
the persistence in the impact of policy rate change rather merely looking
at the instantaneous change in order to assess the impact on financial
assets and hence macro aggregates.
Table 2: Transmission of policy rate changes to short term interest rates
after controlling for liquidity conditions (Dependent variable: call money rates) |
Variable |
Coefficient |
t-Statistic |
C |
5.55 |
7.62 |
drRPO(-1) |
0.61*** |
2.99 |
drRPO(-2) |
0.70** |
2.06 |
drRPO(-3) |
0.53** |
2.17 |
DLDef |
0.96*** |
7.07 |
DLDef*drRPO |
0.82*** |
5.41 |
DUM2007M3 |
6.17*** |
32.32 |
DUM2007M6M7 |
-5.04*** |
-19.78 |
DUM2008M9 |
0.99*** |
3.82 |
AR(1) |
0.93*** |
23.18 |
R2 |
0.94 |
|
DW stats |
1.95 |
|
LM test stats |
0.04(F-stats) |
0.96(prob) |
drRPO = changes in policy rates, DLDef = dummy variable representing periods of
liquidity deficit conditions, DLDef*drRPO = interaction dummy variable to capture
liquidity deficit impact, DUM2007M3, DUM2007M6M7, DUM2008M9 = dummy
variables for extreme market volatility during particular months that are not explained
by other variables. |
A distinct empirical observation is that transmission of policy rates
is higher for bank deposit rates during liquidity surplus conditions. This
could be a reflection of banks’ behaviour of passing on to depositors
the reductions in interest rates faster than the increases.17 Overall, the persistence of shocks seems to be higher during the deficit liquidity
conditions than during surplus conditions (see Annex Table 4 and 5 for
detailed results).
(iii) How asymmetric is the transmission during tight and easy
phases of monetary policy?
The transmission of policy rates to financial markets is also affected
by the state of the monetary policy cycle. We believe that there exists
a threshold level of policy rate that has significant bearing on prices of
financial assets. For the purpose of empirical analysis, we assume that
all (nominal) policy rate changes above 7 per cent, which is a long period average of policy rates during all cycles, imply that monetary policy
is operating in a tight phase.18 Thus, it is assumed that all policy rate
changes above a threshold rate would have relatively strong impact on
financial asset prices than the policy rate changes below this threshold.
Charts 5 and 6 reveal that policy rate changes have a significantly
higher impact during tight phase of monetary policy for call money,
commercial papers and bank lending rates (detailed results in Annex
Table 6 and 7). The instantaneous pass-through of a percentage point
increase in policy rate to call money rates is 81 basis points during tight monetary policy phase as compared with merely 41 basis points
during the easy monetary policy. Further, the results indicate presence
of procyclicality in the behaviour of interest rates facing the corporate
sector as transmission is more pronounced during the tight phase of the
policy cycle. Thus, achieving a threshold level of interest rate is critical
to have desired impact of policy rate changes on financial markets
and the real economy. However, there does not seem to be evidence
of noticeable differences in the instantaneous transmission of policy
rates to short term treasury yield. It is also observed from Charts 5
and 6 that transmission of policy rate is significantly higher during the
tight phases of monetary policy due to presence of strong transmission
lags. A reverse asymmetry is found with respect to bank deposit rates,
which could be attributed to bank’s behaviour of passing on decreases
in interest rates faster than the increases.
(iv) An assessment of liquidity and policy rate shocks during varied
financial market conditions: Results from VAR models
In view of structural changes as well as financial innovations, the
size of the pass-through as well as the precise transmission lags may
differ during the business cycles. In order to further explore monetary
transmission to financial markets, we estimated two VAR models, one
for the short end of financial market and the other for the long end.19
First, a 7-variable VAR model is estimated based on monthly data for
the period 2001:M3 to 2012:M6, in an attempt to assess the response
of short term financial assert prices to policy rate and the liquidity
changes.20 The variables in the VAR model are: Liquidity under the
LAF, changes in policy rates (rRPO), weighted average call money rates
(rCall), yield on 91-day treasury bills (rTB91), weighted average rates
on commercial papers (rCP), BSE Sensex and rupee-dollar exchange
rate (EXR). In the model, the variable on deficit liquidity under the
LAF (D=1 for liquidity deficit condition and 0 otherwise) is introduced
so that the model does not lead to overestimation of the impact of interest rate shocks.21 There is evidence of significant impact of policy
rates shocks on the short end of the financial market, including stock
prices and exchange rate (Chart 7).22 The peak impact of policy rate
shocks to money markets is realised after a lag of 1-5 months. An initial
shock to liquidity and policy rates affects call money, treasury bill and
commercial paper yield with persistence of shocks varying from 2-10 months. A positive policy rate shock also leads to some moderation
in stock prices with a lag and persists for a short period. Thus, asset
price channel of monetary policy seems to be in operation.23 It would
however, be too early to conclude about the considerable wealth effect
of monetary policy shocks given the limited household ownership of
stocks in their asset portfolio in India. We also find some evidence of
exchange rate channel of monetary policy. The nominal rupee-dollar
exchange rate appreciates in response to policy rate shocks, though
the impact is transitory.24 Regarding the impact of liquidity shocks
on financial assets, it is generally found that liquidity shocks are less
pronounced vis-a-vis interest rate shocks. Overall, the results suggest
varying persistence of monetary policy shocks across the short end
of financial market. The counter-factuals on the impact of policy rate
shocks on financial market prices with and without controlling for
liquidity conditions are presented in Appendix 1 and 2.
 |
 |
We also estimate a 6-variable VAR model based on monthly data
for the period 2002:M2 to 2012:M6 to examine how the long end of
financial market responds to policy rate changes.25 26 The variables
included in the VAR model are: Liquidity under the LAF, changes in
policy rates (rRPO), average secondary market yield on government of
India 10-year bonds (r10y), average interest rates on 1-3 year deposit
rates of commercial banks (rD3y), average yield on AAA-rated 5-year corporate bonds (rCorp) and average interest rates on lending rates of
commercial banks (rLend). The impact of policy rate shock on long term
interest rates, though relatively less pronounced as compared to short
end of the markets, is found to be significant. The interest rate channel
rather than the quantity channel is found to be dominant towards the
long end of the markets. There are also lags observed in transmission of
policy rates shocks to long term interest rates.27 Bank lending channel of
monetary policy transmission seems to be evident as policy rates impact
both deposit and lending rates. Nevertheless, there is greater persistence
of policy rate shocks on deposit rates as compared with lending rates,
reflecting the pricing behaviour. The less pronounced impact of policy
rate shocks on lending rates can also be seen in the context of the fact
that long term interest rates are also influenced by a number of other
factors such as fiscal position of government, inflation expectations and assessment of credit risk by economic agents (Chart 8).28 A comparative
assessment of the impulse responses suggests that a shock to policy
rate leads to significant change in yield on 10-year government bonds.
As the government bond yield acts as a benchmark for corporate bond
pricing, changes in sovereign bond yields are instantaneously priced in
the corporate bonds. While the changes in liquidity conditions have only
transitory impact on corporate bond yields, there is some tendency of
short run persistence in the response of corporate bond yields to policy
rate shocks. A comparative picture of the responses of long end of
financial asset prices to policy rate shocks with and without controlling
for liquidity conditions is presented in Appendix 3 and 4.
 |
 |
Section V
Conclusion
The evidence suggests that transmission of monetary policy
changes is instantaneous and large for money market as compared with
the long end of financial markets in India. During deficit liquidity and
tight phase of monetary policy, there is evidence of about 75-80 basis
points contemporaneous pass-through to money market interest rate
of a percentage point change in policy rate suggesting a reasonably
high degree of pass-through. The pass-through improves significantly
during the tight cycles of monetary policy. Bank deposit and lending
rates exhibit longer lags in transmission with cumulative pass-through
of about 50-70 basis points in response to changes in policy rate.
Regarding the lags in the transmission of policy rates to lending rates,
it could be possible that banks are unable to adjust their lending rates
swiftly in response to policy signals until they are able to adjust on the
cost side by repricing the fixed-rate deposits in the next cycle. To the
extent that there exists significant wedge between the response of short
term and long term interest rates to monetary policy changes, greater
is the burden of adjustment on policy interest rates in order to have
desirable effect on real variables. Across the maturity spectrum, there
is existence of asymmetry in response of financial markets to policy rates changes depending on the state of liquidity in financial markets
and the cycle in which monetary policy is operating. The pass-through
of policy rates is found to be significantly higher in deficit liquidity
conditions and during the tight monetary policy cycle largely due to the
presence of transmission lags. Such transmission lags also reemphasise
the importance of forward-looking approach to the policy.
The results from a VAR analysis of policy rate and liquidity shocks
suggest that the quantity channel operates along with the interest rate
channel towards the short end of financial markets and both liquidity
and interest rate shocks seem to be equally persistent. It is the interest
rate channel of monetary policy transmission that is dominant towards
the long end with persistence varying from 4 to 10 months. Thus,
the dominant impact of interest rate channel in affecting long term
interest rates brings out the stabilisation role of monetary policy.
The estimates also exhibit that both the exchange rate and asset price
channel of monetary policy are in operation. The exchange rate channel
of transmission reveals that policy rate shocks and domestic liquidity
tightening both lead to initial appreciation of nominal exchange rate,
which does not seem to be persistent. There is some evidence of the
wealth channel of monetary policy as positive interest rate shocks
are found to cause a reduction in stock prices, which may impact
on household wealth and hence consumption demand. This would,
however, be limited, given the lower share of stocks in total household
wealth in India.
References
Bernanke B. and Allan Blinder (1992). “The Federal Funds rate and
the channel of money transmission.” American Economic Review, 82:
901-21.
Bernanke B. and M. Gertler (1995). “Inside the Black Box: the Credit
Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission.” NBER Working Paper No.
5146.
Bhoi, B. K. and S. C. Dhal (1998). “Integration of Financial Markets in
India: An Empirical Evaluation.” RBI Occasional Papers, 19(4): 345-
380.
Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum and C. Evans (1996). “The effects of
monetary policy shocks: Evidence from the flow of funds.” Review of
Economics and Statistics, 78: 16-34.
Kuttner, K. N. and P. C. Mosser (2002). “The Monetary Transmission
Mechanism: Some Answers and Further Questions”. Economic Policy
Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New York: 15-26.
Loayza, Norman and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel (2002). “Monetary Policy
Functions and Transmission Mechanisms: An Overview”, in Monetary
Policy: Rules and Transmission Mechanisms (eds.) Loayza, Norman
and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, in Series on Central Banking, Analysis and
Economic Policies, Vol. IV, Central Bank of Chile.
Reserve Bank of India (2011). Report of the Working Group on
Operating Procedure of Monetary Policy, March.
Sims, C. A. (1992). “Interpreting the macroeconomic time series facts:
The effects of monetary policy.” European Economic Review, 36: 975-
1000.
Singh, Bhupal (2010). “Monetary Policy Behaviour in India: Evidence
from Taylor-type Policy Frameworks.” RBI Staff Studies, SS(DEAP)
2/2010, Reserve Bank of India.
Annex A: Methodological Issues
(i) List of variables: rRPO = repo rate of the Reserve Bank, rCall =
weighted average call money rates, rCBLO = weighted average collateralised
borrowing and lending rates, rMRPO = average interest rate on market repo
transactions, rTB91 = yield on 91-day treasury bills, rCD = weighted average
rate on certificates of deposits, rCP = weighted average rate on commercial
papers, rOIS1y = 1-year OIS yield, rMBR1m = 1-month MIBOR rate, rD3y
= average unweighted interest rate on bank deposits of 1-3 year maturity,
r10y= yield on 10-year govt. bond, rLend= avg. lending rates of commercial
banks, rCorp= yield on AAA-rated corporate bonds, dLwpi = change in log
of wholesale price index, EXR = rupee-dollar exchange rate, SENSEX =
BSE Sensex. These notations have been referred to in the foregoing analysis.
The data used are monthly averages rather than end month data as the end
month figures could be subject to volatility and may not be appropriate to
capture the underlying relationships between the variables. LAF outstanding
for a month is the average of daily outstanding balances during the month.
Average bank lending rate is the prevailing unweighted lending rate and not
the average rate on outstanding credit. Rupee-dollar exchange rate and BSE
30 share SENSEX are average of daily closing rates/prices.
(ii) Identification of deficit and surplus liquidity samples: A month has been
labelled as liquidity deficit or surplus depending on the average daily balances
in deficit or surplus mode. However, we have also applied our judgement in
defining some of the months as liquidity deficit or surplus depending on how
many days the liquidity was in surplus or deficit and depending on the level
of surplus or deficit so as to retain some element of time series properties
while classifying the samples (see Chart A). Based on these properties,
sample has been reclassified for the analysis.
 |
(iii) Identification of tight and easy monetary policy cycles: There are a
few studies in the Indian context which point to a neutral nominal policy
rate of about 6.5 to 7 per cent. Further, a preliminary alalysis reveals that
the average WPI inflation rate during the period 2001-02 to 2011-12 was
about 6.5 per cent (excluding some months with abnormally low or negative
inflation rate during global financial crisis) and the average nominal policy
rate of 6.8 per cent, implying a negligible real policy interest rate. It may be
noted that although the concept of neutral rate is understood in terms of real
interest rate in advanced economies, in case of emerging market economies
like India, where there is relative volatility in inflation, a nominal measure of
neutral rate may be more appropriate to assess the policy stance. Rather than
going into the debate of the neutral policy rate, we assume that on an average
above 7 per cent would indicate a tight monetary policy stance. Accordingly,
the sample has been reclassified for the two sub periods.
Annex Table 1: Unit Root tests |
Variables |
Level/First diff. |
Augmented Dickey-Fullertest statistic |
Phillips-Perron test statistic |
Test critical values |
1% level |
5% level |
10% level |
rRPO |
level |
-2.6 |
-2.2 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
|
Δ |
-4.8 |
-7.4 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rCall |
level |
-4.0 |
-3.9 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rCBLO |
level |
-3.2 |
-2.7 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rMRPO |
level |
-3.5 |
-3.1 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rTB91 |
level |
-1.9 |
-2.3 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
|
Δ |
-9.5 |
-9.5 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rCD |
level |
-1.9 |
-2.0 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
|
Δ |
-10.9 |
-10.9 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rCP |
level |
-2.8 |
-2.8 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rOIS1y |
level |
-3.1 |
-2.5 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rMBR1m |
level |
-2.5 |
-2.3 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
|
Δ |
-7.9 |
-7.9 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rD3y |
level |
-1.5 |
-1.5 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
|
Δ |
-5.6 |
-5.7 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
r10y |
level |
-2.8 |
-2.8 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rLend |
level |
-1.5 |
-1.4 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
|
Δ |
-8.0 |
-8.1 |
-3.5 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rCorp |
level |
-2.0 |
-2.1 |
-3.6 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
|
Δ |
-7.2 |
-7.2 |
-3.6 |
-2.9 |
-2.6 |
rRPO = repo rate of the Reserve Bank, rCall = weighted average call money rates, rCBLO = weighted average collateralised borrowing and lending rates, rMRPO = average interest rate on market repo transactions, rTB91 = yield on 91-day treasury bills, rCD = weighted average rate on certificates of deposits, rCP = weighted average rate on commercial papers, rOIS1y = 1-year OIS yield, rMBR1m = 1-month MIBOR rate, rD3y = average interest rate on bank deposits of 1-3 year maturity, r10y= yield on 10-year govt. bond, rLend= avg. lending rates of commercial banks, rCorp= yield on AAA-rated corporate bonds. These notations may be referred to in the subsequent analysis. |
Annex Table 2: Transmission of policy rate changes to the short end of financial markets |
Variables |
rCall |
rCBLO |
rMRPO |
rTB91 |
rCD |
rCP |
rMBR1m |
rOIS1y |
C |
6.11 |
5.80 |
5.68 |
0.01 |
0.04 |
7.99 |
-0.52 |
6.27 |
|
(6.17) |
(4.26) |
(6.75) |
(0.49) |
(0.98) |
(9.60) |
(-2.78) |
(8.33) |
ΔrRPO |
0.38** |
0.43* |
0.39* |
0.51*** |
|
0.39* |
0.73*** |
0.51*** |
|
(2.35) |
(1.90) |
(1.87) |
(4.36) |
|
(1.92) |
(4.83) |
(3.55) |
ΔrRPO(-1) |
0.60*** |
0.53*** |
0.50** |
0.29** |
0.91*** |
0.51** |
0.40*** |
0.58*** |
|
(2.58) |
(2.90) |
(2.22) |
(2.23) |
(5.73) |
(2.41) |
(3.09) |
(2.78) |
ΔrRPO(-2) |
0..62** |
|
0.55* |
|
|
|
|
0.34*** |
|
(2.24) |
|
(1.79) |
|
|
|
|
(3.35) |
ΔrRPO(-3) |
0.45** |
|
|
|
|
0.45** |
|
0.25* |
|
(2.34) |
|
|
|
|
(2.06) |
|
(1.90) |
rCall |
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.09*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(3.16) |
|
DUM2004M6_2007M1 |
|
|
|
|
1.53*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(43.63) |
|
|
|
D2007M3_2008M9 |
6.27*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(32.63) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
DUM2007M6M7_2009M4 |
|
-4.57*** |
|
-1.52** |
-1.56*** |
|
|
|
|
|
(-17.04) |
|
(-2.53) |
(-37.52) |
|
|
|
DUM2007M6M7 |
-5.04*** |
|
-3.14*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
(-19.31) |
|
(-6.40) |
|
|
|
|
|
DUM2007M8_2008M7 |
|
|
|
1.19*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(3.53) |
|
|
|
|
DUM2008M9M10 |
1.35*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(6.39) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
DUM2008M12 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
-0.63** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
(-2.47) |
|
DUM2010M6_M10 |
|
0.92*** |
|
|
|
1.89** |
|
|
|
|
(4.05) |
|
|
|
(2.44) |
|
|
AR(1) |
0.94*** |
0.93*** |
0.92*** |
|
|
0.90*** |
|
0.95*** |
|
(34.22) |
(27.74) |
(19.82) |
|
|
(21.34) |
|
(26.15) |
R2 |
0.93 |
0.88 |
0.85 |
0.51 |
0.45 |
0.82 |
0.41 |
0.92 |
DW Statistics |
1.96 |
1.98 |
1.83 |
1.89 |
2.02 |
2.07 |
2.07 |
1.84 |
BG-LM Test-F Stats |
0.04 |
0.02 |
0.72 |
0.99 |
1.37 |
0.61 |
0.82 |
2.10 |
Prob. |
(0.96) |
(0.98) |
(0.49) |
(0.38) |
(0.26) |
(0.54) |
(0.44) |
(0.11) |
Sample |
2001 M3 to
2012
M6 |
2003 M2 to
2012
M6 |
2003 M2 to
2012
M6 |
2001 M3 to
2012
M6 |
2001 M5 to
2012
M6 |
2001 M8 to
2012
M6 |
2001
M5 to
2012
M6 |
2001 M8 to
2012
M6 |
*, **, *** represent significance level of 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
DUM: Dummy variables to capture extreme fluctuations in the series. Dummy variable defined to represent a particular month in a year.
Note: The Newey-West estimator (bartlett kernel, fixed bandwidth) is used to estimate covariance matrix of parameters of the models.
The estimator improves OLS estimation in the presence of heteroskedasticity/autocorrelation.
The figures in brackets are t-statistics. |
Annex Table 3: Transmission of policy rate changes to the long end of financial markets |
Variables |
r10y |
rCorp |
rD3y |
rLend |
C |
7.02 |
0.01 |
0.02 |
0.01 |
|
(9.78) |
(0.27) |
(0.90) |
(0.39) |
ΔrRPO |
0.25 * |
0.41 *** |
0.12 ** |
0.27 *** |
|
(1.83) |
(4.61) |
(2.12) |
(4.67) |
ΔrRPO(-1) |
0.22 * |
0.27 *** |
0.33 *** |
0.15 *** |
|
(1.90) |
(3.64) |
(4.66) |
(2.60) |
ΔrRPO(-3) |
-0.19 ** |
|
|
|
|
(-2.40) |
|
|
|
ΔrRPO(-4) |
|
|
0.22 *** |
0.14 *** |
|
|
|
(2.98) |
(2.55) |
dLwpi |
0.07 *** |
|
|
|
|
(2.70) |
|
|
|
DUM2003M2_2008M10 |
|
1.11 *** |
|
|
|
|
(26.89) |
|
|
DUM2007M4 |
|
|
|
0.62 *** |
|
|
|
|
(5.41) |
DUM2007M7_2008M12 |
|
-0.99 *** |
|
|
|
|
(-5.28) |
|
|
DUM2008M6 |
0.62 *** |
|
|
|
|
(11.85) |
|
|
|
DUM2008M12 |
-1.13 *** |
|
|
|
|
(-8.42) |
|
|
|
DUM2010M7 |
|
|
|
-3.42 *** |
|
|
|
|
(-21.13) |
DUM2011M2_2012M2 |
|
|
1.05 *** |
|
|
|
|
(3.54) |
|
DUM2012M1 |
|
|
-1.75 *** |
|
|
|
|
(-62.07) |
|
AR(1) |
0.97 *** |
-0.24 ** |
|
|
|
(31.84) |
(-2.15) |
|
|
R2 |
0.94 |
0.61 |
0.71 |
0.81 |
DW Statistics |
1.76 |
1.97 |
1.98 |
1.82 |
BG-LM Test-F Stats |
0.76 |
1.55 |
0.13 |
0.23 |
prob |
(0.47) |
(0.22) |
(0.88) |
(0.80) |
Sample |
2002M2 to
2012M6 |
2002M2 to
2012M6 |
2002M2 to
2012M6 |
2002M2 to
2012M6 |
*, **, *** represent significance level of 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
dLwpi = change in log of wholesale price level.
Note: The Newey-West estimator (bartlett kernel, fixed bandwidth) is used to estimate covariance matrix of parameters of the models.
The estimator improves OLS estimation in the presence of heteroskedasticity/autocorrelation.
The figures in brackets are t-statistics. |
Annex Table 4: Transmission of policy rate under deficit liquidity conditions |
Variables |
rCall |
rTB91 |
r10y |
rCp |
rD3y |
rLend |
C |
7.35 |
0.02 |
7.28 |
9.35 |
0.10 |
0.06 |
|
(19.32) |
(0.61) |
(46.54) |
(32.08) |
(2.79) |
(2.10) |
ΔrRPO |
0.74*** |
0.71*** |
0.20* |
0.39** |
0.38*** |
0.41*** |
|
(5.82) |
(11.86) |
(1.87) |
(2.15) |
(3.85) |
(3.33) |
ΔrRPO(-1) |
0.63*** |
0.14* |
|
0.82*** |
|
0.14*** |
|
(3.41) |
(1.92) |
|
(6.06) |
|
(3.87) |
ΔrRPO(-2) |
0.63*** |
-0.19*** |
|
0.75*** |
|
|
|
(2.68) |
(-2.93) |
|
(4.32) |
|
|
ΔrRPO(-3) |
0.53*** |
0.13*** |
|
0.63*** |
|
|
|
(2.64) |
(2.87) |
|
(3.30) |
|
|
dLwpi |
|
|
0.11*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
(5.70) |
|
|
|
DUM1 |
6.21*** |
1.24*** |
0.73*** |
2.18*** |
1.42*** |
|
|
(31.84) |
(4.03) |
(13.44) |
(7.89) |
(39.13) |
|
DUM2 |
-5.09*** |
-2.39*** |
-1.80*** |
-1.30*** |
-2.14*** |
-1.68*** |
|
(-22.68) |
(-56.54) |
(-3.87) |
(-4.96) |
(-6.07) |
(-5.84) |
AR(1) |
0.78*** |
|
0.63*** |
0.68*** |
|
|
|
(7.97) |
|
(4.25) |
(5.76) |
|
|
R2 |
0.88 |
0.89 |
0.79 |
0.81 |
0.85 |
0.83 |
DW Statistics |
1.95 |
1.74 |
2.22 |
1.93 |
1.97 |
1.57 |
BG-LM Test-F Stats |
0.05 |
1.51 |
0.23 |
0.29 |
0.12 |
1.60 |
prob |
(0.95) |
(0.23) |
(0.79) |
(0.75) |
(0.89) |
(0.21) |
Obs. |
71 |
71 |
71 |
71 |
71 |
71 |
*, **, *** represent significance level of 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
DUM1 and DUM2 are dummy variables used for months with extreme price volatility either positive or negative.
Note: The Newey-West estimator (bartlett kernel, fixed bandwidth) is used to estimate covariance matrix of parameters of the models.
The estimator improves OLS estimation in the presence of heteroskedasticity/autocorrelation.
The figures in brackets are t-statistics. |
Annex Table 5: Transmission of policy rate under surplus liquidity conditions |
Variables |
rCall |
rTB91 |
r10y |
rCp |
rD3y |
rLend |
C |
0.03 |
0.02 |
6.79 |
6.31 |
-0.02 |
-0.01 |
|
(1.43) |
(0.93) |
(8.91) |
(11.90) |
(-0.79) |
(-0.86) |
ΔrRPO |
0.31** |
0.32* |
0.30* |
|
0.39*** |
|
|
(2.41) |
(1.85) |
(1.89) |
|
(3.08) |
|
ΔrRPO(-1) |
0.35*** |
0.33*** |
|
|
0.42*** |
0.26** |
|
(3.32) |
(2.75) |
|
|
(3.49) |
(2.08) |
ΔrRPO(-3) |
0.26** |
|
|
0.62*** |
0.24** |
|
|
(2.37) |
|
|
(3.78) |
(2.62) |
|
DUM1 |
0.96*** |
0.35*** |
|
2.12*** |
2.91*** |
1.76*** |
|
(43.48) |
(12.89) |
|
(7.65) |
(26.79) |
(11.86) |
DUM2 |
-1.06*** |
-0.81*** |
-1.10*** |
|
-0.37*** |
-0.74*** |
|
(-6.15) |
(-12.15) |
(-4.20) |
|
(-9.22) |
(-39.71) |
AR(1) |
|
|
0.95*** |
0.85*** |
|
|
|
|
|
(26.38) |
(10.18) |
|
|
R2 |
0.76 |
0.57 |
0.90 |
0.81 |
0.95 |
0.76 |
DW Statistics |
1.98 |
1.98 |
1.75 |
1.82 |
2.19 |
2.33 |
BG-LM Test-F Stats |
0.63 |
0.40 |
0.58 |
0.93 |
0.67 |
1.19 |
prob |
(0.54) |
(0.67) |
(0.56) |
(0.40) |
(0.52) |
(0.31) |
Obs. |
65 |
65 |
65 |
65 |
65 |
65 |
*, **, *** represent significance level of 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
Note: The Newey-West estimator (bartlett kernel, fixed bandwidth) is used to estimate covariance matrix of parameters of the models.
The estimator improves OLS estimation in the presence of heteroskedasticity/autocorrelation.
The figures in brackets are t-statistics. |
Annex Table 6: Transmission of policy rate under the tight cycle of monetary policy |
Variables |
rCall |
rTB91 |
r10y |
rCp |
rD3y |
rLend |
C |
5.49 |
-0.04 |
7.64 |
0.03 |
0.04 |
0.02 |
|
(9.86) |
(0.96) |
(22.64) |
(0.39) |
(1.11) |
(0.82) |
ΔrRPO |
0.81*** |
0.48*** |
1.08*** |
0.81*** |
0.12*** |
0.31*** |
|
(4.03) |
(8.36) |
(6.26) |
(3.31) |
(3.46) |
(5.01) |
ΔrRPO(-1) |
0.45** |
|
|
1.17*** |
0.48*** |
0.73*** |
|
(2.35) |
|
|
(3.61) |
(4.24) |
(4.43) |
ΔrRPO(-2) |
0.76*** |
|
|
|
|
-0.12*** |
|
(3.00) |
|
|
|
|
(-2.74) |
ΔrRPO(-3) |
0.72*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
(2.94) |
|
|
|
|
|
dLwpi |
0.29*** |
|
0.07*** |
|
|
|
|
(3.50) |
|
(12.37) |
|
|
|
DUM1 |
6.17*** |
1.05*** |
0.64*** |
2.05*** |
1.04*** |
0.35*** |
|
(31.97) |
(7.17) |
(6.52) |
(11.96) |
(3.14) |
(4.42) |
DUM2 |
-5.03*** |
-1.22*** |
-0.62*** |
-1.73*** |
-1.71*** |
-2.80*** |
|
(-18.19) |
(-3.06) |
(-3.55) |
(-11.32) |
(-52.07) |
(-11.74) |
AR(1) |
0.65*** |
|
0.86*** |
|
|
|
|
(5.15) |
|
(14.67) |
|
|
|
R2 |
0.91 |
0.61 |
0.86 |
0.62 |
0.79 |
0.93 |
DW Statistics |
1.99 |
2.21 |
1.65 |
1.96 |
1.85 |
1.78 |
BG-LM Test-F Stats |
0.27 |
0.58 |
1.62 |
0.12 |
0.59 |
0.34 |
prob |
(0.76) |
(0.57) |
(0.21) |
(0.88) |
(0.56) |
(0.71) |
Obs. |
68 |
68 |
68 |
68 |
65 |
65 |
*, **, *** represent significance level of 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
Note: The Newey-West estimator (bartlett kernel, fixed bandwidth) is used to estimate covariance matrix of parameters of the models.
The estimator improves OLS estimation in the presence of heteroskedasticity/autocorrelation.
The figures in brackets are t-statistics. |
Annex Table 7: Transmission of policy rate under the easy cycle of monetary policy |
Variables |
rCall |
rTB91 |
r10y |
rCp |
rD3y |
rLend |
C |
0.03 |
0.05 |
0.00 |
0.01 |
0.00 |
-0.02 |
|
(1.00) |
(2.24) |
(0.06) |
(0.09) |
(0.04) |
(-1.34) |
ΔrRPO |
0.41*** |
0.41** |
0.30*** |
|
|
0.31* |
|
(2.62) |
(2.32) |
(2.71) |
|
|
(1.70) |
ΔrRPO(-1) |
|
0.40*** |
|
0.89** |
0.53*** |
|
|
|
(2.86) |
|
(2.32) |
(3.80) |
|
ΔrRPO(-3) |
0.41*** |
|
|
|
0.38*** |
0.33*** |
|
(2.95) |
|
|
|
(3.40) |
(2.72) |
rCall |
|
|
|
0.68*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
(3.31) |
|
|
dLwpi |
|
|
0.05*** |
|
|
|
|
|
|
(3.13) |
|
|
|
DUM1 |
0.86*** |
0.66*** |
0.60*** |
3.04*** |
3.12*** |
0.44*** |
|
(6.38) |
(5.42) |
(8.12) |
(8.60) |
(70.30) |
(13.51) |
DUM2 |
-1.04*** |
-0.73*** |
-2.42*** |
-1.49*** |
-0.62*** |
-3.45*** |
|
(-5.62) |
(-6.90) |
(-23.44) |
(-5.35) |
(-12.96) |
(-38.38) |
AR(1) |
|
|
-0.39*** |
-0.27** |
|
|
|
|
|
(-2.24) |
(-2.01) |
|
|
R2 |
0.74 |
0.63 |
0.75 |
0.70 |
0.91 |
0.89 |
DW Statistics |
2.07 |
2.05 |
1.81 |
1.95 |
1.63 |
1.98 |
BG-LM Test-F Stats |
0.89 |
0.36 |
1.90 |
0.92 |
1.35 |
0.22 |
prob |
(0.42) |
(0.70) |
(0.18) |
(0.40) |
(0.27) |
(0.81) |
Obs. |
67 |
67 |
67 |
67 |
66 |
66 |
*, **, *** represent significance level of 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.
Note: The Newey-West estimator (bartlett kernel, fixed bandwidth) is used to estimate covariance matrix of parameters of the models.
The estimator improves OLS estimation in the presence of heteroskedasticity/autocorrelation.
The figures in brackets are t-statistics. |
|